Criminality and economic conditions

By Willem Adriaan Bonger


    The Project Gutenberg eBook of Criminality and economic conditions
    
This ebook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United States and 
most other parts of the world at no cost and with almost no restrictions 
whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or re-use it under the terms 
of the Project Gutenberg License included with this ebook or online 
at www.gutenberg.org. If you are not located in the United States, 
you will have to check the laws of the country where you are located 
before using this eBook.



    
        Title: Criminality and economic conditions
        
        Author: Willem Adriaan Bonger
        Author of introduction, etc.: Edward Lindsey
                Frank H. Norcross
        Translator: Henry P. Horton

        
        Release date: July 28, 2023 [eBook #71282]
        Language: English
        Original publication: United Kingdom: William Heinemann, 1916
        Credits: Jeroen Hellingman and the Online Distributed Proofreading Team at https://www.pgdp.net (This file was produced from images generously made available by The Internet Archive/American Libraries.)
    
        
            *** START OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK CRIMINALITY AND ECONOMIC CONDITIONS ***
        




                   THE MODERN CRIMINAL SCIENCE SERIES

                    Published under the Auspices of
         THE AMERICAN INSTITUTE OF CRIMINAL LAW AND CRIMINOLOGY


                              CRIMINALITY
                                  AND
                          ECONOMIC CONDITIONS


                                   BY

                         WILLIAM ADRIAN BONGER
                       of Amsterdam, Netherlands

                             TRANSLATED BY
                            HENRY P. HORTON
                          of Ithaca, New York

                      WITH AN EDITORIAL PREFACE BY
                             EDWARD LINDSEY
                        of the Warren, Pa., Bar

                      AND WITH AN INTRODUCTION BY
                           FRANK H. NORCROSS
                 Justice of the Supreme Court of Nevada
        Vice-President of The American Institute of Criminal Law
                            and Criminology


                                 LONDON
                           WILLIAM HEINEMANN








CONTENTS

                                                                   PAGE
General Introduction to the Modern Criminal Science Series           xi
Editorial Preface by Edward Lindsey                                  xv
Introduction by Frank H. Norcross                                   xix
Translator’s Note                                                 xxiii
Preface to the American Edition                                   xxvii
Preface to the Original Edition                                    xxix
Introduction                                                       xxxi


PART ONE

CRITICAL EXPOSITION OF THE LITERATURE DEALING WITH THE RELATION
BETWEEN CRIMINALITY AND ECONOMIC CONDITIONS


CHAPTER I

THE PRECURSORS

AUTHORS WHO TREATED THE SUBJECT BEFORE THE BIRTH OF MODERN
CRIMINAL SCIENCE

I.        Thomas More                                                 1
II.       Jean Meslier                                                7
III.      J. J. Rousseau                                              8
IV.       Morelly                                                     9
V.        C. Beccaria                                                10
VI.       S. N. H. Linguet                                           10
VII.      P. H. D. d’Holbach                                         13
VIII.     G. B. de Mably                                             14
IX.       J. P. Brissot de Warville                                  15
X.        W. Godwin                                                  18
XI.       R. Owen                                                    21
XII.      E. Cabet                                                   25
XIII.     F. Engels                                                  27


CHAPTER II

THE STATISTICIANS

I.        A. M. Guerry                                               30
II.       Ad. Quetelet                                               31
III.      Edw. Ducpetiaux                                            33
IV.       L. M. Moreau-Christophe                                    37
V.        G. Mayr                                                    38
VI.       A. Corne                                                   47
VII.      H. Von Valentini                                           50
VIII.     A. Von Oettingen                                           53
IX.       H. Stursberg                                               55
X.        L. Fuld                                                    57
XI.       B. Weisz                                                   60
XII.      W. Starke                                                  62
XIII.     Rettich                                                    66
XIV.      A. Meyer                                                   68
XV.       M. Tugan-Baranowsky                                        71
XVI.      E. Tarnowsky                                               73
XVII.     H. Müller                                                  74
XVIII.    Criticism                                                  84


CHAPTER III

THE ITALIAN SCHOOL

I.        C. Lombroso                                                88
II.       R. Garofalo                                                96
III.      E. Ferri                                                   99
IV.       H. Kurella                                                136
V.        E. Fornasari di Verce                                     138
VI.       A. Niceforo                                               145


CHAPTER IV

THE FRENCH SCHOOL (THE SCHOOL OF THE ENVIRONMENT)

I.        A. Lacassagne                                             148
II.       G. Tarde                                                  149
III.      A. Corre                                                  161
IV.       L. Manouvrier                                             164
V.        A. Baer                                                   176


CHAPTER V

THE BIO-SOCIALISTS

I.        Ad. Prins                                                 178
II.       W. D. Morrison                                            181
III.      F. Von Liszt                                              187
IV.       P. Näcke                                                  190
V.        Havelock Ellis                                            192
VI.       Carroll D. Wright                                         193


CHAPTER VI

THE SPIRITUALISTS

I.        H. Joly                                                   199
II.       L. Proal                                                  203
III.      M. de Baets                                               205
IV.       Criticism                                                 207


CHAPTER VII

THE THIRD SCHOOL AND THE SOCIALISTS

I.        F. Turati                                                 210
II.       B. Battaglia                                              214
III.      N. Colajanni                                              220
IV.       A. Bebel                                                  227
V.        P. Lafargue                                               229
VI.       H. Denis                                                  235
VII.      H. Lux                                                    237
VIII.     P. Hirsch                                                 241


CHAPTER VIII

CONCLUSIONS                                                         244


PART TWO

BOOK I

THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM AND ITS CONSEQUENCES


CHAPTER I

THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM                                         247


CHAPTER II

SOCIAL CONDITION OF THE DIFFERENT CLASSES

A.        The Bourgeoisie                                           263
B.        The Petty Bourgeoisie                                     267
C.        The Proletariat                                           269
D.        The Lower Proletariat                                     275


CHAPTER III

THE RELATION OF THE SEXES AND OF THE FAMILY

A.        Marriage                                                  291
B.        The Family                                                307
C.        Prostitution                                              321


CHAPTER IV

ALCOHOLISM                                                          357


CHAPTER V

MILITARISM                                                          374


BOOK II

CRIMINALITY


CHAPTER I

GENERAL CONSIDERATIONS

A.        Definition of Crime                                       377
B.        The Origin of Egoistic Acts in General                    381
C.        Egoistic Tendencies Resulting from the Present
          Economic System and its Consequences                      401
          a.    The Present Economic System                         402
          b.    The Proportion in which the Different Classes
                are Guilty of Crime                                 436
          c.    Marriage                                            449
          d.    The Criminality of Women                            463
          e.    The Family                                          478
          f.    Prostitution                                        504
          g.    Alcoholism                                          508
          h.    Militarism                                          516
          i.    The Penalty                                         519
          j.    Imitation                                           528
          k.    Conclusions                                         532
D.        Individual Differences                                    534
E.        The Classification of Crime                               536


CHAPTER II

ECONOMIC CRIMES

A.        Vagrancy and Mendicity                                    546
B.        Theft and Analogous Crimes                                563
          a.    Thefts Committed from Poverty                       564
          b.    Theft Committed from Cupidity                       571
          c.    Crimes Committed by Professional Criminals          579
C.        Robbery and Analogous Crimes                              589
D.        Fraudulent Bankruptcy, Adulteration of Food, and
          Analogous Crimes                                          599


CHAPTER III

SEXUAL CRIMES

A.        Adultery                                                  609
B.        Rape and Indecent Assaults upon Adults                    612
C.        Rape and Indecent Assaults upon Children                  621


CHAPTER IV

CRIMES FROM VENGEANCE AND OTHER MOTIVES

A.        Crimes Committed from Vengeance                           625
B.        Infanticide                                               644


CHAPTER V

POLITICAL CRIMES                                                    648


CHAPTER VI

PATHOLOGICAL CRIMES                                                 656


CHAPTER VII

CONCLUSIONS                                                         667


BIBLIOGRAPHY                                                        673

INDEX                                                               701








GENERAL INTRODUCTION TO THE MODERN CRIMINAL SCIENCE SERIES.


At the National Conference of Criminal Law and Criminology, held in
Chicago, at Northwestern University, in June, 1909, the American
Institute of Criminal Law and Criminology was organized; and, as a part
of its work, the following resolution was passed:

“Whereas, it is exceedingly desirable that important treatises on
criminology in foreign languages be made readily accessible in the
English language, Resolved, that the president appoint a committee of
five with power to select such treatises as in their judgment should be
translated, and to arrange for their publication.”

The Committee appointed under this Resolution has made careful
investigation of the literature of the subject, and has consulted by
frequent correspondence. It has selected several works from among the
mass of material. It has arranged with publisher, with authors, and
with translators, for the immediate undertaking and rapid progress of
the task. It realizes the necessity of educating the professions and
the public by the wide diffusion of information on this subject. It
desires here to explain the considerations which have moved it in
seeking to select the treatises best adapted to the purpose.

For the community at large, it is important to recognize that criminal
science is a larger thing than criminal law. The legal profession in
particular has a duty to familiarize itself with the principles of that
science, as the sole means for intelligent and systematic improvement
of the criminal law.

Two centuries ago, while modern medical science was still young,
medical practitioners proceeded upon two general assumptions: one as to
the cause of disease, the other as to its treatment. As to the cause of
disease,—disease was sent by the inscrutable will of God. No man could
fathom that will, nor its arbitrary operation. As to the treatment of
disease, there were believed to be a few remedial agents of universal
efficacy. Calomel and blood-letting, for example, were two of the
principal ones. A larger or smaller dose of calomel, a greater or less
quantity of bloodletting,—this blindly indiscriminate mode of treatment
was regarded as orthodox for all common varieties of ailment. And so
his calomel pill and his bloodletting lancet were carried everywhere
with him by the doctor.

Nowadays, all this is past, in medical science. As to the causes of
disease, we know that they are facts of nature,—various, but
distinguishable by diagnosis and research, and more or less capable of
prevention or control or counter-action. As to the treatment, we now
know that there are various specific modes of treatment for specific
causes or symptoms, and that the treatment must be adapted to the
cause. In short, the individualization of disease, in cause and in
treatment, is the dominant truth of modern medical science.

The same truth is now known about crime; but the understanding and the
application of it are just opening upon us. The old and still dominant
thought is, as to cause, that a crime is caused by the inscrutable
moral free will of the human being, doing or not doing the crime, just
as it pleases; absolutely free in advance, at any moment of time, to
choose or not to choose the criminal act, and therefore in itself the
sole and ultimate cause of crime. As to treatment, there still are just
two traditional measures, used in varying doses for all kinds of crime
and all kinds of persons,—jail, or a fine (for death is now employed in
rare cases only). But modern science, here as in medicine, recognizes
that crime also (like disease) has natural causes. It need not be
asserted for one moment that crime is a disease. But it does have
natural causes,—that is, circumstances which work to produce it in a
given case. And as to treatment, modern science recognizes that penal
or remedial treatment cannot possibly be indiscriminate and
machine-like, but must be adapted to the causes, and to the man as
affected by those causes. Common sense and logic alike require,
inevitably, that the moment we predicate a specific cause for an
undesirable effect, the remedial treatment must be specifically adapted
to that cause.

Thus the great truth of the present and the future, for criminal
science, is the individualization of penal treatment,—for that man, and
for the cause of that man’s crime.

Now this truth opens up a vast field for re-examination. It means that
we must study all the possible data that can be causes of crime,—the
man’s heredity, the man’s physical and moral make-up, his emotional
temperament, the surroundings of his youth, his present home, and other
conditions,—all the influencing circumstances. And it means that the
effect of different methods of treatment, old or new, for different
kinds of men and of causes, must be studied, experimented, and
compared. Only in this way can accurate knowledge be reached, and new
efficient measures be adopted.

All this has been going on in Europe for forty years past, and in
limited fields in this country. All the branches of science that can
help have been working,—anthropology, medicine, psychology, economics,
sociology, philanthropy, penology. The law alone has abstained. The
science of law is the one to be served by all this. But the public in
general and the legal profession in particular have remained either
ignorant of the entire subject or indifferent to the entire scientific
movement. And this ignorance or indifference has blocked the way to
progress in administration.

The Institute therefore takes upon itself, as one of its aims, to
inculcate the study of modern criminal science, as a pressing duty for
the legal profession and for the thoughtful community at large. One of
its principal modes of stimulating and aiding this study is to make
available in the English language the most useful treatises now extant
in the Continental languages. Our country has started late. There is
much to catch up with, in the results reached elsewhere. We shall, to
be sure, profit by the long period of argument and theorizing and
experimentation which European thinkers and workers have passed
through. But to reap that profit, the results of their experience must
be made accessible in the English language.

The effort, in selecting this series of translations, has been to
choose those works which best represent the various schools of thought
in criminal science, the general results reached, the points of contact
or of controversy, and the contrasts of method—having always in view
that class of works which have a more than local value and could best
be serviceable to criminal science in our country. As the science has
various aspects and emphases—the anthropological, psychological,
sociological, legal, statistical, economic, pathological—due regard was
paid, in the selection, to a representation of all these aspects. And
as the several Continental countries have contributed in different ways
to these various aspects,—France, Germany, Italy, most abundantly, but
the others each its share,—the effort was made also to recognize the
different contributions as far as feasible.

The selection made by the Committee, then, represents its judgment of
the works that are most useful and most instructive for the purpose of
translation. It is its conviction that this Series, when completed,
will furnish the American student of criminal science a systematic and
sufficient acquaintance with the controlling doctrines and methods that
now hold the stage of thought in Continental Europe. Which of the
various principles and methods will prove best adapted to help our
problems can only be told after our students and workers have tested
them in our own experience. But it is certain that we must first
acquaint ourselves with these results of a generation of European
thought.

In closing, the Committee thinks it desirable to refer the members of
the Institute, for purposes of further investigation of the literature,
to the “Preliminary Bibliography of Modern Criminal Law and
Criminology” (Bulletin No. 1 of the Gary Library of Law of Northwestern
University), already issued to members of the Conference. The Committee
believes that some of the Anglo-American works listed therein will be
found useful.


Committee on Translations.

Chairman, John H. Wigmore,
            Professor of Law in Northwestern University, Chicago.
          Ernst Freund,
            Professor of Law in the University of Chicago.
          Maurice Parmelee,
            Professor of Sociology in the State University of Missouri.
          Roscoe Pound,
            Professor of Law in Harvard University.
          Edward Lindsay,
            Of the Warren, Pa., Bar.
          Wm. W. Smithers,
            Secretary of the Comparative Law Bureau of the American Bar
            Association, Philadelphia, Pa.








EDITORIAL PREFACE TO THE PRESENT VOLUME.

By Edward Lindsey.


Any adequate study of the phenomena of crime and of the criminal must
take into account the economic phase—must consider the subject matter
of the study from the economic standpoint; for while few will follow
the socialist theorists in the controlling importance they assign to
the economic factors of social life it is nevertheless manifest that
these factors are powerful elements in the totality of social
conditions and must be given due consideration in the survey of all
societal phenomena, including that of crime. The work selected to
represent this viewpoint in the Modern Criminal Science Series is that
of one of the younger criminalists—an able and thorough study of the
effect of economic conditions on crime and distinguished by the
extensive and critical use made of a wide range of statistical data.

William Adrian Bonger, the author of the work here translated, of
Amsterdam, Holland, is a Dutch Publicist, a pupil of Professor Van
Hamel, well known as one of the founders of the International Union of
Penal Law and the most eminent of Dutch students of criminology. He was
born at Amsterdam, September 6, 1876, and received the degree of Doctor
in Law from the University of Amsterdam in June, 1905. The first part
of the present work, which consists of a survey, with copious extracts
and critical comments, of the previous literature upon the subject of
the relation of crime to economic conditions is a revision of a thesis
originally presented at the University.

Dr. Bonger is also the author of “Religion and Crime: A Criminological
Study”; Leiden, 1913, and numerous articles in Dutch and German
periodicals. Among these are the following in “Nieuwe Tijd” (The New
Age), a well-known Dutch socialist review: “An Apology for War”, a
critical review of “Die Philosophie des Krieges” by Professor Steinmetz
(1908); “Capital and Income in the Netherlands” (1910); “Marxism and
Revisionism” (1910); “Crime and Socialism: A Contribution to the Study
of Criminality in the Netherlands” (1911); and “Religion and Irreligion
in the Netherlands” (1911). Two noteworthy contributions to “Neue Zeit”
are “Cesare Lombroso” in Vol. XXVIII, number one (1910), and
“Verbrechen und Sozialismus: Zugleich ein Beitrag zum Studium der
Kriminalität im Deutschland” in Vol. XXX, number two (1912). In 1912
also appeared “The Social Factors of Crime and their Significance in
Comparison with the Individual Causes” in Vol. XXIII of the
“Tijdschrift voor Strafrecht”, the only Dutch journal of criminal law.

In the first part of this work, instead of stating in his own language
the views expressed in the previous literature on the subject Dr.
Bonger has by extracts from the various authors given us their opinions
in their own language, adding brief critical comments of his own. The
second part contains Dr. Bonger’s own discussion of the phenomena of
crime based upon an unusually thorough collection of statistical data
and the elaboration of his views. In the selection of authors from whom
he quotes Dr. Bonger shows his sympathy with the social philosophy of
socialism which appears as well in the exposition of his own
explanation of criminality; but the facts which he collects together
with the evidence on which they rest are so explicitly set forth and
his own conclusions so carefully distinguished that the value of the
study is not diminished even for those who are not disposed to accept
his social philosophy.

Dr. Bonger sees clearly that the concept of crime is a social and not a
biological one. It is the social value or harmfulness of acts or
conduct that is involved in the concept and if we use terms that have a
predominantly biological connotation such as “normal” or “abnormal”, we
must be careful to distinguish that use as referring to a social
standard or we will be in danger of a confusion of thought. That some
of the acts which society has classed as crimes may be deemed
pathological is incidental; it is not on this account that they are
termed crimes but because they are socially detrimental. That some of
the individuals who have committed crimes may be called “abnormal” is
incidental; it is not because of this that they are classified as
criminals. That the economic factor has a large influence in connection
with that kind of conduct the social significance of which stamps it as
criminal the author abundantly shows. The extent to which this is the
case and the extent to which the economic conditions involved are
inherent in our present social organization are matters on which there
will be difference of opinion with the author. Dr. Bonger’s expressed
belief that his main positions will be received without sympathy in
this country we venture to think will not prove to be well founded. On
the contrary so clearly has he set them forth and so well has he
supported them that they can hardly fail of appreciation. If this work
serves to some extent as a corrective to a too prevalent tendency
toward a confusion of thought between biological and social concepts
and standards in the study of human conduct—and especially that kind of
conduct which we have deemed so socially detrimental as to brand as
crime—its inclusion in this series will be amply justified.


Warren, Pa.
February 26, 1916.








INTRODUCTION TO THIS VOLUME.

By Frank H. Norcross. [1]


Dr. Bonger’s work—“Criminality and Economic Conditions”—will arrest the
attention of students of criminology, sociology and kindred subjects.
In it, also, the political economist may delve with profit.

The eminent scholar and author in his preface to the American edition
expresses the conviction that his “ideas about the etiology of crime
will not be shared by a great many readers of the American edition,”
and, also, “that the book is sure to meet with many disapproving
critics on this side of the ocean.” The distinguished author may be
agreeably disappointed in the number of American readers who will agree
in a large measure with his conclusions as to the causes of crime
generally. I am inclined to think that the remedy which Dr. Bonger
proposes is more apt to elicit controversy than the correctness of his
diagnosis. The great value of Dr. Bonger’s work to Americans, however,
will be independent of the number of readers who concede the force of
his reasoning or accept the logic of his conclusions. Disagree with the
author’s conclusions as the reader may and its value to the reader will
not be impaired. One cannot take issue with the conclusions of a
scholar based on study and research, without an exercise of processes
of the mind valuable to the reader, and probably so to others. From the
right quantity and quality of criticism comes the truth. One of the
most valuable portions of Dr. Bonger’s work will be found in his own
criticisms of the writings of other European authors, particularly
those comprising the so-called Italian and French schools.

“Criminality and Economic Conditions” is the nearest approach to an
exhaustive treatment of the question of the agencies productive of
crime which has thus far been published in this country. The work is a
result of great study and research, and little existing data can have
been overlooked. Agree or not with the conclusions of the author, doubt
the force of his reasoning if one will, nevertheless, such reasoning
and conclusions have their basis in statistics and data furnished, from
which other reasoning or conclusions may be formed if the reader thinks
the author’s conclusions are not supported by the facts.

Whether existing economic conditions are fundamentally wrong, and crime
is but the natural concomitant of a false economic basis upon which
society is organized, is a controversial question which is so
forcefully presented by the author that the reader must concede that
his views have been presented by a master.

Dr. Bonger’s thesis, doubtless, will have the effect of increasing the
number of Americans who regard environment as the greatest contributory
cause of crime and who place heredity or innate criminality in a
subordinate position, though many may continue to regard these matters
as of greater importance than the author attributes to them. The author
does not hesitate to express his contempt for the theory recently
espoused by some Americans that “sterilization” may be an effective
method of reducing the “army of criminals.” “One should be inclined to
ask,” he says, “if the advocates of ‘sterilization’ have never heard of
Australia, where a considerable number of inhabitants have descended
from the worst of criminals and where yet the rate of criminality is
low.” The Australian might reply that this is not a fair test, for at
the time England was transporting so many of her criminals to
Australia, the English criminal code was so drastic that “the worst of
criminals” constituted but a small per cent of those who became its
victims. But this observation does not militate against the correctness
of the Doctor’s observation that “sterilization” is “as useful as the
efforts to stop with a bottle a brook in its course.” If the advocates
of “sterilization” are wrong in their theory, it is only illustrative
of the fact that we Americans have been so busy developing a new
country that, until very recent years, we gave no thought to the
immense problem of the causes of crime, or attempted to apply to the
subject any sort of intelligent, to say nothing of scientific,
consideration. When at last it dawned upon a few of the American people
that the cost in dollars and cents of dealing with our crime problem,
to say nothing of the incidental economic waste, exceeded a billion
dollars annually, or, as Professor Münsterberg in one of his books
forcibly puts it: “that this country spends annually five hundred
millions of dollars more on fighting the existing crime than on all its
works of charity, education, and religion”,—it began to be considered
worth while to study this tremendous social problem with a view, if
possible, of improving conditions. Those who investigated the subject
found little in the way of statistics or reliable data upon which to
base a study of conditions with a view of applying remedies. Some few
had written upon various phases of the subject. It was not, however,
until the organization of the American Institute of Criminal Law and
Criminology in 1909 that intelligent direction along practical lines
was given to a study by Americans of this great social and economic
problem. The Journal of the Institute was the first periodical of its
kind published in the English language. In Continental Europe a number
of such journals were being published and many students of the problem
had contributed valuable works upon different phases of the subject.
The American Institute has deemed the quickest way for Americans to
become abreast of the best modern thought on criminal law and
criminology, is to make available for American readers the best
scientific thought of European writers, hence, “The Modern Criminal
Science Series,” of which Dr. Bonger’s work becomes one of the most
valuable volumes.

Until very recent years, most American judges and prosecuting attorneys
gave little thought to the underlying causes of crime. It was the
general assumption that courts and court officers had performed their
full functions when the guilt or innocence of a defendant had been
determined and he was discharged or committed to some penal
institution. Here again little thought was given to the one
incarcerated other than to hold and generally to exploit him until by
law he was entitled to be discharged. Those whose province it was to
get men into prison and those whose duty it was to keep them in custody
gave little attention to the question whether the convict was a better
or a worse unit of society when he came out than when he entered upon a
prison term. Even less thought was given to the more important
question—why so many commit crime at all. If normal human beings under
normal conditions do not commit crime, then crime is evidence of the
abnormal, either in the person or in the condition. If this is a
correct hypothesis, then the administration of criminal law must to a
greater degree in the future than in the past be predicated upon a
comprehension and due consideration of this fact.

If, in order to materially reduce the quantum of crime, it is necessary
to change the economic basis upon which modern society rests and
reorganize it “based upon the community of the means of production”,
then the outlook for an early diminution in the volume of crime may not
be overly encouraging. Such a change in the economic basis of society
is hardly to be expected otherwise than as the result of the slow
process of social evolution. Progress in this respect has not been
perceptibly rapid since Moses gave to the world the Book of
Deuteronomy. Many abuses of our present economic system, however, may
be modified or abolished without waiting for or conceding the necessity
of the change which the eminent scholar holds is fundamental.

Again, in conclusion, let me reiterate that the value of Dr. Bonger’s
work does not depend upon an agreement with all the views of the
author. The book will bring to the American reader a depth and breadth
of view most valuable to the administrators of criminal law and to
those interested in the wider field of general social progress.


Carson City, Nevada,
February 18, 1916.








TRANSLATOR’S NOTE.


This translation is based upon the Amsterdam edition of 1905, but the
translator has been furnished by the author not only with special notes
for the American edition, but also with the latest corrections to the
French text. Dr. Bonger has also furnished a revised bibliography, and
kindly wrote the American preface in English. In the translation some
slight condensation of the work has been made, with the approval of the
committee, by the omission of a few passages of a parenthetical nature,
in quotations and notes. The very valuable bibliographical notes have
been retained intact. Grateful acknowledgment is due to the Editorial
Committee for suggestions as to some difficult legal terms, and to Mr.
Georgio de Grassi for assistance in the translation of Italian
passages.


Henry P. Horton.

Ithaca, N.Y.,
September, 1914.








CRIMINALITY AND ECONOMIC CONDITIONS


PREFACE TO THE AMERICAN EDITION.


The resolution of the “Committee on Translations of the American
Institute of Criminal Law and Criminology” to include my book
“Criminalité et conditions économiques” among the European works, that
were assigned for translation was welcomed by me with gladness. The
fact that the difference of language is an obstacle for many to become
acquainted with a book, is for its author very disagreeable. This was
also the reason which obliged me to publish my work not in my own but
in the French language.

I am fully convinced that my ideas about the etiology of crime will not
be shared by a great many readers of the American edition. As far as I
can see, in the English-speaking countries the causes of criminality
are sought in man himself rather than in his surroundings. Heredity,
too, is considered there of great importance. Hence the attempts to
reduce the army of criminals by so-called “sterilization.” Against this
point of view my book is in sharp opposition; I consider it one of the
most fatal errors. There was a time in Europe when it was thought with
Lombroso that crime was rooted in man himself; the progress of
sociology has shown more and more clearly that the roots are found
outside man, in society. There is nothing more variable than man! That
heredity plays a great part on the scene of criminality has never been
proved. Have the advocates of “sterilization”, one should be inclined
to ask, never heard of Australia, where a considerable number of the
inhabitants are descended from the worst of criminals, and where yet
the rate of criminality is low? The army of prostitution has been for a
great many centuries by far more “sterile” than the army of criminals
can ever be made, and yet prostitution is not decreased; the increase
and decrease of this phenomena is ruled by social factors. In short,
the effect of “sterilization” seems to me as useful as the efforts to
stop with a bottle a brook in its course, as Manouvrier once called it.
On the other hand I beg the adherents of the individualistic theory of
crime to take into consideration that in some European countries the
beginning of the rise of the lower classes, who form the greatest
contingent of criminals, has been sufficient to arrest the increase of
crime, even in many cases to occasion a decrease.

My book will thus be sure to meet with many disapproving critics on the
other side of the ocean. I fear them not. If only facts are opposed to
facts, truth will come to light. “Du choc des opinions jaillit la
vérité!”

According to my undertaking I have stated in notes the principal
literature of the latest years. In concert with the desire of the
Committee I have shortened the text as much as possible. The whole
passage about “race and crime” I have omitted because—maintaining in
general what I had written about it—I now have much more to say on the
subject, but the space therefor was not at my disposition. For the same
reason I left the passage on “Physical Environment and Crime” as it
was. The treatment in detail of both these questions will take place in
due time elsewhere.

I will not close this preface without assuring the Committee on
Translations how highly I value their broad view and large-minded
resolution to give a hearing to one whose opinions differ so much from
the usual. To my translator, my hearty thanks for the good care
bestowed on my book.


W. A. Bonger.

Amsterdam,
June, 1914.








THE AUTHOR’S PREFACE TO THE ORIGINAL EDITION.


Honorable mention has been given to the first part of this work, which
was written upon a subject proposed by the juridical faculty of the
University of Amsterdam, and entitled “A Systematic and Critical
Exposition of the Literature Dealing with the Relation between
Criminality and Economic Conditions.” To this exposition I have added
the opinions of some additional authors, and have treated some others
more fully than in the original; but on the whole this part of the work
has been little changed. The second part, on the other hand, is almost
entirely new; though it is true that in my thesis I had already marked
out a line of investigation which, in my opinion, required a profound
study of the relation between criminality and economic conditions. The
period of one year fixed by the faculty was too limited a time in which
to give more than a brief survey of the question. I have left the
exposition as it was without restating it in the second part (now the
more important division of the work), although I am aware that
objections might be made, especially as to the form. However, I have
not felt that these are of sufficient importance to demand a complete
recasting of the work.

I take advantage of this opportunity to express my sincere thanks to
those who have expressed their good will by lending me their aid;
especially to my highly esteemed colleague, Professor G. A. van Hamel,
and my friends Dr. A. Aletrino and N. W. Posthumus.


Amsterdam,
February, 1905.








    I have taken great pains neither to deride human actions,
    nor to deplore them, nor to detest them, but to understand them.

                                                              —Spinoza.








INTRODUCTION.


In systematizing the literature of my subject I have pursued the
following method: I begin with some significant extracts from authors
who wrote before the birth of modern criminal science. After these I
take up the statisticians, that is to say, those who, without belonging
to any special school of criminologists, have treated the subject
principally by the aid of statistics. Next I give an exposition of the
school which insists especially upon the individual factors in crime,
and ascribes only a secondary place to economic factors (the Italian
school); following this I treat of the school which considers the rôle
played by environment as very important (the French school); and
afterwards that of the bio-sociological doctrine which forms the
synthesis of the two schools. Then follow the “spiritualists”, that is
to say the religious authors who have been more or less influenced by
modern criminal science; and finally, the authors who belong to the
“terza scuola”, and the socialists who consider the influence of
economic conditions as being very important or even decisive. The
authors coming under the same heading have been treated in
chronological order.

Like every classification this is more or less arbitrary. Several
authors might have been placed under two different headings. We may add
that as time goes on the differences between the Italian and French
schools are becoming less and less marked, so that their opinions and
those of the bio-sociologists no longer show any great divergences as
far as our subject is concerned.








PART ONE.

CRITICAL EXPOSITION OF THE LITERATURE DEALING WITH
THE RELATION BETWEEN CRIMINALITY AND ECONOMIC CONDITIONS.


CHAPTER I.

THE PRECURSORS.

AUTHORS WHO TREATED THE SUBJECT BEFORE THE BIRTH
OF MODERN CRIMINAL SCIENCE.

I.

THOMAS MORE. [2]

In the first part of his “Utopia” More severely criticises the economic
conditions of his time in England, and adds some observations upon the
criminality of that period.

Raphael Hythloday, whom More makes the speaker in his work, and through
whom he expresses his own opinions, says:

“It chanced on a certain day, when I sat at the Cardinal’s table, there
was also a certain lay man cunning in the laws of your realm. Who, I
cannot tell whereof taking occasion, began diligently and earnestly to
praise that strait and rigorous justice, which at that time was there
executed upon felons, who, as he said, were for the most part twenty
hanged together upon one gallows. And, seeing so few escaped
punishment, he said he could not choose but greatly wonder and marvel,
how and by what evil luck it should so come to pass, that thieves
nevertheless were in every place so rife and so rank.

“Nay, Sir, quod I (for I durst boldly speak my mind before the
Cardinal) marvel nothing hereat; for this punishment of thieves passeth
the limits of justice, and is also very hurtful to the public weal. For
it is too extreme and cruel a punishment for theft, and yet not
sufficient to refrain and withhold men from theft. For simple theft is
not so great an offense, that it ought to be punished with death.
Neither is there any punishment so horrible, that it can keep them from
stealing, which have no other craft whereby to get their living.
Therefore in this point, not you only, but also the most part of the
world, be like evil schoolmasters, which be readier to beat, than to
teach their scholars. For great and horrible punishments be appointed
for thieves, whereas much rather provision should have been made, that
there were some means, whereby they might get their living, so that no
man should be driven to this extreme necessity, first to steal, and
then to die.

“Yes (quod he) this matter is well enough provided for already. There
be handicrafts, there is husbandry to get their living by, if they
would not willingly be nought. Nay, quod I, you shall not scape so; for
first of all, I will speak nothing of them that come home out of the
wars, maimed and lame, as not long ago, out of Blackheath field, and a
little before that, out of the wars in France; such, I say, as put
their lives in jeopardy for public weal’s or the king’s sake, and by
reason of weakness or lameness be not able to occupy their old crafts,
and be too aged to learn new; of them I will speak nothing, forasmuch
as wars have their ordinary recourse. But let us consider those things
that chance daily before our eyes. First there is a great number of
gentlemen, which can not be content to live idle themselves, like
drones, of that which others have labored for; their tenants, I mean,
whom they poll and shave to the quick, by raising their rents (for this
only point of frugality do they use, men else through their lavish and
prodigal spending, able to bring themselves to very beggary) these
gentlemen, I say, do not only live in idleness themselves, but also
carry about with them at their tails a great flock or train of idle and
loitering serving men, which never learn any craft whereby to get their
livings. These men as soon as their master is dead, or be sick
themselves, be incontinent thrust out of doors. For gentlemen had
rather keep idle persons, than sick men, and many times the dead man’s
heir is not able to maintain so great a house, and keep so many serving
men as his father did. Then in the mean season they that be thus
destitute of service, either starve for hunger, or manfully play the
thieves. For what would you have them do? When they have wandered
abroad so long, until they have worn threadbare their apparel, and also
impaired their health, then gentlemen because of their pale and sickly
faces, and patched coats, will not take them into service. And
husbandmen dare not set them a work, knowing well enough that he is
nothing meet to do true and faithful service to a poor man with a spade
and a mattock for small wages and hard fare, which being daintily and
tenderly pampered up in idleness and pleasure, was wont with a sword
and buckler by his side to jet through the street with a bragging look,
and to think himself to be as good as any man’s mate.

“Nay, by Saint Mary, sir (quod the lawyer), not so. For this kind of
man must we make the most of. For in them as men of stouter stomachs,
bolder spirits, and manlier courages than handicrafts men and plowmen
be, doth consist the whole power, strength, and puissance of our army,
when we must fight in battle. Forsooth, sir, as well you might say
(quod I) that for war’s sake we must cherish thieves. For surely you
shall never lack thieves while you have them. No, nor thieves be not
the most false and faint-hearted soldiers, nor soldiers be not the
cowardliest thieves; so well these two crafts agree together. But this
fault, though it be much used among you, yet is not peculiar to you
only, but common also almost to all nations. Yet France besides this is
troubled and infected with a much sorer plague. The whole realm is
filled and besieged with hired soldiers in peace time (if that be
peace) which be brought in under the same color and pretense, that hath
persuaded you to keep these idle serving men. For these wise fools and
very archdolts thought the wealth of the country herein to consist, if
there were ever in readiness a strong and sure garrison, specially of
old practised soldiers, for they put no trust at all in men
unexercised. And therefore they must be forced to seek for war, to the
end that they may have practised soldiers and cunning manslayers, lest
that (as it is prettily said by Sallust) their hands and their minds
through idleness and lack of exercise, should wax dull. But how
pernicious and pestilent a thing it is to maintain such beasts, the
Frenchmen by their own harms have learned, and the examples of the
Romans, Carthaginians, Syrians, and of many other countries do
manifestly declare. For not only the empire, but also the fields and
cities of all these, by divers occasions have been overrunned and
destroyed by their own armies beforehand had in a readiness. Now how
unnecessary a thing this is, hereby it may appear, that the French
soldiers, which from their youth have been practised and inured in
feats of arms, do not crack nor advance themselves to have very often
gotten the upper hand and mastery of your new made and unpractised
soldiers. But in this point I will not use many words, lest perchance I
may seem to flatter you.

“No, nor those same handicraftmen of yours in cities, nor yet the rude
and uplandish plowmen of the country, are not supposed to be greatly
afraid of your gentlemen’s idle serving men, unless it be such as be
not of body or stature correspondent to their strength and courage, or
else whose bold stomachs be discouraged through poverty. Thus you may
see, that it is not to be feared lest they should be effeminated, if
they were brought up in good crafts and laborsome works, whereby to get
their livings, whose stout and sturdy bodies (for gentlemen vouchsafe
to corrupt and spill none but picked and chosen men) now either by
reason of rest and idleness be brought to weakness or else by easy and
womanly exercises be made feeble and unable to endure hardness. Truly
howsoever the case standeth, this methinketh is nothing available to
the public weal, for war’s sake, which you never have, but when you
will yourselves, to keep and maintain an innumerable flock of that sort
of men, that be so troublesome and noyous in peace, whereof you ought
to have a thousand times more regard than of war.

“But yet this is not the only necessary cause of stealing. There is
another, which, as I suppose, is proper and peculiar to you Englishmen
alone. What is that? quod the Cardinal. Forsooth my Lord (quod I) your
sheep that were wont to be so meek and tame, and so small eaters, now
as I hear say, be become so great devourers and so wild, that they eat
up, and swallow down the very men themselves. They consume, destroy,
and devour whole fields, houses, and cities. For look in what parts of
the realm doth grow the finest and therefore dearest wool, there
noblemen and gentlemen, yea and certain abbots, holy men no doubt, not
contenting themselves with the yearly revenues and profits, that were
wont to grow to their forefathers and predecessors of their lands, nor
being content that they live in rest and pleasure nothing profiting,
yea much noying the public weal, leave no ground for tillage, they
inclose all into pastures; they throw down houses; they pluck down
towns, and leave nothing standing, but only the church to be made a
sheephouse. And as though you lost no land by forests, chases, lands,
and parks, those good holy men turn all dwelling places and all
glebeland into desolation and wilderness. Therefore that one covetous
and unsatiable cormorant and very plague of his native country may
compass about and enclose many thousand acres of ground together within
one pale or hedge, the husbandmen be thrust out of their own, or else
either by fraud, or by violent oppression they be put besides it, or by
wrongs and injuries they be so wearied, that they be compelled to sell
all. By one means therefore or by other, either by hook or crook they
must needs depart away, poor, silly, wretched souls, men, women,
husbands, wives, fatherless children, widows, woeful mothers, with
their young babes, and their whole household small in substance and
much in number, as husbandry requireth many hands. Away they trudge, I
say, out of their known and accustomed houses, finding no place to rest
in. All their household stuff, which is very little worth, though it
might well abide the sale; yet being suddenly thrust out, they be
constrained to sell it for a thing of nought. And when they have
wandered abroad till that be spent, what can they do but steal and then
justly pardy be hanged, or else go about begging. Yet then they also be
cast into prison as vagabonds, because they go about and work not, whom
no man will set to work, though they never so willingly profer
themselves thereto. For one shepherd or herdman is enough to eat up
that ground with cattle, to the occupying whereof about husbandry many
hands were requisite.

“And this is also the cause why victuals be now in many places dearer.
Yea, besides this the price of wool is so risen, that poor folks which
were wont to work it, and make cloth thereof, be now able to buy none
at all. And by this means very many be forced to forsake work, and to
give themselves to idleness. For after that so much ground was inclosed
for pasture, an infinite multitude of sheep died of the rot, such
vengeance God took of their inordinate and insatiable covetousness,
sending among the sheep that pestiferous murrain, which much more
justly should have fallen of the sheep-masters’ own heads. And though
the number of sheep increase never so fast, yet the price falleth not
one mite, because there be so few sellers. For they be almost all comen
into a few rich men’s hands, whom no need forceth to sell before they
lust, and they lust not before they may sell as dear as they lust.

“Now the same cause bringeth in like dearth of the other kinds of
cattle, yea and that so much the more, because that after the farms
plucked down and husbandry decayed, there is no man that careth about
the breeding of young stock. For these rich men bring not up the young
ones of great cattle as they do lambs. But first they buy them abroad
very cheap and afterward, when they be fatted in their pastures, they
sell them again exceeding dear. And therefore (as I suppose) the whole
incommodity hereof is not yet felt. For yet they make dearth only in
those places where they sell. But when they fetch them away from thence
where they be bred faster than they can be brought up; then shall there
also be felt great dearth, stock beginning there to fail where the ware
is bought. Thus the unreasonable covetousness of a few hath turned that
thing to the utter undoing of your island, in the which thing the chief
felicity of your realm did consist. For this great dearth of victuals
causeth men to keep as little houses and as small hospitality as they
possibly may, and to put away their servants, whither, I pray you, but
abegging or else (which these gentle bloods and stout stomachs will
sooner set their minds unto) astealing?

“Now to amend the matter, to this wretched beggary and miserable
poverty is joined great wantonness, importunate superfluity and
excessive riot. For not only gentlemen’s servants, but also
handicraftman, yea and almost the plowmen of the country, with all
other sorts of people, use much strange and proud newfangledness in
their apparel, and too much prodigal riot and sumptuous fare at their
table. Now bawds, queans, whores, harlots, strumpets, brothel-houses,
stews, and yet another stews, winetaverns, alehouses and tippling
houses, with so many naughty, lewd, and unlawful games, as dice, cards,
tables, tennis, bowls, quoits, do not all these send the haunters of
them straight astealing when their money is gone?

“Cast out these pernicious abominations, make a law that they, which
plucked down farms and towns of husbandry, shall reëdify them, or else
yield and uprender the possession thereof to such as will go to the
cost of building them anew. Suffer not these rich men to buy up all, to
engross and forestall, and with their monopoly to keep the market alone
as please them. Let not so many be brought up in idleness, let
husbandry and tillage be restored, let clothworking be renewed, that
there may be honest labors for this idle sort to pass their time
profitably, which hitherto either poverty has caused to be thieves, or
else now to be vagabonds, or idle serving men, and shortly will be
thieves. Doubtless unless you find a remedy for these enormities, you
shall in vain advance yourselves of executing justice upon felons. For
this justice is more beautiful in appearance, and more flourishing to
the show, than either just or profitable. For by suffering your youth
wantonly and viciously to be brought up, and to be infected, even from
their tender age, by little and little with vice, then in God’s name to
be punished, when they commit the same faults after being come to man’s
state, which from their youth they were ever like to do; in this point,
I pray you, what other thing do you, than make thieves and then punish
them?” [3]




II.

JEAN MESLIER. [4]

In speaking of the faults which cling to society Meslier, among other
things, says the following about crime:

“Another abuse, and one that is almost universally accepted and
authorized in the world, is the appropriation of the wealth of the soil
by individuals, in place of which all ought to possess it equally in
common and enjoy it equally in common. I mean all those of the same
district or territory, so that they as well as those who inhabit the
same city, town, village, or parish should compose but one great
family. They should all regard themselves as being brothers and sisters
one to another and all children of the same fathers and mothers, who,
for this reason ought to love one another as brothers and sisters and,
in consequence, live peaceably together, having all things common. All
should have the same or similar food, should be equally well lodged,
clothed and shod, but should also apply themselves equally to their
business, that is to say, to work or to some other honest and useful
employment, each following his or her profession, or whatever is most
necessary and fitting to be done according to the time or season or the
things especially needed. And all this should be done, not under the
direction of those who would like to dominate over others tyrannically
and imperiously, but only under the direction of the wisest and best
intentioned, for the maintenance and advancement of the public weal.
All cities and other communities should also on their own account take
great pains to make alliances with their neighbors and keep inviolable
the peace and union between them, in order to aid and succor one
another in time of need; for without this the public well-being cannot
be maintained, and the greater part of mankind must be wretched and
unhappy.

“For first, what results from this individual appropriation of the
wealth of the soil for each to enjoy it severally apart from the
others, as it seems good to him? It results that each is eager to get
as much as he can, in all sorts of ways, good and bad. For cupidity,
which is insatiable and, as we know, the root of all evils, looking
through an open door, so to speak, toward the accomplishment of its
desires, does not fail to take advantage of the opportunity, and makes
all men do whatever they can in order to have an abundance of goods and
riches, and to be so protected from indigence as to have the pleasure
and contentment of enjoying whatever they wish. From this it happens
that those who are the strongest, the most crafty, the most skilful,
and often even the most wicked and unworthy, have the largest share in
the wealth of the soil and are best provided with all the good things
of life.” [5]

“This is not all, but it also results from this abuse of which I have
been speaking, namely that wealth is so badly distributed among men,
some having everything, or at least much more than their true share,
and others having nothing, or lacking a part of what is useful and
necessary ... it results from this, I say, that hatred and envy first
of all arise. From these spring in turn murmurings, complainings,
commotions, insurrections, and wars, which cause an infinity of evils
among men. From these again proceed thousands and millions of
mischievous lawsuits which the private owners are obliged to have among
themselves to defend their property and to maintain what they consider
their rights. These suits cause thousands of pains to the body, and
tens of thousands of disquietudes to the mind, and often enough cause
the entire ruin of both parties. From this it also happens that those
who have nothing, or who have not all that they need, are constrained
and obliged to employ evil means to get subsistence. From this come the
frauds, deceptions, rascalities, injustices, extortions, robberies,
thefts, murders, assassinations, and brigandages which cause such an
infinity of evils among men.” [6]




III.

J. J. ROUSSEAU.

I believe that the following observation, which I find in the
“Discourse upon the Origin and Foundations of Inequality among Men”, is
worth quoting.

“The first man who, having enclosed a piece of ground, took it into his
head to say, ‘This is mine’, and found people simple enough to believe
him, was the true founder of civil society. What crimes, wars, and
murders, what miseries and horrors would the human race have been
spared if some one had torn up the stakes, or filled the ditch, and
cried to his comrades: ‘Beware of heeding this impostor. You are lost
if you forget that the fruits of the ground belong to all, and the
ground itself to no one.’” [7]




IV.

MORELLY.

In his “Code de la nature” this author seeks to show that the harmony
in which men lived in primitive society (when common property existed)
has been destroyed by the institution of private property, which,
coming in little by little, has changed common interests into contrary
interests. He expresses himself on this point as follows:

“Every division of goods, whether equal or unequal, and all individual
appropriation of the portions so formed are what Horace calls ‘Summi
materiam mali.’ All political or moral phenomena are the effects of
this pernicious cause. It is by this that we can explain all theorems
and problems with regard to the origin, development, connection, and
affinity of virtues or vices, disorders, and crimes; also with regard
to the true motives of good or bad actions, the determinations and
perplexities of the human will, the depravity of the passions, the
inefficacy of precepts and laws to restrain them; and, finally, with
regard to the monstrous creations resulting from the aberrations of the
mind and the heart. The reason, I say, for all these things can be
ascribed to the general obstinacy of legislators about breaking or
letting any one else break the cord with which sociability was first
bound by those who usurped to their own use soil that ought to belong
indivisibly to all humanity.” [8]

Farther along he defines the same idea more exactly when he says: “Take
away property, I repeat without ceasing, and you destroy forever a
thousand factors which lead men to desperate extremities. I say that,
delivered from this tyrant, it is totally impossible that man should
give himself to crimes, that he should be a thief, an assassin, or a
conqueror. The laws which authorize property punish him, it is true,
for these crimes. Even his own remorse and fears, sprung from the
prejudices of the moral system in which he has been raised, punish him
still more. But the most severe chastisement of the offender is the
primitive and innate feeling of benevolence. This inner voice of
Nature, though commonly confined to the indifferent admonition not to
injure, has still force enough to make the criminal feel keenly.” [9]




V.

C. BECCARIA.

The following passage taken from the introduction to Beccaria’s “Des
délits et des peines” is not without importance for our subject:

“The advantages of society ought to be equally divided among all its
members. However, when men are gathered together we note a constant
tendency to collect privileges, power, and happiness in the hands of a
small minority, and to leave for the multitude only poverty and
weakness. It is only by good laws that this tendency can be checked.
But ordinarily men leave the regulation of the most important matters
to temporary laws and to the caution of the moment, or even entrust
them to the discretion of those whose interests are opposed to the best
institutions and the wisest laws.” [10]

“If we turn to history we shall see that laws, which ought to be
agreements freely made between free men, have oftenest been only the
instrument of the passions of the minority or the result of the chance
of the moment, never the work of a wise observer of human nature who
has known how to direct all the actions of the multitude to this single
end: The greatest good of the greatest number.” [11]

In Section 35 (“On Theft”) we read, among other things, as follows:

“A theft committed without violence ought to be punished merely by a
fine. It is just that he who takes the property of another should be
deprived of his own. But if theft is ordinarily the crime of poverty
and despair, if this offense is committed only by that class of
unfortunate men to whom the right of property (a terrible right and
perhaps not a necessary one) has left no possession but mere existence,
the imposition of a fine will contribute only to multiply thefts, by
increasing the number of the indigent, and robbing an innocent family
of bread to give it to a rich man who is perhaps himself a criminal.”
[12]




VI.

S. N. H. LINGUET.

In his “Théorie des lois civiles”, directed principally against
Montesquieu’s “L’esprit des lois”, in which Linguet seeks to defend the
thesis, “The spirit of the laws is Property”, there are some
interesting passages. After having shown that private property has been
founded upon violence, he treats of the origin of the laws and, at the
same time, of the causes of crime, and says:

“Among men all equal, all robust, passionate, sanguinary, and
accustomed to arms, dangerous disputes would continually arise. It
would be impossible but that chance and intelligence should produce
great inequality of fortune. He who believed that he had been injured
would wish to get justice for himself. The association formed to secure
the booty would be troubled by the difficulty of enjoying it. These
inconveniences occurred to the clearest thinkers and they sought to
find a remedy. It was a totally new art that they created. But as it is
almost always science that misleads, and as truth is never so easy to
discover as at a distance from the Doctors, they looked about to see
what route they should take.

“They thought that a primary act of violence was incontestably
necessary. They could not disavow it, since it was the sole basis of
their rights. But they also saw that it was necessary to prevent any
further violence, since this would fall upon themselves. They conceived
that the primitive usurpation ought to be regarded as a sacred title;
but they perceived no less clearly that it was necessary to proscribe
any new usurpation, which would contradict the ancient one and destroy
it. In order to succeed in this they proposed to authorize only those
brigandages which were carried on in common, and to punish severely
those persons who dared to commit individual acts of spoliation. In
response to their suggestions it was decreed that society should have
the right to take everything, but that the members of society, as
individuals, should be deprived of this right. They agreed that each
should have peaceful possession of the part allotted to him, and that
whoever tried to take it from him should be declared a public enemy and
prosecuted as such.

“Here, then, in a few words is the source of all human laws. From it
spring laws of every kind except the divine law, the source of which is
as pure as its author. Upon this basis are founded all imaginable
constitutions. This it is which sanctions the law of nations and the
civil law, of which the one legitimates conquests, and the other
proscribes robbery, only punishing, however, the thefts not committed
by a large company. Finally this same principle has directed the steps
of all politicians and of all founders of governments and empires.

“They have come by different ways, the details of which it is useless
to discuss here, to change the original social anarchy, in which these
principles were discovered, into administrations more or less
imperfect. Violence thus formed the foundation of their rights, but all
wished to keep with justice what they got possession of very unjustly.
They took precautions to prevent those who assisted them in their
wholesale conquest from imitating them in detail. After making sure of
the general domain they did not wish any one to be able to dispute the
particular distribution of it. They confirmed by regulations all their
accomplices in the possession of what they had had the address or the
good fortune to seize. They decreed that any one who, seeing these
possessions stolen by force, should attempt to secure restitution by
the same method, should be punished as guilty of an offense against
society.” [13]

In the chapter “Good and Evils which Laws Produce” Linguet pronounces
the following trenchant and satirical judgment:

“The aim [of justice and law], as we have said, is to give society a
fixed position. There results from them an invariable order which keeps
each member in his place. It is by their means that the multitude who
do not know them, even while they respect them, submit without
repugnance to the small number who are armed by them. In this sense
there is nothing so admirable as the law. It is the most sublime
invention that ever presented itself to the human mind. It offers to
any reflective individual the most satisfying, the most beautiful of
spectacles. To restrain force and violence by pacific means; to
subjugate the liveliest passions; to assure to painful virtues the
preference over easy and delusive vices; to direct the eyes, the hands,
and the hearts of men; to subdue them without preventing them from
believing themselves free; to prescribe duties capable of securing the
repose of docile souls who performed them, and of protecting them
against rebellious spirits, who wish to be exempt from them; all this
the laws do or ought to do. It would be difficult to join together so
much greatness with so many benefits.

“But as the theory of the laws is honorable to the humanity which has
been able to grasp it, so the practical application of the laws has
been most distressing, when, after the observance of them has been
recommended, it is necessary to pass on to the punishments decreed for
the offenses which violate them. The passions which self-interest
unceasingly incites often necessitate this grievous extremity. Then we
see men authorized by general consent to exercise an inflexible rigor
upon their fellows. We hear justice pronounce sentences which would
pass for cruel if they were not indispensable. It makes use of prisons,
executioners, gallows. Liberty and even life become pledges of which
justice deprives men at pleasure when they abuse them. To make good the
losses which the state suffers from the crimes that disturb it, it
comes back upon the criminals, and consequently suffers almost equally
from the crime and from the punishment.” [14]




VII.

P. H. D. D’HOLBACH.

In the third section of his “Système social”, under the heading, “The
Influence of Government upon Morals”, Holbach, in treating of the
causes of crime says among other things:

“In China they punish the mandarin in the department in which a great
crime has been committed. A bad government has its own negligence or
its own injustice to blame for the great number of malefactors who are
found in a state. The multiplicity of criminals proclaims an
administration as tyrannical and careless. The severity of taxes, the
vexations and hardships inflicted by the rich and great multiply the
number of the unfortunate, whom poverty often reduces to despair and
who avail themselves of crime as the promptest means of escape from
their condition. If wealth is the mother of vices, poverty is the
mother of crimes. When a state is badly governed and wealth is too
unequally divided, so that millions of men lack the necessaries of
life, while a small number of citizens are surfeited with luxuries,
there we commonly see a great number of criminals, whose number
punishments do not diminish. If a government punishes the unfortunate
it leaves undisturbed the vices that are leading the state to its ruin;
it erects gibbets for the poor, whereas by bringing men to poverty it
has itself made thieves, assassins, and criminals of every kind; it
punishes crime, while it continually invites men to commit crime.” [15]

“The man who has no share in the wealth of the state is not held to
society by any bond. How can we expect a crowd of unfortunates to whom
we have given neither principles nor morals to remain quiet spectators
of the abundance, the luxury, the unjustly acquired riches of so many
corrupt individuals, who seem to insult the general poverty, and are
only rarely disposed to relieve it? By what right can society punish
the thieving servant who has been a witness of the unpunished robberies
and extortions of his master, or has seen public thieves strutting
along, enjoying the consideration of their fellow citizens, and
shamelessly displaying the fruits of their extortions under the very
eyes of the heads of the state? How can we make the poor respect the
property of others when they themselves have been the victims of the
rapacity of the rich, or have seen the property of their fellow
citizens snatched away by violence or fraud with impunity? Finally how
can we successfully preach submission to men to whom everything proves
that the laws, armed against themselves alone, are indulgent toward the
great and happy, and are inexorable only for the unhappy and poor? ‘A
man dies but once’ and the imagination of the criminal familiarizes
itself little by little with the idea of the most cruel punishments. He
ends by regarding them as a ‘mauvais quart d’heure’, and would as soon
perish by the hand of the executioner as die of hunger, or even work
all his life without reward.” [16]




VIII.

G. B. DE MABLY.

This author’s opinion of crime is best expressed by the following
quotation taken from his “De la législation ou principes des lois”:

“The more I reflect upon it the more I am convinced that inequality of
fortune and condition disorders man and alters the natural sentiments
of his heart, for the habit of luxury gives him a desire for things
that are useless for his true happiness and fills his mind with the
most unjust and absurd prejudices and errors. I believe that equality,
while satisfying modest requirements, keeps those requirements modest,
and preserves in the soul a peace which is opposed to the birth and
progress of the passions. By what strange folly should we have
cultivated a studied elegance and refinement in our needs if inequality
of fortune had not accustomed us to regard this ridiculous
fastidiousness as a proof of superiority, and attained thereby a
certain consideration? Why should I consider as below me a man who is
perhaps my superior in merit; why should I pretend to have authority
over him and so open the door to tyranny, to servitude, and all the
vices most fatal to society, if the inequality of conditions had not
exposed my soul to ambition, as the inequality of fortune has exposed
it to avarice? It is inequality alone that has taught men to prefer
many useless and harmful things to virtue. I believe that it has been
demonstrated that in a state of equality nothing would be easier than
to prevent abuses and maintain the law. Equality is certain to produce
all good, because it unites men, elevates their souls, and prepares
them for mutual feelings of benevolence and amity. Inequality, on the
other hand, produces all evil, because it degrades men, humiliates
them, and sows division and hatred among them.” [17]




IX.

J. P. BRISSOT DE WARVILLE.

In his “Théorie des loix criminelles” we find among others the
following passages that are of interest in connection with the subject
which occupies our attention:

“A man is not born an enemy to society. It is circumstances which give
him that title, such as poverty or misfortune. He does not disturb the
general tranquillity until he has lost his own. He ceases to be a good
citizen only when the name becomes meaningless in his case; and it is
when poverty has destroyed his own privileges that he dares to attack
those of his fellows. To make all citizens happy is, then, to prevent
the inception of crime; and the rarity of crime is in direct ratio to
the goodness of the administration. This simple principle, however
unknown to administrators even to the present day, is no less solid on
that account, no less luminous, and ought no less to serve as the basis
for government. If it has been neglected, it is because it has appeared
easier to rulers to punish the unfortunate being who demands the rights
that nature gave him, than to satisfy his just demand; to stifle the
cries of anguish, than to change them to shouts of applause. The penal
code of every nation is much like the bull of Phalaris; its imposing
garb of juridical forms, like the timbrels and other instruments
surrounding the brazen monster, prevent the cries of the victims from
reaching the ear. Tyrants cry out to the credulous spectators that
blood is necessary to the public safety; good legislators are greedy of
it.

“The first and most efficacious means of preventing crimes consists,
then, in a wise administration that procures the general happiness.
When the rays of the beneficent star that rules extend their influence
even to the lowest ranks of society, they are rarely sullied by
punishments; each, concentrating itself upon the spot where heaven has
thrown it, makes the day that it lightens joyous and blessed (and crime
is so near to the man who is forced to curse his fate!). If the taxes
are light and not severely felt, if subsistence is easy, the number of
marriages increases, they are happy, and the population multiplies. The
people then do not regret their labors, since they are interspersed
with pleasures. They are attached to the fatherland, which offers them
good fortune, and to life, which gives them the means of enjoying it. A
man does not disturb the public peace, because his own prosperity is
the fruit of it. A property-holder himself, he takes good care not to
do any violence to the right of property, and even where he would not
naturally have a horror of bloodshed, his days are too precious to him
for him to dare to cut short those of his fellow-citizens.” [18]

“... What sovereign, I say, cannot easily see that he has in his hand
the true means of restraining crime, namely to secure the public
well-being by means of civil legislation. Yes, the more perfect civil
legislation becomes the less need there will be for criminal
legislation. And this need will disappear entirely when the twofold
basis upon which civil legislation ought to rest becomes fixed and
invariable; when the property and the liberty of subjects are respected
by the monarch; when the unfortunate man who has been born without
property (though with the same needs as others) can, by working,
correct the injustice of fate, and destroy the inequality of the
distribution of wealth; when, finally, the fruit of his labor will not
be the prey of the greedy tax-gatherer. The rich man can then enjoy his
wealth in safety, because despair will no longer expose him to the
knife of the poor man whom his proud opulence insults. We posit here as
the foundation of good legislation the security of real and personal
property, but a masterpiece of statesmanship would be, to make them
useless, if it were possible, by abolishing them altogether. This would
be to tear up crime by the roots. It was thus that Lycurgus, whose laws
have been so calumniated because to narrow minds they seemed impossible
of imitation, cleverly dried up the source of all crime. To avoid
attacks upon property he abolished it; to prevent adultery he had all
women held in common; to make the Spartan a hero he made him the slave
of his harsh legislation; finally to prevent the sad effects of the
passions he permitted none but the passion for the public weal. This is
why crimes were so rare in Sparta as long as these laws were faithfully
observed. But when Lysander brought back from the fatal conquest of
Athens treasures, the taste for art and the rage for luxury, all the
vices were rapidly introduced. Then crimes broke out; ambition made men
commit perjuries, assassinations, treasons; then the virtuous Agis, who
wanted to revive morality, perished under the perfidious knife of the
royal servitude; then men like Nabis and Machanidas appeared; and
finally a penal code was introduced, and Sparta was reduced to the
status of an ordinary city.” [19]

“Ought we to be astonished that the attacks upon the social laws are so
multiplied to-day, and that there are always so many thieves and
assassins, when to the causes of crime which we have developed it is
necessary to add that horrible malady of European states, mendicity?
When the water destined by nature to quench the thirst of all men is
artificially diverted into particular channels for the exclusive use of
certain individuals, the unfortunate man, tormented by need, falls into
despair, and in a rage breaks these fatal channels, making the
fragments fall upon the heads of his enemies. Exclusive possession of
property has everywhere produced poverty in the most numerous class,
and poverty has given birth to mendicity, which, robbing with one hand
to satisfy hunger, with the other plunges a dagger into the bosom of
the rich to stop their cries. Here we have in two words the origin of
theft and murder. To destroy the roots of these it would be necessary
to restore among men the equality of condition so praised by modern
philosophers, but not at all included in the programs of modern
governments. It would be necessary to distribute wealth equally among
all citizens, to eradicate from their hearts the corrosive desire of
ambition, and to blunt the spur of their personal interest.” [20]

In his “Recherches philosophiques sur la propriété et sur le vol”
Brissot gives an exposition of natural property, and of property as
established by society. He says of crime: “Civil property is very
different from natural property, as we have shown. It is not based upon
the same title, and has not the same aim or the same bounds. Need is
the limit of natural property. Civil property goes further and includes
superfluities. In nature each man has a right to everything; in society
the man to whom his parents have left no property has a right to
nothing. In nature he would be guilty if he did not satisfy his needs;
he is guilty in society when he satisfies them if he has no property.
Society has, then, upset all the ideas of property given by nature. It
has destroyed the equilibrium between human beings which nature
established. Equality banished there appear the odious distinctions of
rich and poor. Society has been divided into two classes, the first
consisting of citizens with property, living in idleness; the second
and more numerous class composed of the mass of the people, to whom the
right to exist has been sold dear, and who are degraded and condemned
to perpetual toil. To confirm this new right of property the most cruel
punishments have been pronounced upon all those who disturb or attack
it. The breach of this right is called theft; and see how far we are
from nature! The thief in the state of nature is the rich man, the man
who has a superfluity; in society the thief is he who robs this rich
man. What a complete transposition of ideas!” [21]

“If man retains, even in society, the inalienable right of property
which nature has given him, nothing can take it from him, nothing can
prevent his exercising it. If the other members of society concentrate
in their own persons the possession of all the soil; if those who are
robbed by this spoliation and forced to have recourse to labor cannot
by this means secure their whole subsistence, then they have the right
to exact from the others, who hold property, the means of satisfying
their needs. They have a claim upon the wealth of others in proportion
to their own necessity, and force used to resist this claim is
violence. The rich man is the only thief; he alone ought to hang from
those infamous gallows which are raised only to punish the man born in
poverty for being needy; only to force him to stifle the voice of
nature, the cry of liberty; only to compel him to subject himself to a
harsh servitude in order to avoid an ignominious death.” [22]




X.

W. GODWIN.

In the third chapter of the First Book of his “Enquiry Concerning
Political Justice”, Godwin treats of two important kinds of crime,
theft and fraud.

Of these he says: “Two of the greatest abuses relative to the interior
policy of nations which at this time prevail in the world, consist in
the irregular transfer of property, either first by violence, or
secondly by fraud. If among the inhabitants of a country there existed
no desire in one individual to possess himself of the substance of
another, or no desire so vehement and restless as to prompt him to
acquire it by means inconsistent with order and justice, undoubtedly in
that country guilt could scarcely be known but by report. If every man
could with perfect facility obtain the necessities of life, and,
obtaining them, feel no uneasy craving after its superfluities,
temptation would lose its power. Private interest would visibly accord
with public good; and civil society become what poetry has feigned of
the golden age. Let us inquire into the principles to which these evils
are indebted for their existence.” [23]

According to him these crimes are the consequence:

First, Of poverty, which has reached enormous dimensions (in England
one person out of every seven has at some time received public aid).
The situation has become such that for the poor man the state of
society is a state of war. He considers society not as a body whose
object is to maintain personal rights and to procure to each individual
the means of providing for his own support, but as a body that protects
the advantageous position of one class of persons, while holding others
in a state of poverty and dependence.

Second, Of the ostentation of the rich, who make the poor man feel all
the more what he is deprived of.

Third, Of the tyranny of the rich, made permanent by legislation, by
the administration of the laws, and by the distribution of wealth.

In his Eighth Book (“Of Property”), Godwin elaborates the ideas given
above. Speaking of the moral improvement that would result from the
abolition of private property, he says: “And here it is obvious that
the great occasions for crime would be cut off forever. All men love
justice. All men are conscious that man is a being of one common
nature, and feel the propriety of the treatment they receive from one
another being measured by one common standard. Every man is desirous of
assisting another; whether we should choose to ascribe this to an
instinct implanted in his nature which renders this a source of
personal gratification, or to his perception of the reasonableness of
such assistance. So necessary a part is this of the constitution of
mind, that it may be doubted whether any man perpetrates any action,
however criminal, without having first invented some sophistry, some
palliation, by which he proves to himself that it is best to be done.
Hence it appears, that offense, the invasion by one man upon the
security of another, is a thought alien to the human mind, and which
nothing could have reconciled us to but the sharp sting of necessity.
To consider merely the present order of society, it is evident that the
first offense must have been his who began a monopoly, and took
advantage of the weakness of his neighbors to secure certain exclusive
privileges to himself. The man on the other hand who determined to put
an end to this monopoly, and who peremptorily demanded what was
superfluous to the possessor and would be of extreme benefit to
himself, appeared to his own mind to be merely avenging the offended
laws of justice. Were it not for the plausibleness of this apology, it
is to be presumed that there would be no such thing as crime in the
world.

“The fruitful source of crimes consists in this circumstance, one man’s
possessing in abundance that of which another man is destitute. We must
change the nature of mind before we can prevent it from being
powerfully influenced by this circumstance, when brought strongly home
to its perceptions by the nature of its situation. Man must cease to
have senses, the pleasures of appetite and vanity must cease to
gratify, before he can look on tamely at the monopoly of these
pleasures. He must cease to have a sense of justice before he can
clearly and fully approve this mixed scene of superfluity and want. It
is true that the proper method of curing this inequality is by reason
and not by violence. But the immediate tendency of the established
administration is to persuade that reason is impotent. The injustice of
which they complain is upheld by force, and they are too easily
induced, by force to attempt its correction. All they endeavor is the
partial correction of an injustice, which education tells them is
necessary, but more powerful reason affirms to be tyrannical.

“Force grew out of monopoly. It might accidentally have occurred among
savages whose appetites exceeded their supply, or whose passions were
inflamed by the presence of the object of their desire; but it would
gradually have died away, as reason and civilization advanced.
Accumulated property has fixed its empire; and henceforth all is an
open contention of the strength and cunning of the one party against
the strength and cunning of the other. In this case the violent and
premature struggles of the necessitous are undoubtedly an evil. They
tend to defeat the very cause in the success of which they are most
deeply interested; they tend to procrastinate the triumph of truth. But
the true crime in every instance is in the selfish and partial
propensities of men, thinking only of themselves, and despising the
emolument of others; and of these the rich have their share.

“The spirit of oppression, the spirit of servility, and the spirit of
fraud, these are the ultimate growth of the established administration
of property. They are alike hostile to intellectual and moral
improvement. The other vices of envy, malice, and revenge are their
inseparable companions. In a state of society where men lived in the
midst of plenty, and where all shared alike the bounties of nature,
these sentiments would inevitably expire. The narrow principle of
selfishness would vanish. No man would be obliged to guard his little
store, or provide with anxiety and pain for his restless wants, each
would lose his individual existence in the thought of the general good.
No man would be an enemy to his neighbor, for they would have no
subject of contention; and of consequence philanthropy would resume the
empire which reason assigns her; mind would be delivered from her
perpetual anxiety about corporal support, and free to expatiate in the
field of thought which is congenial to her. Each would assist the
inquiries of all.” [24]




XI.

R. OWEN. [25]

The author in several works has given us his ideas upon the relation
between crime and the social environment, and especially economic
conditions. It is in “The Book of the New Moral World”, which appeared
in 1844, that his views are best expressed. [26]

They may be summed up as follows: It is not the man himself, it is his
circumstances that form his character; an unfavorable environment
produces a bad man, a favorable one a good man. The organization of the
society of today is such that it awakens in a man all evil qualities.
The greater part of mankind live in conditions of the greatest poverty,
and become physically, intellectually, and morally inferior. The
working classes are housed in unsanitary dwellings, work too hard and
too long, and are insufficiently clothed and nourished.

Improper production and distribution of wealth are the causes of the
prevalence of disorder and anarchy. The means of production, the raw
materials and the productive forces, are sufficient to provide amply
for the needs of all. But competition by devouring wealth prevents
this, and brings it about that while some have a superfluity, the
majority have not even the necessaries of life (a fact which is one
great cause of criminality). The process of distribution adds
enormously to the waste because of the great number of intermediaries.

Education and instruction are neglected to the last degree. The
children of the lower classes are almost entirely deprived of
instruction, not to say education; their parents, never having been
taught themselves, are incapable of imparting instruction, nor have
they the leisure for it. However, the children of all classes are made
egotistical and anti-social; they have impressed upon them the maxim
“Each one for himself”, in place of being taught that the love of one’s
neighbor is the principle upon which society ought to be based.

Owen finds the cause of crime, then, in the organization of society
upon the basis of private property. The following is a characteristic
passage from Volume VI, “General Constitution of Government and
Universal Code of Law”:

“Private property has been, and is at this day, the cause of endless
crime and misery to man, and he should hail the period when the
progress of science, and the knowledge of the means to form a superior
character for all the individuals of the human race, render its
continuance not only unnecessary, but most injurious to all; injurious
to an incalculable extent to the lower, middle, and upper classes. The
possession of private property tends to make the possessor ignorantly
selfish; and selfish, very generally, in proportion to the extent of
the property held by its claimant....

“Private property also deteriorates the character of its possessor in
various ways; it is calculated to produce in him pride, vanity,
injustice, and oppression, with a total disregard of the natural and
inalienable rights of his fellow men. It limits his ideas within the
little narrow circle of self, prevents the mind from expanding to
receive the extended views beneficial for the human race, and
understand great general interests that could be made most essentially
to improve the character and condition of all....

“Private property alienates mind from mind, is a perpetual cause of
repulsive action throughout society, a never-failing source of
deception and fraud between man and man, and a strong stimulus to
prostitution among women. It has caused war throughout all the past
ages of the world’s known history, and has been a stimulant to
innumerable private murders.

“It is now the sole cause of poverty and its endless crimes and
miseries over the world, and in principle it is as unjust as it is
unwise in practice.

“In a rational-made society it will never exist. Whatever may have been
its necessity or utility, before the introduction of the supremacy of
machinery and chemistry, it is now most unnecessary and an unmixed
evil; for every one, from the highest to the lowest, may be ensured
through life much more of all that is really beneficial for humanity,
and the permanent happiness of the individual, through public
scientific arrangements, than it is possible to obtain through the
scramble and contest for procuring and maintaining private property.

“Private property also continually interferes with or obstructs public
measures which would greatly benefit all, and frequently to merely
please the whim or caprice of an ill-trained individual....

“With a well arranged scientific system of public property, equal
education and condition, there will be no mercenary or unequal
marriages; no spoiled children; and none of the evils which proceed
from these errors in the present system, if crudities which pervade all
the departments of life, and are thoroughly inconsistent, can be called
a system of society.

“In fact, as soon as individuals shall be educated and placed—and it is
for the best and permanent interest of society that all should be
educated and placed—the saving of time, labour, and capital, between
public and private property, will be beyond any estimate the mind of
man can form in favour of public property....

“Therefore the twelfth law [27] will be, that—

“‘Under the Rational System of society—after the children shall have
been trained to acquire new habits and new feelings, derived from a
knowledge of the laws of human nature—there shall be no useless private
property.’

“The old system of the world has been created and governed on the
assumed principle of man’s responsibility to man, and by man’s rewards
and punishments.

“And this principle has been assumed upon the original supposition,
that man was born with power to form himself into any character he
liked; to believe or disbelieve whatever he pleased; and that he could
love, hate, or be indifferent as to all persons and things, according
to an independent will which enabled him to do as he liked in all these
respects.

“The present system is, therefore, essentially a system supported and
governed by laws of punishment and reward of man’s creating, in
opposition to nature’s laws of punishing and rewarding. The former
system is artificial, and always produces crime and misery, continually
increasing, and therefore requiring new laws to correct the evils
necessarily forced upon society by the old laws; thus laws are
multiplied without limit by man to counteract nature’s laws, and ever
without success. While nature’s beautiful and benevolent laws, if
consistently acted upon in a system made throughout in accordance with
them, would produce knowledge, goodness, and happiness, continually
increasing, to the human race.

“By man’s laws being forced upon the population of all countries, in
continual opposition to nature’s laws; with law added to law, in the
vain attempt to remedy endless previous laws, the world had been made
and kept criminal, with crimes multiplying as human laws increased.

“The laws of man are made to support injustice, and give additional
power to the oppressor and to the man devoid of truth and honesty over
the innocent and just. And such must be the result, as long as human
laws, lawyers, and law paraphernalia shall be sanctioned by society....

“Nature’s laws carry with them the only just rewards and punishments
that man should experience; and they are, in every case, efficient for
nature’s purposes, and to ensure the happiness of man in all countries
and climes; and, differing from man’s puny, short-sighted laws, they
are always adequate to the end intended to be accomplished. And this
end is evidently to increase human knowledge and happiness. It is
through these laws of nature, that man has attained the knowledge which
he has acquired. He has been continually urged onward to make
discoveries, and to invent, through pain experienced, or pleasure
enjoyed or anticipated.

“But man has been trained to have his character formed, and to be
governed by laws of his own making; his habits, manners, ideas, and
associations of ideas have emanated, directly or indirectly, from his
artificial and injurious source; and, in consequence, the mind,
language, and practice of all individuals have become a chaos of
confusion. And this chaos in the character and conduct of individuals
has made a yet greater chaos in all the proceedings of society: and, in
consequence, man is now opposing man, and nation opposing nation, all
over the earth. Yet all nature declares, that it shall be by union of
man with man, and nation with nation, that the human race can ever
attain a high degree of permanent prosperity and happiness, or become
rational.

“Nevertheless, while this irrational individual and general character
shall remain, those men and women who have been made to receive this
character, and to be so injured, must continue for a time to be
governed by these most injurious laws. The laws of nature being alone
applicable to a society, whose laws are in accordance with the laws of
nature.

“When this rational society shall be formed, and men, individually and
generally, shall be trained to act in accordance with it, then shall
human punishments and rewards cease, and cease for ever.

“The thirteenth law will therefore be, that—

“‘As soon as the members of these scientific associations shall have
been educated, from infancy, in a knowledge of the laws of their
nature, trained to act in obedience to them, and surrounded by
circumstances all in unison with them, there shall be no individual
reward or punishment.’

“The Rational System of society is one and indivisible in its
principles and practices; each part is essential to its formation. It
is one unvarying consistent system for forming the character of all
individuals, and for governing their affairs; and it is essentially a
system to prevent evil, and render individual punishment and reward as
unnecessary, as they are unjust and injurious to all....

“Individual punishments and rewards, ignorance, the inferior feelings
and passions, with all crimes and miseries, will go together when the
irrational system shall be abolished. When the cause of evil shall be
removed, then will the evil cease, and not before.” [28]




XII.

E. CABET.

In the second part of his “Voyage en Icarie” the author treats of the
relation between crime and economic conditions. In his opinion money
and inequality of fortune and of property are the causes of all crimes.
The following quotation explains his views. (The work speaks of present
day society as in the past, and supposes the existence of a state with
common property.)

“Wealth and superfluity being, by their nature, as I have already said,
injustice and usurpation, the poor often thought only of robbing the
rich; and theft, under all its forms (swindling, pocket-picking,
bankruptcy, breach of trust, fraud, cheating, etc.), was the almost
universal occupation of the poor as well as of the rich. And the poor
robbed not only the rich, they robbed even the poor themselves, so that
all, rich and poor, were both robbers and robbed.

“It would be impossible to enumerate all the kinds of theft and classes
of thieves. It was in vain that the rich had terrible laws made against
theft; it was in vain that the prisons and galleys were kept filled
with poor thieves, and that their blood was often poured out upon the
scaffold. Buoyed up by the hope of not being discovered, the poor
robbed in the fields, or in houses, or upon the highroads, or even in
the streets at night. The skilful pick-pocket stole even in open day.
The audacious swindler robbed by means of trickery and deceit,
sometimes by selling things of no value, sometimes by taking advantage
of credulity or even of beneficence.

“Shall I speak of the counterfeiters of every description? Shall I also
speak of the usurers, the great thieves, the wolves of the bourse and
the bank, the contractors and monopolists? Shall I speak of those who
enriched themselves by means of public calamities, who desired or
provoked invasions or wars in order to make their fortunes, and famines
in order to amass money in the midst of corpses? Shall I speak of the
thieves who risked the public health by adulterating the food and drink
that they sold, and of those other great robbers, the heads of the
army, who pillaged foreign peoples while exposing their own country to
terrible reprisals? Finally shall I speak of the innumerable means of
amassing money at the expense of others, and of the innumerable
individuals in almost all classes who daily practiced them?

“Not all these acts were classed as thefts by the law. The most
inexcusable, the most harmful, those which were only practiced by the
rich, even enjoyed legal impunity. But all of them were, nevertheless,
in reality according to the rules of a sound morality, thefts. Each
class presented, without doubt, many exceptions. There were some rich
men as honest as possible, and many workers and poor men were persons
of probity; but it may be said that by force of circumstances, and as
an irresistible consequence of the inequality of fortune, all men, rich
and poor, were generally induced to commit actions which were in
reality only a kind of theft.

“And often theft led to all kinds of cruelty, to murder, and even to
the most barbarous tortures in order to make owners reveal where they
had hidden their gold. How many poisonings and parricides did the
thirst for gold or inheritance excite! Thieves kidnapped children in
order to prostitute them. They even stole and murdered young people in
order to sell the flesh of their corpses!

“In a word, neither confidence nor security was possible. Each
individual saw enemies in almost all the others; and society seemed, as
it were, but a haunt of cut-throats in the midst of a forest! And all
these horrors, which you will find more or less everywhere, were with
us, and are still elsewhere—I cannot repeat it too often—the inevitable
result of the unrestricted right of property.” [29]




XIII.

F. ENGELS.

Among the disastrous consequences which industrial capitalism draws in
its train the author ranks the tremendous increase of criminality. In
his “Condition of the Working Class in England” he says: “The failings
of the workers in general may be traced to an unbridled thirst for
pleasure, to want of providence, and of flexibility in fitting into the
social order, to the general inability to sacrifice the pleasure of the
moment to a remoter advantage. But is that to be wondered at? When a
class can purchase only a few and only the most sensual pleasures by
its wearying toil, must it not give itself over blindly and madly to
those pleasures? A class about whose education no one troubles himself,
which is a playball to a thousand chances, knows no security in
life—what incentives has such a class to providence, to
‘respectability’, to sacrifice the pleasure of the moment for a remoter
enjoyment, most uncertain precisely by reason of the perpetually
varying, shifting conditions under which the proletariat lives? A class
which bears all the disadvantages of the social order without enjoying
its advantages, one to which the social system appears in purely
hostile aspects—who can demand that such a class respect this social
order? Verily that is asking much! But the working-man cannot escape
the present arrangement of society so long as it exists, and when the
individual worker resists it, the greatest injury falls upon himself.

“Thus the social order makes family life almost impossible for the
worker. In a comfortless, filthy house, hardly good enough for mere
nightly shelter, ill-furnished, often neither rain-tight nor warm, a
foul atmosphere filling rooms overcrowded with human beings, no
domestic comfort is possible. The husband works the whole day through,
perhaps the wife also and the elder children, all in different places;
they meet night and morning only, all under perpetual temptation to
drink; what family life is possible under such conditions? Yet the
working-man cannot escape from the family, must live in the family, and
the consequence is a perpetual succession of family troubles, domestic
quarrels, most demoralizing for parents and children alike. Neglect of
all domestic duties, neglect of the children, especially, is only too
common among the English working-people, and only too vigorously
fostered by the existing institutions of society. And children growing
up in this savage way, amidst these demoralizing influences, are
expected to turn out goody-goody and moral in the end! Verily the
requirements are naïve, which the self-satisfied bourgeois makes upon
the working-man!

“The contempt for the existing order is most conspicuous in its extreme
form—that of offenses against the law. If the influences demoralizing
to the working-man act more powerfully, more concentratedly than usual,
he becomes an offender as certainly as water abandons the fluid for the
vaporous state at 80 degrees, Réaumur. Under the brutal and brutalizing
treatment of the bourgeoisie, the working-man becomes precisely as much
without volition as water, and is subject to the laws of nature with
precisely the same necessity; at a certain point all freedom ceases.
Hence with the extension of the proletariat, crime has increased in
England, and the British nation has become the most criminal in the
world. From the annual criminal tables of the Home Secretary, it is
evident that the increase of crime in England has proceeded with
incomprehensible rapidity. The number of arrests for criminal offenses
reached in years: 1805, 4,605; 1810, 5,146; 1815, 7,898; 1820, 13,710;
1825, 14,437; 1830, 18,107; 1835, 20,731; 1840, 27,187; 1841, 27,760;
1842, 31,309 in England and Wales alone. That is to say, they increased
seven-fold in thirty-seven years. Of these arrests, in 1842, 4,497 were
made in Lancashire alone, or more than 14 per cent. of the whole; and
4,094 in Middlesex, including London, or more than 13 per cent. So that
two districts which include great cities with proletarian populations,
produced one fourth of the total amount of crime, though their
population is far from forming one fourth of the whole. Moreover, the
criminal tables prove directly that nearly all crime arises within the
proletariat; for in 1842, taking the average, out of 100 criminals,
32.35 could neither read nor write; 58.32 read and wrote imperfectly;
6.77 could read and write well; 0.22 had enjoyed a higher education,
while the degree of education of 2.34 could not be ascertained. In
Scotland, crime has increased yet more rapidly. There were but 89
arrests for criminal offenses in 1819, and as early as 1837 the number
had risen to 3,176, and in 1842 to 4,189. In Lanarkshire, where Sheriff
Alison himself made out the criminal report, the population has doubled
in thirty years, and crime in five and a half, or six times more
rapidly than the population. The offenses, as in all civilized
countries, are, in the great majority of cases, against property. The
proportion of offenses to the population, which in the Netherlands is
as 1 : 7,140, and in France as 1 : 1,804, was in England, when Gaskell
wrote, as 1 : 799. The proportion of offenses against persons to the
population in the Netherlands, 1 : 28,904; in France, 1 : 17,537; in
England, 1 : 23,395; that of crimes in general to the population in the
agricultural districts, as 1 : 1,043; in the manufacturing districts as
1 : 840. (‘Manufacturing Population of England’, chap. 10.) In the
whole of England today the proportion is 1 : 660; though it is scarcely
ten years since Gaskell’s book appeared!” [30]








CHAPTER II.

THE STATISTICIANS.


I.

A. M. GUERRY.

In his “Essai sur la statistique morale de la France”, the author has
made a study of the influence of age, sex, season, education, etc.,
upon criminality. But there is scarcely to be found an exposition of
the influence of economic conditions upon the subject which we are
considering. The following passages, however, are not devoid of
interest.

“Wealth, (as determined by the amount of taxes on personal and real
property) more often than density of population, coincides with crimes
against property, of which it thus appears to be an indirect cause. We
shall observe, however, that while the maximum of wealth falls in the
departments of the North, where the greatest number of crimes against
property are found; and the minimum in the center where these crimes
are most rare; yet in the South the average is almost as high as in the
North. Now if in the North is wealth which indirectly produces the
crimes against property, why is it that the same is not true of the
South? It would be unsafe to conclude from the fact that the poorest
departments are those where the fewest crimes against property are
committed, that poverty is not the principal cause of these crimes. In
order to justify this conclusion, which in other regards we are far
from rejecting, more direct proofs would be necessary. As a matter of
fact, it is possible that the departments where there is the least
wealth are not those where there are the greatest number of the very
poor; and that the departments where the largest fortunes are to be
found are just those where the poverty of a part of the population is
greatest.

“The question of the effect of wealth or poverty upon morality presents
more difficulty than one would suspect at first glance. To study it it
would be necessary to determine the ratio of the indigent and pauper
class in each department. Some documents upon the subject have been
published, it is true, but they have no authentic character, and do not
appear to merit enough confidence for us to give the analysis of them
here.” [31]

Further along Guerry shows that the departments where commerce and
manufacturing are most highly developed furnish also the greatest
number of crimes against property. But the author has not investigated
the connection between these two symptoms. Although not rejecting,
then, entirely the hypothesis that poverty is not the principal cause
of crimes against property, Guerry recognizes nevertheless that a
causal connection between poverty and crime is possible, that is to say
he perceives that the department where the greatest poverty prevails is
not necessarily that which is the poorest, nor that the richest is the
one that has the fewest of the very poor.




II.

AD. QUETELET.

An exposition of the whole system of this author would lead us too far.
But the following quotations from his “Physique sociale” will suffice
to show the breadth of his views and the vastness of his conception of
society.

“Thus, to make our manner of procedure plain by an example, anyone who
examines too closely a small portion of a very great circumference
traced upon a plane, will see in this portion only a certain number of
physical points, assembled in a more or less accidental way.... From a
greater distance his eye will take in a greater number of points, which
will already appear regularly distributed in an arc of a certain
extent; soon, if the observer continues to recede, he loses sight of
the individual points ... grasps the law that has presided over their
general arrangement, and recognizes the nature of the curve traced....

“It is in this way that we shall study the laws that concern the human
race; for when we examine them from too near at hand it becomes
impossible to grasp them; we are struck only with individual
peculiarities, which are infinite.” [32]

“In all that relates to crimes, the same figures are reproduced with
such constancy that it is impossible to misconstrue them, even in the
case of those crimes which, it would seem, should be most likely to
escape human prevision, such as homicides, since these are in general
committed as a consequence of quarrels arising without motive, and
under apparently fortuitous circumstances. Experience, however, proves
that not only is the annual number of homicides nearly constant, but
that even the weapons employed are used in the same proportions. What
can be said then of crimes that are the result of reflection?

“This constancy with which the same crimes reappear annually in the
same order, and lead to the same penalties in the same proportions, is
one of the most curious of the facts that we learn from court
statistics.... A budget which we pay with frightful regularity is that
of the jails, the penitentiaries, and the gallows.... We can enumerate
in advance how many individuals will stain their hands with the blood
of their fellows, how many will be forgers, how many poisoners; almost
as we can predict the births and deaths....

“Society contains within itself the germs of all the crimes that are
about to be committed. It is society, in a way, which prepares them,
and the criminal is only the instrument that executes them.

“Every social state supposes, then, a certain number and certain order
of crimes as a necessary consequence of its organization. This remark,
which might appear discouraging at first sight, becomes consoling, on
the contrary, when we consider it more closely, since it shows the
possibility of the improvement of men, by the modification of their
institutions and habits and whatever, in general, influences their
manner of being. At bottom this is only the extension of the well known
law ... that so far as the same causes are present we must expect the
repetition of the same effects. What has produced the belief that this
did not apply to moral phenomena is the too great influence commonly
ascribed to man in matters relating to his actions.” [33]

In the second volume of the “Physique sociale”, Quetelet studies the
influence of climate, age, and sex upon the tendency to crime. Although
he merely touches upon our subject and treats it only indirectly, the
following passages are worth the trouble of quoting:

“Poverty also is very generally regarded as leading to evil; however
the department of the Creuse, one of the poorest in France, is that
which shows in every respect, the highest morality. In the same way in
the Netherlands, the most moral province is Luxemburg, where there is
most poverty reigning. We must, however, be clear about the word
poverty, which is here employed with a significance to which exception
may be taken. A province is not really poor for having less extreme
wealth than another, if the inhabitants, as in Luxemburg, are sober and
industrious; if, by their labor, they succeed in providing in a
dependable way for their needs, and in satisfying tastes that are so
much the more modest, as the inequality of fortune is less felt, and
causes less temptation; it may be said with more justice that this
province enjoys a modest competence. Poverty makes itself felt in the
provinces where great wealth is piled up, as in Flanders, Holland, the
department of the Seine, etc., and especially in manufacturing
countries, where the slightest political disturbance, the slightest
obstruction in the channels of trade, will suddenly reduce thousands
from a state of well-being to one of distress. It is these sudden
changes from one state to another that give birth to crime, especially
if those who suffer from them are surrounded by temptations, and are
irritated by the continual sight of luxury and an inequality of fortune
that makes them desperate.” [34]

In speaking of the three races that make up the population of France,
Quetelet says:

“The most remarkable anomaly that the Celtic race seems to present is
found in the departments that belong to the valley of the Seine,
especially below Paris. Several causes contribute to bring this about.
We shall note first that these departments are those which, by reason
of their extent, contain most persons and things, and consequently
offer most opportunities to commit crimes; it is there that there is
most movement and that most vagrants flow in from all districts....
Finally, it is here also that we find most industrial establishments
and these establishments support a congested population whose means of
support are more precarious than in other vocations.... The commercial
and industrial provinces of the Netherlands are likewise those in which
most offenses are committed.” [35]




III.

EDW. DUCPETIAUX.

One of the parts of his “Paupérisme dans les Flandres” treats of the
criminality in the two provinces of that name. We quote the following
from it:

“Criminality is the inseparable companion of poverty. As the number of
indigent persons increases, we see the number of crimes also increase.
Hunger is a bad counselor. In the midst of crushing destitution, a man
gradually loses the notion of justice and injustice, of good and bad;
beset by needs that he cannot satisfy, he disregards the laws, and ends
by recoiling from no attempt that appears capable of bettering his
condition. Visiting a prison is enough to convince one of the influence
of this cause upon the number and the nature of the offenses, and
before even questioning the statistics that attest the progress of
criminality in Flanders, we could be assured that this progress had
coincided with that of pauperism. It is not then a demonstration (which
we judge quite unnecessary) that we are about to offer here, it is only
a series of facts that may serve to make the reader appreciate the
greatness of the evil and the urgent necessity of attacking its source.

“The first of these facts is the high figure for convicts belonging to
East and West Flanders, when compared with the total number of convicts
in the central prisons.... In the ten years between 1838 and 1847,
23,075 convicts were received in the central prisons of the kingdom;
10,308 belonged to the two Flanders and 12,767 to the other provinces;
the proportion, to 1000 convicts, was 447 for the first two provinces,
and 553 for the seven others. Now this proportion is considerably in
excess of that of the respective populations of the two divisions,
since, to the thousand inhabitants, there are only 331 in Flanders and
669 in the rest of the kingdom. In other words, during the decennial
period in question, one prisoner was received to 139 inhabitants in
Flanders, and to 227 in the seven other provinces.

“The second fact is the increase in the number of persons arraigned and
convicted in the Flemish provinces during the last few of these years,
and particularly since the food shortage of 1845. In a space of seven
years, the number of those arraigned in the two Flanders increased
about in the ratio of 7 to 17; that of those condemned to imprisonment
grew, during the same period from 35 to 123, or nearly quadrupled.

“These data are confirmed by an abstract of the numbers received into
the jails and prisons of the two provinces, as well as by the average
population of these establishments, during the period from 1839 to
1848:


======+===============================================+=======+==========
      | Persons Received into the Jails and Prisons of|       |  Average
      +-----------------------------------------------+       |Population
Years.|                                               |Totals.|  of the
      |                West Flanders.                 |       | Prisons.
------+-----------+-----------+-----------+-----------+-------+----------
      |  Bruges.  | Courtrai. |   Ypres.  |   Furnes. |       |
      +-----------+-----------+-----------+-----------+       |
1839  |   1,578   |     592   |     572   |     169   | 2,911 |    233
1840  |   1,502   |     643   |     821   |     196   | 3,162 |    238
1841  |   1,377   |     795   |     599   |     175   | 2,946 |    311
1842  |   1,489   |     863   |     836   |     271   | 3,459 |    346
1843  |   1,478   |     922   |     790   |     298   | 3,488 |    374
1844  |   1,502   |     941   |     696   |     270   | 3,409 |    379
1845  |   1,876   |     935   |     600   |     254   | 3,665 |    376
1846  |   2,378   |   1,108   |     935   |     601   | 5,022 |    574
1847  |   3,751   |   2,012   |   1,238   |     909   | 7,910 |    820
1848  |   2,859   |   1,960   |   1,070   |     690   | 6,579 |    694
      +-----------+-----------+-----------+-----------+       |
      |                East Flanders.                 |       |
      +-----------+------------+----------+---------- +       |
      |   Ghent.  | Audenarde. |      Termonde.       |       |
      +-----------+------------+----------------------+       |
1839  |   2,094   |     842    |         754          | 3,690 |    289
1840  |   2,311   |     919    |         852          | 4,082 |    357
1841  |   2,163   |     771    |         852          | 3,786 |    351
1842  |   2,171   |     844    |         905          | 3,920 |    333
1843  |   3,610   |     991    |         870          | 5,471 |    408
1844  |   2,548   |     760    |         718          | 4,026 |    345
1845  |   2,579   |   1,061    |       1,461          | 5,101 |    360
1846  |   5,499   |   2,732    |       2,092          | 0,323 |    619
1847  |   7,491   |   6,943    |       3,240          | 7,674 |    972
1848  |   6,309   |   4,462    |       2,829          | 3,600 |    698
======+===========+============+======================+=======+==========


“The increase in the numbers received into the jails and prisons of the
two provinces took place especially in the years 1845, 1846, and 1847;
in 1848 we note quite a pronounced decrease, which continues in 1849.
Of all the signs to prove the existence and progress of pauperism, this
is perhaps the most certain. During the disastrous years that had just
elapsed, the prisons became in a sense annexes of the hospitals and
almshouses; a great number of offenses were committed with the sole
object of finding asylum....

“As to the children, we shall understand the imminence of the danger
when we realize that in the short space of three years, from 1845 to
1847, 26,247 children and young persons of both sexes under 18, were
incarcerated in prison or were inmates of workhouses. Most of these
children belonged to the two provinces of Flanders, and a great number
were arrested outside the limits of their province. Here is the
increase in the number of those received into the prisons of Ghent and
Bruges, and the jails of Audenarde, Termonde, Courtrai, Ypres, and
Furnes:


==========+==========================+=========================
          |Young Prisoners (under 18)|
          |       Received in        | Total during the 3 Yrs.
 Cities.  +--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+-------
          |  1845. |  1846. |  1847. |  Boys. | Girls. |General
          |        |        |        |        |        | Total.
----------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+-------
          |               Prisons of E. Flanders.
          +--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+-------
Ghent     |    350 |  1,345 |  1,898 |  2,671 |    922 |  3,593
Audenarde |    207 |    315 |    674 |    929 |    267 |  1,196
Termonde  |    123 |    235 |    406 |    616 |    148 |    764
          +--------+--------+--------+ -------+--------+-------
          |               Prisons of W. Flanders.
          +--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+-------
Bruges    |    459 |    299 |    550 |  1,110 |    198 |  1,308
Courtrai  |    116 |    170 |    331 |    560 |     57 |    617
Ypres     |     70 |    184 |    250 |    414 |     90 |    504
Furnes    |     43 |    139 |     57 |    151 |     88 |    239
          +--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+-------
Totals    |  1,368 |  2,687 |  4,166 |  6,451 |  1,770 |  8,221
==========+========+========+========+========+========+=======


“This deplorable fact of the increase of criminality among the young is
explained by the statistics of indigence. We see in fact that, among
the indigent persons aided in East Flanders, in 1847, there were:


==============================+===========+===========+========
                              |  In the   |   In the  |
                              |  Cities.  |  Country. |  Total.
------------------------------+-----------+-----------+--------
Indigent persons under 6 yrs. |   6,693   |   34,637  |  41,530
   ,,      ,,     ,,  12 ,,   |   8,327   |   37,437  |  45,764
   ,,      ,,     ,,  18 ,,   |   5,597   |   20,060  |  25,653
                              |           |           +--------
General total                                         | 112,947
======================================================+========


“Supposing that West Flanders, which has more dependents in proportion
than East Flanders, has the same proportion of children, we arrive at a
total for the two provinces, of 225,894 indigent persons whose age is
not above 18. In this number there are 174,588 who have not passed
their twelfth year! And there are thousands of orphans!

“Notwithstanding the improvement that begins to make itself felt,
thanks to the resumption of work and the low price of provisions, many
of these young unfortunates continue to give themselves up to begging
and vagrancy. But lately driven from their homes by cold and hunger,
they form a wandering population, incessantly buffeted from almshouse
to almshouse, from prison to prison.

“In Brussels at this present moment (July, 1849) there are still to be
found in the annex of the prison, about 250 mendicants, among whom are
97 children below the age of 17. In the prisons of Ghent and Bruges
their number is equally great.” [36]

“It is an established fact, then, that the increase of criminality in
Flanders has gone hand in hand with the extension of poverty. The
latter brings about the abandonment of homes; ... from this come
mendicity, vagrancy, marauding, and theft. The incarceration of so
great a number of unfortunates brings the most disastrous consequences.
The germs of corruption, brutality, and crime are continually injected
into a large fraction of the population. The habit of working is lost,
energy is relaxed, idleness becomes incurable. When we think especially
of the mass of children who, during the last few years, have passed
through the prisons and almshouses, we cannot picture without pity,
mingled with fear, the future of this generation, initiated at an early
age into the existence of criminals, and condemned to the dangers and
evils inseparable from the abandonment and degradation to which they
are a prey.” [37]




IV.

L. M. MOREAU-CHRISTOPHE. [38]

In speaking of England, after having sketched how industrialism, as it
spread more and more, drew after it an increase of pauperism, the
author says of the connection between criminality and economic
conditions:

“Parallel with the ascending figure for pauperism, rises the growing
figure for criminality. The number of persons arraigned at the assizes
of England and Wales has increased as follows:


=============+==========+===============
   Years.    | Totals.  |Annual Average.
-------------+----------+---------------
1814 to 1820 |  78,762  |    11,252
1821 to 1827 |  99,842  |    14,263
1828 to 1834 | 134,062  |    19,152
1834 to 1840 | 162,502  |    23,214
1841 to 1847 | 193,445  |    27,760
=============+==========+===============


“Thus in a space of thirty-four years the number of crimes has more
than doubled in England, while, in the same interval, the increase of
the population has hardly passed 40%.

“The parallelism between the growing pauperism and growing criminality
is even more striking when the comparison is applied to the delinquents
under the summary jurisdiction of the justices of the peace. Up to the
time of the establishment of the workhouses in 1834 the number of poor
persons assisted increased progressively from year to year. Well, the
number of persons arrested by the metropolitan police followed the same
progression. This number was 72,824 in 1831, and 77,543 in 1832. In
1833 the new poor law with its terrible workhouses was approaching;
consequently the number of arrests was no more than 69,959. In 1834 the
law was promulgated, and up to 1838 was executed with great rigor; as a
result the number of arrests fell to 64,269 in 1834, to 63,674 in 1835,
and to 63,584 in 1836. In 1837 the severity began to relax;
consequently the number of arrests increased to 64,416. In 1839 the
laxity continued, and the number of arrests increased to 70,717. Laxity
reached its height in 1842, and the number of arrests rose to 76,545;
this was an arrest to each 25 of the population.

“In Newcastle in 1837 the magistrates sentenced 1 person to 24 of the
whole population. In Leeds during a period of six years, from 1833 to
1838, there was one person arrested to 32 of the population. In
Manchester in 1841 ... the ratio of persons arrested, to the
population, was as 1 to 21.... In 1831, ten years earlier, the
proportion was still only 1 to 78. It almost quadrupled, then, in the
interval. In Liverpool in 1840 there was one arrest to 12 inhabitants.”
[39]




V.

G. MAYR.

The statistical data that form the basis of Dr. Mayr’s “Statistik der
gerichtlichen Polizei im Königreiche Bayern und in einigen anderen
Ländern” are different from those used in similar works. For, while
generally only the number of crimes whose authors have been convicted,
or that of delinquents punished, are considered, Dr. Mayr is of the
opinion that to obtain a true picture of the morality of a people, it
is necessary to take into account the number of crimes known to the
police. “If we wish really to form an exact picture of the moral
condition of a people, we must first of all ask ourselves the question,
how great is the number of the cases of crimes of different kinds that
are of common notoriety, before we ask how great is the number of the
individuals who are convicted of these crimes. The immorality of a
people is determined not by the number of individuals convicted, but by
the number of crimes committed; else that people would be most moral in
which no offender ever let himself be caught, even if more crimes were
committed there than elsewhere.” [40]



BAVARIA.

The results of Dr. Mayr’s researches in regard to crime in this country
are shown by him in a number of charts. [41]

Cis-Rhenal Territory. A comparison of the curves for crimes against
property and those for crimes against persons shows us that the first
descends as the other ascends, and vice versa. In seeking for the
causes we find that in general the motives for the latter class of
crime are, among others, coarseness, passion, and dissoluteness, while
that of the first kind of crime is the desire to secure objects for
direct use. The more difficult it is to gain a livelihood in a lawful
manner, the more this tendency will develop.

According to the author, the fluctuation in the price of grain is one
of the most important factors bearing upon criminality. And indeed, in
examining his nine statistical charts the connection between the high
or the low cost of grain, and the great or the small number of offenses
against property comes out clearly. The curve for offenses against
persons, on the other hand, falls when the price of grain rises, and
vice versa. The improvement of living conditions, both subjectively
(through having the means to purchase the necessaries) and objectively
(through a fall in prices) must consequently exercise a considerable
influence upon criminality. This is seen very well in the last years of
the period 1835–61, when the price of grain was low, and wages very
generally increased. Hence, from 1857 on, there was an increase in the
crimes against persons, and a decrease in the crimes against property.

It ought to be remarked here that however just in itself Dr. Mayr’s
observation may be, we must beware of drawing the erroneous conclusion
that those who feel most strongly the influence of the fall of prices
and the rise in wages must necessarily, according to a law of nature,
commit crimes against persons. This is true only for gross and
uncultivated individuals who do not know how to occupy their leisure.
But the degree of civilization of an individual depends above all upon
the economic conditions under which he was placed by his birth. There
are, then, economic causes for both kinds of crime.

Upper Bavaria. This district shows a higher figure for crime than any
other province in Bavaria. It is especially the great increase since
1857–1858 that is most striking, and which is explained at least
partially by the application of another system of examining offenses.
The increase in the number of crimes against the person is the
consequence of prosperous years, while the high figure for crimes
against property is explained by the great influx of individuals from
neighboring districts, who, from an economic standpoint, were not
independent. In the period from 1837 to 1864 the population increased
49,128 by birth, and 66,299 by immigration.

Lower Bavaria. The connection between crimes against property and the
price of grain is weaker in this province than in any of the others,
because of its great production of cereals, which, for the most part,
are destined for home consumption.

The upper Palatinate, Upper, Central, and Lower Franconia, and Swabia,
all give convincing proofs of Dr. Mayr’s thesis, though in Franconia
the truth is less apparent through the fact that bad years brought
increased emigration, which cut down the normal increase in the number
of crimes.



Where he treats of the different forms of crime, we read the following
remarks, which are of interest in connection with our subject: “As we
have just seen, crimes against persons increase when the price of grain
goes up. We must except from this rule, however, two kinds of crime:
infanticide and abortion.” The first of these crimes reached its
maximum in the critical years 1854–55, and the second in 1853–1854.

As a proof of the coincidence of the fluctuations of crimes against
property with those of the price of grain in the period preceding that
which he studied especially, Dr. Mayr gives the following table:


========+=================================+================
        |Number of Crimes against Property|
        |   to 100,000 of Population.     |
 Years. +--------------+------------------+ Price of Rye
        |  District of |  District of the |  in Munich.
        |   the Isar.  |   Lower Danube.  |
--------+--------------+------------------+----------------
1818/19 |       --     |       138        |   8 fl.  15 kr.
  19/20 |       --     |       148        |   6      31
  20/21 |       233    |       157        |   7      28
  21/22 |       297    |       200        |   7      58
  22/23 |       267    |       195        |   7      57
  23/24 |       276    |       --         |   6       2
  24/25 |       295    |       166        |   6      59
  25/26 |       317    |       157        |   6      18
  26/27 |       315    |       144        |   6      55
  27/28 |       463    |       241        |  11      11
  28/29 |       416    |       234        |  11       6
  29/30 |       401    |       216        |  10      48
  30/31 |       427    |       264        |  11      12
  31/32 |       530    |       302        |  12      35
  32/33 |       493    |       313        |   8      21
  33/34 |       --     |       318        |   8      42
  34/35 |       487    |       318        |   7      47
========+==============+==================+================


In chapter IV (“Zahl und Bewegung der Polizeiübertretungen im Gebiete
diesseits des Rheins”) Dr. Mayr gives some interesting information with
regard to thefts of wood. The following table gives the figures for
these crimes in this district compared with the others:


============================|============================
    Above the Average       |    Below the Average
  (Cis-Rhenal Territory).   |  (Cis-Rhenal Territory).
----------------------------+----------------------------
The Upper Palatinate   18 % |Central Franconia       1 %
Upper Franconia        80 ,,|Swabia                 63 ,,
Lower Franconia       178 ,,|Upper Bavaria        99.2 ,,
                            |Lower Bavaria        99.5 ,,
=========================================================


The great difference between these figures is explained by the fact
that in Lower Franconia only a quarter of the woods are privately owned
(the rest belonging to corporations, etc.). In Upper Bavaria the
private forests are 92%, and in Lower Bavaria 96½% of the whole.
Besides, the price of wood is very high in Lower Franconia. Once more,
then, economic conditions are the cause of crime.



Upon the movement of the figures for mendicity Dr. Mayr remarks that
they are strongly influenced by the cost of the primary necessities.
“The parallel movement of the food-price and mendicity offers little to
astonish us if we learn from the statistics of crimes that the
objective difficulty or ease of getting food resulting from the
fluctuations in price, exercises a direct influence upon increase and
decrease of serious crimes against property. It is explicable that only
a small portion of individuals who become economically dependent
proceed to serious crime, while the majority fall into the minor
misdemeanors involved in a living obtained through begging and
vagrancy. The same force that appears in the increase and decrease of
attacks upon property, must consequently appear much more intensively
in the fluctuations of mendicity and vagrancy.”


BAVARIA. [42]

=======+=======================+===============================================================================
       |    Price of Rye       |              Number of Mendicants and Vagrants Arrested to
       | (Bavarian Bushel).    |                        100,000 of the Population.
       +-----------+-----------+-------------+-----------+-----------+-----------------------+--------+--------
Years. | Cis-Rhenal|           |             |           |           |                       |        |
       | Territory.|Palatinate.|   Bavaria.  |           |           |      Franconia.       |        |
       +-----+-----+-----+-----+------+------+           |   Upper   +------+--------+-------+        |  The
       | fl. |  kr.| fl. |  kr.|Upper | Lower|Palatinate.|Palatinate.|Upper |Central | Lower |Swabia. |Kingdom.
-------+-----+-----+-----+-----+------+------+-----------+-----------+------+--------+-------+--------+--------
1835/36|   6 |  53 |  8  |  17 | 2696 | 1558 |   1542    |   1952    | 2165 |  1348  |   665 |  1456  |  1685
1836/37|   7 |  31 | 10  |  26 | 2100 | 1839 |   2075    |   2277    | 2421 |  1229  |   711 |  1262  |  1727
1837/38|  10 |  18 | 12  |  21 | 2065 | 2483 |   2472    |   2233    | 2255 |  1438  |   639 |  1306  |  1842
1838/39|  11 |  30 | 13  |  40 | 2232 | 1989 |   2056    |   2076    | 2195 |  1435  |   519 |  1640  |  1771
1839/40|  10 |  35 | 12  |   6 | 2032 | 1805 |   2238    |   2111    | 2584 |  1233  |   515 |  1829  |  1781
1840/41|   8 |  49 | 10  |   4 | 1887 | 1608 |   1845    |   1711    | 1810 |  1006  |   410 |  1531  |  1467
1841/42|   9 |  14 | 12  |  39 | 1777 | 1318 |   1878    |   1625    | 1814 |  1008  |   434 |  1599  |  1433
1842/43|  14 |  10 | 15  |  19 | 1810 | 1757 |   2479    |   2365    | 2679 |  1450  |   615 |  2177  |  1893
1843/44|  14 |   1 | 10  |  28 | 1905 | 1690 |   1970    |   2286    | 2264 |  1475  |   475 |  2151  |  1758
1844/45|  15 |  15 | 13  |  30 | 1857 | 1698 |   2411    |   2364    | 1412 |  1119  |   423 |  1722  |  1622
1845/46|  19 |  53 | 21  |  45 | 2182 | 1836 |   3528    |   2856    | 1447 |  1475  |   535 |  2332  |  2033
1846/47|  21 |  36 | 22  |  44 | 2902 | 2166 |   4276    |   3757    | 1904 |  1850  |   949 |  2586  |  2584
1847/48|  10 |  12 | 10  |  22 | 1916 | 1635 |   2704    |   2290    | 1348 |  1364  |   548 |  1985  |  1746
1848/49|   7 |  34 |  8  |  46 | 2269 | 1439 |   2555    |   1360    | 1015 |  1270  |   586 |  1545  |  1563
1849/50|   7 |  57 |  8  |  57 | 2346 | 1528 |   2801    |   1782    |  991 |  1351  |   716 |  1893  |  1686
1850/51|  12 |  20 | 13  |  10 | 2213 | 1790 |   3269    |   1734    | 1096 |  1294  |  1002 |  2023  |  1845
1851/52|  17 |  53 | 15  |  57 | 2927 | 2243 |   4562    |   3030    | 1637 |  2274  |  2236 |  2969  |  2705
1852/53|  17 |  39 | 17  |  46 | 2572 | 1918 |   5010    |   2289    | 2017 |  1795  |  2165 |  2535  |  2592
1853/54|  23 |  38 | 24  |  13 | 2932 | 2097 |   5854    |   2983    | 2127 |  2282  |  2894 |  2671  |  3027
1854/55|  23 |  19 | 23  |  38 | 2964 | 2591 |   5026    |   3326    | 2470 |  2215  |  2831 |  2804  |  3229
1855/56|  17 |  45 | 22  |   2 | 2423 | 1817 |   4637    |   2367    | 2050 |  1595  |  2515 |  1939  |  2443
1856/57|  15 |  26 | 18  |   5 | 2157 | 1724 |   3265    |   2059    | 1176 |  1412  |  1931 |  1435  |  1922
1857/58|  12 |  31 | 12  |  58 | 1956 | 1237 |   2595    |   1537    |  588 |   974  |  1621 |  1203  |  1505
1858/59|  10 |  28 | 12  |  13 | 1949 | 1170 |   2309    |   1334    |  462 |   497  |   940 |  1029  |  1255
1859/60|  11 |  45 | 15  |  15 | 2084 | 1219 |   2622    |   1538    |  525 |   890  |   994 |  1105  |  1419
1860/61|  14 |   8 | 16  |  19 | 2055 | 1304 |   2580    |   1318    |  484 |   720  |   750 |  1069  |  1336
       +-----+-----+-----+-----+------+------+-----------+-----------+------+--------+-------+--------+--------
Average|  13 |  35 | 14  |  44 | 2234 | 1741 |   3083    |   2155    | 1649 |  1388  |  1120 |  1842  |  1920
=======+=====+=====+=====+=====+======+======+===========+===========+======+========+=======+========+========



ENGLAND.

In speaking of the influence of economic conditions upon mendicity Dr.
Mayr gives the following table:


ENGLAND AND WALES.

=========+=========================+===================
Years.   |Price of Wheat (Quarter).|Number of Vagrants.
---------+-------------------------+-------------------
         |         sh.  d.         |
1858     |         44   2          |      22,559
1859     |         43  10          |      23,353
1860     |         53   3          |      22,666
1861     |         55   4          |      24,001
1862     |         55   5-1/2      |      29,504
1863     |         44   9          |      33,182
1864     |         40   2          |      31,932
=========+=========================+===================


However, in this case the increase of mendicity does not rest upon the
high prices alone, but also upon the crisis which, owing to the
depression of the cotton industry from 1860 on, lowered the plane of
living of hundreds of thousands of workers, or drove them into the
street.


ENGLAND AND WALES.

Number and Kind of Cases Tried by Jury.

========+========+=========+=========+===============+=========+=========+======
        |Offenses|Offenses |Offenses |    Forgery    |Violent  |  Other  |Total.
        |against |against  |against  |      and      |Attacks  |Offenses.|
Years.  |Persons.|Property |Property |Counterfeiting.|against  |         |
        |        |  with   |without  |               |Property.|         |
        |        |Violence.|Violence.|               |         |         |
--------+--------+---------+---------+---------------+---------+---------+------
1858    |   14   |   29    |   233   |      13       |   2.5   |   4.5   |  296
1859    |   13   |   22    |   209   |      11       |   3     |   5     |  263
1860    |   11   |   20    |   207   |       8.5     |   2.5   |   4     |  253
1861    |   12   |   25    |   200   |       8.5     |   2.5   |   4     |  252
1862    |   12.5 |   28    |   203   |       9.5     |   3     |   6     |  262
1863    |   14.5 |   26    |   194   |       9       |   3.5   |   7     |  254
1864    |   15   |   24    |   190   |       6.5     |   3.5   |   7     |  246
        +--------+---------+---------+---------------+---------+---------+------
Average |   13   |   25    |   205   |       9       |   3     |   5     |  260
========+========+=========+=========+===============+=========+=========+======


Here the influence of the fall of prices is distinctly seen; offenses
against property have decreased, those against persons, on the
contrary, have increased.


ENGLAND AND WALES.

Total Offenses Tried by Jury, and Offenses not Specified.

========+==========================+===========================
Years.  |Assaults upon Persons to  |  Attacks upon Property
        |100,000 of the Population.|without Violence to 100,000
        |                          |     of the Population.
--------+--------------------------+---------------------------
1858    |          439             |           439
1859    |          438             |           399
1860    |          399             |           392
1861    |          383             |           415
1862    |          403             |           433
1863    |          436             |           392
1864    |          469             |           365
        +--------------------------+---------------------------
Average |          426             |           405
========+==========================+===========================


The great fall in the price of grain in 1863–1864 is once more
accompanied by a diminution of the offenses against property, and an
increase in those against persons.

We might conclude from this table that the remark concerning crimes
against property and those against persons is not applicable, since in
1858 the number of crimes against property was very high,
notwithstanding the reduced price of grain. Here is Dr. Mayr’s
explanation of it:

“The reason must be the following: The occasion for high spirits to be
found in improved living conditions follows immediately upon any such
improvement, and disappears at once when times grow worse. For this
reason the fluctuation in attacks upon persons harmonizes exactly with
the fluctuation in the price of food. The effects of hard times are
only partially such as lead to punishable offenses; in most cases
economic ruin occurs first, which leads only after an interval to
attacks upon property. For this reason the effects of hard times
continue to manifest themselves at a time when the hard times
themselves are already practically over. This is the explanation both
of the great number of attacks upon property in the year 1857, when the
effects of the immediately preceding hard times were making themselves
felt, as well as the gradual increase in the number of attacks against
property in the years 1860–1862.” [43]


Number of Persons against whom Action was Brought for Abandonment.

                    ========|================
                    Years.  | To 100,000 of
                            | the Population.
                    --------|----------------
                     1858   |      20
                     1859   |      18
                     1860   |      17
                     1861   |      21
                     1862   |      21
                     1863   |      19
                     1864   |      18
                            |----------------
                    Average |      19
                    =========================


The fall in the price of grain in 1863–1864 was accompanied by a
diminution in the number of crimes of this kind.


Violations of the Vagrant Act to 100,000 of the Population.

=======+============+===========+==========+=========+===============+=============+============+==============+======
Years. |Prostitutes.|Mendicants.| Without  |Furnished| Presence in a | Presence in |Incorrigible|Other Offenses|Total.
       |            |           |  Means   |Burglar's|Closed Building|Public Places| Vagabonds. | against the  |
       |            |           |    of    |   with  |with Criminal  |with Criminal|            | Vagrant Act. |
       |            |           |Existence.|  Tools. |   Intent.     |   Intent.   |            |              |
-------+------------+-----------+----------+---------+---------------+-------------+------------+--------------+------
1858   |    51.4    |   50.2    |   18.9   |   0.3   |    14.2       |   18.0      |    2.0     |    13.0      |  168
1859   |    37.1    |   39.2    |   15.9   |   0.3   |    12.2       |   12.7      |    1.6     |    12.0      |  131
1860   |    33.6    |   37.9    |   15.2   |   0.2   |    11.5       |   10.1      |    1.2     |     9.4      |  119
1861   |    35.4    |   41.3    |   17.7   |   0.4   |    12.5       |   11.7      |    1.2     |    10.7      |  131
1862   |    41.4    |   55.4    |   20.1   |   0.4   |    14.0       |   14.5      |    2.1     |    12.8      |  161
1863   |    39.2    |   52.9    |   18.6   |   0.2   |    13.3       |   15.3      |    2.5     |    15.5      |  157
1864   |    35.8    |   46.0    |   18.0   |   0.2   |    13.3       |   14.8      |    2.2     |    12.7      |  143
       +------------+-----------+----------+---------+---------------+-------------+------------+--------------+------
Average|    39.7    |   46.1    |   17.7   |   0.3   |    13.0       |   13.9      |    1.8     |    12.3      |  144
=======+============+===========+==========+=========+===============+=============+============+==============+======


The maximum number of infractions of the Vagrant Act took place in
1858, when the harmful consequences of the rise in the price of grain,
which took place immediately before, were still making themselves felt.
The increase in 1861–1862 was the result of the high price of wheat,
and of the crisis in the cotton industry.


France.

=======+=========================+======================
       |Arrests in the Department|Average Price of Grain
Years. | of the Seine to 100,000 |   per Hectolitre.
       |   of the Population.    |
-------+-------------------------+----------------------
1855   |        1222             |   fr.  29.37
1856   |        1170             |        30.22
1857   |        1169             |        23.83
1858   |        1154             |        16.44
1859   |        1008             |        16.69
1860   |        1074             |        20.41
1861   |        1128             |        24.25
1862   |        1250             |        23.24
1863   |        1133             |        19.78
1864   |        1158             |        17.58
=======+=========================+======================


Here also the influence of price makes itself felt.

The following table gives the number of persons arrested in the
department of the Seine, grouped according to the alleged crimes, and
compared with the price of wheat. Group I contains offenses against the
public order; Group II, offenses against persons; Group III, offenses
against morals; group IV, offenses against property; Group V,
miscellaneous. Taking 100 as the average figure for the price of grain
as well as for crimes in the economically favorable years 1858–59, the
proportion is as follows:


======+======+==============================+===================+=====+=============+=====+======
      |Price |              I.              |        II.        | III.|      IV.    |  V. |
      |  of  +------------------------------+------+------------+-----+------+------+-----+
Years.|Wheat.|Total.|    For     |    For   |Total.|   For      |     |Total.|Simple|     |Total.
      |      |      |Vagabondage.|Mendicity.|      |Assault.[44]|     |      |Theft.|     |
------+------+------+------------+----------+------+------------+-----+------+------+-----+------
1855  | 178  | 128  |    122     |   148    |  76  |    72      | 100 |  102 | 116  | 106 |  113
1856  | 182  | 117  |    118     |   114    |  81  |    80      | 104 |  106 | 121  |  92 |  108
1857  | 144  | 119  |    127     |   117    |  82  |    81      |  98 |  101 | 114  | 100 |  108
1860  | 123  |  96  |     90     |   134    | 103  |   106      | 100 |  110 | 123  |  80 |   99
1861  | 146  |  95  |     99     |   105    |  95  |    96      | 131 |  116 | 124  | 103 |  104
1862  | 140  | 120  |    128     |   147    |  94  |    98      | 108 |  116 | 131  | 108 |  116
1863  | 119  | 112  |    119     |   186    |  90  |    94      |  92 |  101 | 114  |  97 |  105
1864  | 106  | 115  |    124     |   176    |  84  |    87      |  85 |  111 | 123  |  84 |  107
======+======+======+============+==========+======+============+=====+======+======+=====+======


Here it is to be observed:

a. that the movement of mendicity and vagrancy is not in direct
correlation with that of the price of grain.

b. that Group IV shows only a slight correlation with the price of
grain, since there are included in it many crimes whose causes are not
of an economic nature.

c. that during the last years of this period the increase of crimes
against property was greater than the figures for the price of grain
would lead one to suppose; a fact which is explained, according to Dr.
Mayr, by the lack of work resulting from the war of secession.

The law that crimes against persons increase with the fall of prices is
confirmed by these statistics.




VI.

A. CORNE. [45]

According to this author the laws regulating moral phenomena are at
present hidden by thick clouds.

“We may await with confidence the dissipation of these clouds, when
some great principle, about which our observations of detail will group
themselves, will appear to us in a flood of light. Everything seems to
indicate to me that this master principle is no other than the
principle of activity. In fact, the first rudiments of social science
have as yet been given us only by political economy, and its sole
foundation is the affirmation of human activity. On the other hand,
since giving myself up without any preconceptions to this special study
of criminality I have been little by little led by a close examination
of the facts, to find the general cause of crimes in the absence of
this principle of activity.

“When we reflect upon this, it appears quite in the natural order of
things that the development of criminality, that is to say of the
spirit of destruction and dissolution, should manifest itself at the
time of the weakening or disappearance of the generative principle of
all production and of all society. There is here, then, if I am not
deceived, more than a mere coincidence. There is a relationship which
deserves to be noted so much the more since it is from the principle of
activity that all physical laws also are derived today.” [46]

Let us accompany the author to the domain of facts. After having given
an exposition of the movement of criminality in France in comparison
with that of other countries, he finally takes up the question of
etiology. For the crowd, says the author, the criminal is a kind of
monster in the midst of society, a monster predestined to crime because
of his innate tendencies. Looked at in this way criminality is an
individual evil. Corne, on the contrary, believes it to be a social
evil. For, however much society may be developed in all respects, it is
nevertheless always imperfect, since the ignorance and corruption of
morals are great. The author lays stress upon two facts, namely, the
corruption of morals in the upper classes, and militarism. Not only
does militarism draw after it the ruin of peoples, and develop man’s
violent instincts, but it has still other very serious moral
consequences, by forcing celibacy upon young men at the passionate age.

The author admits that there are facts which might seem to give the lie
to his opinion—the influence, for example, of the price of grain upon
the decrease and increase of criminality.


========+======================+=================
Years.  | Average Price of a   |Number of Persons
        | Hectolitre of Wheat. |   Arraigned.
--------+----------------------+----------------=
        |      fr.  c.         |
 1850   |      14   32         |     147,757
 1851   |      14   48         |     146,368
 1852   |      16   75         |     159,791
 1853   |      22   39         |     171,351
 1854   |      28   82         |     170,940
 1855   |      29   32         |     163,748
 1856   |      30   75         |     162,049
 1857   |      24   37         |     161,556
 1858   |      16   75         |     157,815
 1859   |      16   75         |     150,948
 1860   |      20   24         |     144,301
 1861   |      24   55         |     151,112
 1862   |      23   24         |     152,332
 1863   |      19   78         |     144,072
 1864   |      17   58         |     146,230
========+======================+=================


Although, according to Corne, the high price of grain may be only an
accidental fact, there must yet be some importance attached to it in
view of the disastrous consequences which may result from it to
families that have in any case a hard time to make both ends meet. But
the figures given above do not prove the influence to be very great.
For prices rise sometimes although the other figures fall, and vice
versa. And then the sudden increase of [detected] crime from 1849 to
1853 must be attributed to a better organization of the police.

Then the author gives the following table:


========+======================+===========================
Years.  |     Price of a       |Number of Persons Convicted
        | Hectolitre of Wheat. | of Attacks upon Property
        |                      |(to 1000 of Population).
--------+----------------------+---------------------------
        |      fr.  c.         |
 1850   |      14   32         |          147,757
 1851   |      14   48         |          146,368
 1852   |      16   75         |          159,791
 1853   |      22   39         |          171,351
 1854   |      28   82         |          170,940
 1855   |      29   32         |          163,748
 1856   |      30   75         |          162,049
 1857   |      24   37         |          161,556
 1858   |      16   75         |          157,815
 1859   |      16   75         |          150,948
 1860   |      20   24         |          144,301
 1861   |      24   55         |          151,112
 1862   |      23   24         |          152,332
 1863   |      19   78         |          144,072
 1864   |      14   32         |          146,230
========+======================+===========================


We see that the coincidence of the figures is here naturally greater
than in the first table.

“The situation of criminals may be summed up in a word: isolation. Most
of them hardly know what a family is. They are miserable, they have no
home, no fixed occupation which attaches them little by little to men
and things. They are immersed in the gloom of ignorance. Aside from
what affects their immediate physical wants the rest of the world is
for them as if it did not exist.” [47] They are alone, isolated from
birth. For among juvenile prisoners there are reckoned not only many
illegitimate and orphaned children, but also many who have been
deserted. Out of 8006 young criminals in prison December 31st, 1864,
60% were illegitimate, orphaned, or deserted.

The author then depicts the environment in which the children of the
proletariat ordinarily grow up—bad hygienic conditions, demoralizing
surroundings, etc.—and points out the harmful effect of labor in
factories upon the young. Corne also considers celibacy to be one of
the causes of crime, since the individual has no one to care for him or
be interested in his fate. Crime is developed much more in the great
cities than in the country, for the reason, the author thinks, that men
are much more isolated, much more left to themselves in the city than
in rural neighborhoods.

—Here I would remark that it is for economic reasons that men are
prevented from marrying, and that the great criminality of cities is
best explained by the marked difference in economic situation, and by
the more frequent opportunities for wrong-doing found there.—

According to Corne one of the best preventives of crimes is property,
since it engenders a feeling of responsibility. The property owner
exerts himself to increase his wealth, and hence property has a moral
influence. [48]

“Criminality comes from a lack of vitality. It is an anemia. In order
to prevent it we must excite a desire for activity.” It is in this that
the usefulness of education appears. The man who knows how to read and
write, has in his hands an instrument which can multiply his means of
action indefinitely. [49]

—As regards education, it has been proved that Corne and many others
have exaggerated its importance for the etiology of crime. When
education extends beyond the art of reading and writing, it has a
civilizing influence, and causes a diminution of violent crimes, but it
does not result in a decrease of criminality in general, since the
economic causes of crime remain. Education changes, indeed, the nature
of criminality, but not its extent. [50]—

The author concludes by saying “The man who has a family, who has
property, who is educated, who is known by his fellow citizens and has
his share of influence upon them, can not be the individual whom we
have seen to be criminal, because of weakness and isolation ... he has
energy, determination, and can control his passions because he is
surrounded and sustained, because a thousand bonds of interest and
affection attach him to society, order, and property.” [51]




VII.

H. VON VALENTINI.

The work “Das Verbrecherthum im Preussischen Staat”, published in 1869
by Prison-director von Valentini, treats especially of the results
obtained by the penal system then in force in Prussia, and of the means
of improving it.

Von Valentini sees in crime primarily the consequence of social
conditions, at least he considers that the best means of combating it
is for society to prevent the criminal tendency from manifesting
itself, and make efforts to raise the moral level of the people. For,
according to our author, 90% of the criminals are “purely material and
entirely neglected” and ought to “undergo a spiritual regeneration.”
[52]

After these general observations he proceeds to more particular
observations upon the criminals themselves in society. He examines
statistically the proportion of criminals in the population. Obtaining
different proportions for different districts of Prussia he
investigates the causes. For this purpose he classifies crimes as:
first, crimes from personal interest, and second, crimes from passion.
Finding then that the provinces of the East give 9% of crimes from
personal interest more than the others, he thinks he has found the
cause in “an existing destitution both material and intellectual, and
in the arrangement of the prisons.” [53]

Chapter Three, upon the “Dimensionen des Nothstandes” contains detailed
tables for each province, the great cities, and the rich and poor
countries. He obtains, then, the following result for the eight
provinces:


======================+===========+===========+==============+=============
                      | Pauperism |           |Percentage of |Ratio of the
                      |  Number   |  To 100   |Crimes against|Percentage of
                      |of Indigent|  of the   | Property to  | the Crimes
Provinces.            |Persons in |Population.|100,000 of the|  against
                      |the Poorest|           | Population.  |  Property
                      |Districts. |           |              | to that of
                      |           |           |              | Pauperism.
----------------------+-----------+-----------+--------------+-------------
Posen                 |   536,495 |   36.1    |    32.89     |   0.91 : 1
Prussia               |   792,948 |   27.6    |    24.69     |   0.89 : 1
Pomerania             |   314,383 |   22.6    |    20.57     |   0.91 : 1
Silesia               |   517,528 |   15.2    |    36.94     |   2.43 : 1
                      +-----------+-----------+--------------+-------------
Total of Eastern group| 2,161,354 |   23.6    |   115.09     |   4.91 : 1
                      |           |           |              |
Rhenish provinces     |   397,350 |   12.0    |     5.59     |   0.46 : 1
Brandenburg           |    84,011 |    3.4    |    26.27     |   7.72 : 1
Westphalia            |    45,849 |    2.8    |     9.21     |   3.29 : 1
Saxony                |   259,901 |    1.3    |    18.33     |  14.10 : 1
                      +-----------+-----------+--------------+-------------
Total of Western group|   553,111 |    5.9    |    59.40     |  25.57 : 1
======================+===========+===========+==============+=============


Another thing that strikes him is the influence of the small landed
proprietor. “The possession of even a small piece of property in land
... is no slight preventative of crime against property.” [54] The
author gives the following statistical summary.

He ranks in the class of small land holdings estates of 30 acres [55]
and below. The total amounts to 10,655,460 acres to 1,716,535 estates,
with an average of 6 acres.

There were in the following provinces:


Posen                        57,519 of these estates, or 1 to 25 inhabitants.
Prussia                      93,793    ,,      ,,       ,,    30     ,,
Pomerania                    61,752    ,,      ,,       ,,    22     ,,
Silesia                     230,710    ,,      ,,       ,,    14     ,,
                            -------
Total of the Eastern group  443,774    ,,      ,,       ,,    18     ,,

Rhenish provinces           788,473    ,,      ,,       ,,     4     ,,
Brandenburg                 112,532    ,,      ,,       ,,    22     ,,
Westphalia                  197,383    ,,      ,,       ,,     8     ,,
Saxony                      174,373    ,,      ,,       ,,    11     ,,
                          ---------
Total of Western group    1,272,761    ,,      ,,       ,,     8     ,,


“The Rhenish provinces alone, then, have nearly twice as many as the
four Eastern provinces together! This explains the figure, 5.59, for
this district given in the table above, taken in connection with the
noteworthy care given to the poor. Can the connection between the
ratios given above and those of the occurrence of crimes against
property be denied?” [56]

In this connection he treats of housing conditions, for which he gives
the following figures.

Dwellings to 1 league:


              Posen        258   Rhenish Provinces    901
              Prussia      230   Brandenburg          304
              Pomerania    218   Westphalia           579
              Silesia      546   Saxony               529
              Total       1252   Total               2313


A more detailed summary of the number of inhabitants shows us that
there were:


=================+======+========+==========+========+=======+============+===========+=======
                 |Posen.|Prussia.|Pomerania.|Silesia.|Rhenish|Brandenburg.|Westphalia.|Saxony.
                 |      |        |          |        | Prov. |            |           |
-----------------+------+--------+----------+--------+-------+------------+-----------+-------
                 |Inhab.| Inhab. |  Inhab.  | Inhab. | Inhab.|   Inhab.   |  Inhab.   | Inhab.
                 |      |        |          |        |       |            |           |
In each dwelling |  9.8 |   9.8  |   10.1   |   7.9  |   6.9 |    10.0    |    7.2    |   7.5
In the cities    | 11.2 |  13.2  |   11.6   |  13.3  |  10.4 |    14.0    |    8.7    |   9.8
In the hamlets   |  8.8 |  10.6  |   10.0   |   8.1  |   6.1 |     9.6    |    7.0    |   6.8
In the villages  |  9.3 |   8.4  |    9.3   |   7.0  |   5.7 |     7.7    |    6.7    |   6.5
=================+======+========+==========+========+=======+============+===========+=======


In these figures von Valentini sees a parallelism with those for small
holdings, and draws the conclusion that this isolation of households is
one of the best preventives of crimes against property.




VIII.

A. VON OETTINGEN. [57]

In chapter IV (“Die ungeordnete Geschlechtsgemeinschaft und die
Prostitution”), the author treats of the influence of the fluctuations
of price in certain important articles of food upon crimes against
property, against morals, against persons, and incendiary crimes
(Prussia). [58]


Percentage.

=======+========+======+=========+========+============
Year.  |Offenses|Arson.|Offenses |Offenses| Combined
       |against |      | against |against | Price per
       |Morals. |      |Property.|Persons.| Bushel of
       |        |      |         |        |Wheat, Rye,
       |        |      |         |        |and Potatoes
       |        |      |         |        |in Groschen.
-------+--------+------+---------+--------+------------
 1854  |  2.26  | 0.43 |  88.41  |   8.90 |    218.1
 1855  |  2.57  | 0.46 |  88.93  |   8.04 |    252.3
 1856  |  2.65  | 0.43 |  87.60  |   9.32 |    203.3
 1857  |  4.14  | 0.53 |  81.52  |  13.81 |    156.3
 1858  |  4.45  | 0.60 |  77.92  |  17.03 |    149.3
 1859  |  4.68  | 0.52 |  78.17  |  16.63 |    150.6
       +--------+------+---------+--------+------------
Average|  3.34  | 0.48 |  84.42  |  11.76 |    188.2
=======+========+======+=========+========+============


This table shows then: first, that crimes against property diminish as
prices fall; second, that under these same conditions crimes against
morals and against persons increase.

—We must be on our guard, however, against drawing false conclusions
from this second fact. The relationship in question is observed only
during a certain period and in certain countries, and is not to be
regarded as a law of nature, i.e., it must not be understood that an
improvement in economic conditions invariably causes an increase in
sexual and violent crimes. If this were the case, the well-to-do
classes, who are always in a position to provide for all their needs,
would furnish most of the criminals of this description. The facts show
just the contrary to occur everywhere. (See Part Two, where I treat
this subject fully.)—

In the chapter, “Die social ethische Lebensbethätigung in der
bürgerlichen Rechtsphäre,” the author treats our subject more fully.
Reasoning from different data taken from other authors, he points out
the connection between economic conditions on the one hand and
vagabondage and mendicity on the other. Having shown a considerable
increase in these offenses in the revolutionary period of 1848, he
attributes this increase to the lack of social discipline, for the
price of provisions was then low. We pass all this part of von
Oettingen’s book in silence, his data being taken for the most part
from other authors. We would merely point out his error in ranking the
year 1848 among those economically favorable because of the fall in the
price of food. As a matter of fact there was a terrible economic crisis
in Europe at the time.

We take the following data from the section entitled “Getreidepreise
und Kriminalität.”

To 100 complaints there were (in Prussia):


=======+======================+=============
       |    Crimes against    | Price of Rye
Years. +-----------+----------+ per Bushel.
       | Property. | Persons. |
-------+-----------+----------+-------------
       |     %     |     %    |   Sgr. Pf.
1862   |   44.3    |   15.8   |    63.10
1863   |   41.6    |   17.0   |    54.3
1864   |   41.6    |   18.4   |    45.6
1865   |   38.5    |   17.7   |    49.11
1866   |   44.4    |   14.5   |    58.5
1867   |   50.2    |   13.1   |    79.0
1868   |   52.3    |   13.8   |    78.8
1869   |   45.7    |   14.3   |    64.7
=======+===========+==========+=============


We find here this rule, that a rise in the price of food is accompanied
by an increase in the crimes against property and a decrease in crimes
against persons, and vice versa. This table also shows that, if a very
pronounced rise in prices has caused a great increase in criminality,
the later fall in prices does not make itself felt in the number of
crimes until some time after its commencement. (See 1867–1868.)

This phenomenon is very distinctly shown by the following table:


========+==============+=================================
Years.  | Cases Tried. |Total Price of a Bushel of Wheat,
        |              |      of Rye, and of Potatoes
        |              |          in Groschen.
--------+--------------+---------------------------------
1854    |   644,483    |           221.6
1855    |   686,207    |           241.4
1856    |   766,628    |           228.4
1857    |   705,291    |           161.1
========+==============+=================================


It was only in 1857, then, that the fall in prices, beginning in 1856,
commenced to produce its effect.

In conclusion we call attention to the following tables:


Saxony.

========+=======================+============================
Years.  |    Crimes Against     | Price of Wheat, of Rye, and
        +-----------+-----------+   of Potatoes per Bushel.
        | Property. |  Persons. |
--------+-----------+-----------+----------------------------
        |           |           |           Gr.
1860    |  37.25    |  35.04    |           170
1861    |  40.28    |  33.10    |           181
1862    |  38.78    |  34.65    |           173
1863    |  36.56    |  35.09    |           147
========+===========+===========+============================


Bavaria.

========+=======================+============================
Years.  |   Offenses against    |       Price of Rye.
        +-----------+-----------+
        | Property. |  Persons. |
--------+-----------+-----------+----------------------------
        |           |           |          Fl.  Kr.
1862/63 |  38.38    |  33.16    |          14, 48
1863/64 |  36.16    |  37.72    |          12, 16
1864/65 |  36.55    |  39.79    |          11, 53
1865/66 |  33.42    |  41.18    |          10, 57
========+===========+===========+============================


Here is another proof of the rule, then, that crimes against property
decrease and those against persons increase as prices fall.




IX.

H. STURSBERG.

In the first part of a brochure edited in 1878 and entitled, “Die
Zunahme der Vergehen und Verbrechen und ihre Ursache,” the author
attempts, with the aid of statistics, to discover in what measure
criminality increased or decreased in Germany during the years
1871–1877. As a result of these researches he finds a considerable
increase in all Germany. [59]

As regards the causes of this increase, Stursberg, though not rejecting
entirely the opinion of Quetelet that society prepares the crime and
that the criminal is only the instrument that executes it, is
nevertheless of the opinion that it is very necessary to take into
account the personal factor, i.e. the presence or absence of religious
and moral sentiments.

There are those, says the author, who seek the cause in the
consequences of the war against France. Although believing also that
the war has had unfavorable effects upon criminality, it is impossible,
in his opinion that this war should be the cause of the increase of
criminality, since crime decreased after the wars of 1864 and 1866. He
considers that one of the causes is the great mildness of the penalties
imposed by the new penal code of the empire. But according to him, this
is not important, for since 1871 there has been rather a diminution
than an increase of recidivism. Nor can bad economic conditions be the
cause, says Stursberg; for criminality had already begun to increase
before the bad years, and it is not theft that has increased the most.
Nevertheless, Stursberg recognizes that prolonged poverty weakens the
moral sentiments, which shows that criminality and poverty are closely
connected.

But there are, in his opinion, more serious causes. There follows a
description of the impetus taken by industry in Germany during the
early seventies, a description not easily surpassed in pointlessness,
and in the naïve ignorance that it evinces. Without comprehending the
significance of the really important events that are happening about
him, the author fulminates against certain consequences of modern
capitalism.

—This appears to him as the consequence of a suddenly awakened desire
for riches. But why should this desire arise at this time? The author
does not tell us. But notwithstanding this he has unquestionably
discovered here one of the principal causes, since the prodigious
increase of industry, shortly followed by the inevitable crisis, has
infallibly caused an increase in criminality. Since Stursberg treats
this question rather as a moralist than as a man of science, we have no
interest in spending longer time upon it.—

In the first few pages of his brochure Stursberg speaks of the
disastrous consequences of alcoholism, after the enactment of the law
of 1869, which increased the number of spirit shops. Armed with
quotations without number he combats in turn the cafés-chantants,
immoral literature, etc., etc.; after which he introduces all at once
the matter of professional liberty. He speaks of the “influence,
impossible to estimate, which honest and pious masters exercised for
centuries upon the journeymen and apprentices, who were like members of
the family.” “The freedom of the trades came in and loosed the bonds of
piety and discipline which had retained the journeyman and apprentices
in the home of their master.”

—As far as we can see, the ideas of the author are rather those of a
writer of the Middle Ages, than of a contemporary of modern capitalism.
It cannot be denied that there is truth at the bottom of this
reasoning. For it is incontestable that in the time of the guilds the
position of the journeymen was in general more favorable than that of
the proletariat today. But it does not follow that the religion of the
master was the cause of this. And a demonstration in which professional
liberty is represented as being in fact a legislative error, and not
the logical and inevitable consequence of the birth of modern
capitalism, is so unscientific that it has no place in an investigation
into the causes of the increase of criminality.—

Then he preaches more particularly against the greater and greater
extension of the study of the natural sciences, against social
democracy, the lack of respect for constituted authorities, etc., etc.,
without, however, alleging the slightest proof of the connection of all
this with the increase of crime. But at the end he says, “the
fundamental cause of the increase of crime is the rapid growth of
irreligion, and the weakening of Christian sentiment in church and
school.” [60]




X.

L. FULD.

Before entering upon his special investigation, the author of “Der
Einfluss der Lebensmittelpreise auf die Bewegung der strafbaren
Handlungen” makes the following observation: Everywhere it is noted
that assaults upon morals with acts of violence increase when the price
of provisions falls. Adhering to the opinion of von Oettingen that “as
the consequence of an increase of prosperity, the tendency to crime
shows itself more by crimes against morals than by those against
property”, Fuld also mentions the opinion of Valentini, that “in this
case the people become audacious and commit these crimes more easily.”

Here are other salient facts; that the number of young criminals
increases, and that the city produces more criminals than the country,
although the sexual morality especially is far from ideal in the
country. Finally in speaking of the influence of profession, Fuld
mentions that the increase in the number of criminals which accompanies
a rise in prices is greater for the first offenders than for
recidivists. The following table which he gives to prove this point,
however, plainly fails to do so:


England.

========+===================+===============+==================
Years.  |   Good Character  |   Character   |  Price of Wheat.
        |     Hitherto.     |    Unknown.   |
--------+-------------------+---------------+------------------
        |                   |               |     Sh.  d.
1858    |      153,576      |    138,388    |      43  11
1859    |      153,369      |    150,084    |      43  8
1860    |      137,574      |    144,485    |      52  9
1864    |      167,038      |    165,808    |      40  2
========+===================+===============+==================


The author explains that the crimes against property are one of the
consequences of the struggle for existence, a fact which accounts in
part for the high figures for criminality in the great cities, where
competition is most intense. The author treats of theft, and begins by
saying that the connection between the price of provisions and theft is
very close.


France.

=========+===========+====================
Years.   |  Thefts.  |  Price of Cereals.
---------+-----------+--------------------
         |           |        fr.
1856     |  18,222   |       16.75
1857     |  17,218   |        ,,
1858     |  15,537   |        ,,
1859     |  14,755   |        ,,
1860     |  15,707   |       20.24
=========+===========+====================


During the following years the prices fell. Nevertheless the number of
thefts increased. According to Fuld we can draw the conclusion that the
influence of price is only relative!—This table proves little. For,
while in 1856 criminality attained its highest point, prices were lower
than in 1860; and, while the figures for theft diminished greatly,
prices remained constant.—


England.

=========+=====================================+==================
Years.   |              Thefts.                | Price of Cereals.
         +-----------------+-------------------+
         |  With Violence. | Without Violence. |
---------+-----------------+-------------------+------------------
         |                 |                   |    Sh.  d.
1857     |      6471       |      43,397       |     42  10
1858     |      5723       |      45,618       |     43  11
1859     |      4433       |      41,370       |     43   8
1860     |      4065       |      41,151       |     52   9
1861     |      5062       |      40,242       |     55   4
1862     |      5746       |      40,191       |     55   5
1863     |      5433       |      39,801       |     44   9
1864     |      5022       |      39,481       |     40   2
1865     |      5160       |      40,383       |     41  10
1866     |      5088       |      39,731       |     43  10
1867     |      6355       |      46,502       |     49  10
=========+=================+===================+==================


Here there is some agreement between the number of thefts and prices.
But it is not as great as Fuld would make out. For example,
notwithstanding the sudden rise on prices in 1860, criminality
diminished, while the year following there was a still further fall in
the thefts without violence.


Prussia.

=========+==================+================
Years.   | Thefts of Wood.  |  Price of Rye.
---------+------------------+----------------
         |                  |     Sgr. Pf.
1862     |     387,000      |      63.10
1863     |     354,276      |      54.3
1864     |     366,667      |      45.6
1865     |     426,336      |      49.11
1866     |     425,551      |      58.5
1867     |     412,165      |      79.0
1868     |     419,158      |      78.8
1869     |     406,662      |      64.7
1870     |     389,746      |      62.3
1871     |     439,288      |      66.0
1872     |     401,280      |      82.0
1873     |     337,112      |      93.0
1874     |     356,859      |     108.0
=========+==================+================


We can indeed find here some agreement between the two columns, but
that is all that can be said.

Then the author says that differences in price are not as great as
formerly, on account of the development of international commerce. He
gives a table of comparative prices from 1870 to 1879 which shows that
five staples show no consistent movement in price. But during the same
period theft was continually on the increase. The number of male
delinquents from 18 to 50 alone varies with prices; the figures for
delinquents between 50 and 60 follow the course of prices but slightly.
Other economic crimes show little conformity.

The final conclusion of Fuld upon crimes against property is: “The
influence of the price of provisions upon these offenses is quite
important.” Although not giving my opinion upon the correctness of this
judgment at this time, I may say that the statistics furnished by Fuld
give almost no proof of it.

The following part treats of crimes against life. It is evident that we
are not concerned with crimes of passion. The only ones that enter into
consideration are those that have an economic object. But since
criminal statistics do not make this distinction, the results of the
author’s investigation can be but small. He is indeed convinced that
the influence of the price of provisions is very perceptible, but he
does not prove it. The same may be said with regard to sexual crimes.




XI.

B. WEISZ. [61]

“The wants that man must satisfy are numerous, but there is none which
makes itself felt so much as hunger. If he cannot satisfy his wants in
a lawful fashion, necessity drives him to other means.”

To prove what he says Dr. Weisz produces the following table:


France.

=======+=====================+================
Years. |Accusations of Crime.| Price of Wheat.
-------+---------------------+----------------
1845   |        5054         |      19.75
1846   |        5077         |      24.05
1847   |        5857         |      29.01
1848   |        4632         |      16.65
1849   |        4910         |      15.37
1850   |        5320         |      14.32
1851   |        5287         |      14.48
1852   |        5340         |      17.23
1853   |        5440         |      22.39
1854   |        5525         |      28.82
1855   |        4798         |      29.32
1856   |        4535         |      30.75
1857   |        4399         |      24.37
1858   |        4302         |      16.75
1859   |        3918         |      16.74
1860   |        3621         |      20.24
1861   |        3842         |      24.55
1862   |        3906         |      23.24
1863   |        3614         |      19.78
1864   |        3447         |      17.58
=======+=====================+================


With but seven exceptions criminality here follows prices. When the
figures for crimes against property are substituted for those for
general criminality in the table, the agreement becomes greater:


=======+=====================+================
1847   |        4537         |      29.01
1848   |        3020         |      16.65
1849   |        2895         |      15.37
1850   |        3174         |      14.32
1851   |        3126         |      14.48
1852   |        3327         |      17.23
1853   |        3519         |      22.39
1854   |        3761         |      28.82
1855   |        3133         |      29.32
1856   |        2766         |      30.75
1857   |        2689         |      24.37
1858   |        2315         |      16.75
1859   |        2019         |      16.74
1861   |        2146         |      24.55
1862   |        2144         |      23.24
1863   |        1941         |      19.78
1864   |        1744         |      17.58
=======+=====================+================


Belgium.

=======+========+============+================
Years. |Price of|  General   |Offenses against
       | Wheat. |Criminality.|   Property.
-------+--------+------------+----------------
1841   |  20.02 |    444     |      332
1842   |  22.17 |    468     |      361
1843   |  19.41 |    434     |      346
1844   |  17.75 |    455     |      336
1845   |  20.06 |    387     |      275
1846   |  24.53 |    616     |      498
1847   |  25.20 |    579     |      496
1848   |  17.37 |    529     |      427
1849   |  17.15 |    451     |      338
1850   |  16.15 |    270     |      168
1851   |  16.71 |    247     |      132
1852   |  20.16 |    290     |      140
1853   |  25.13 |    264     |      191
1854   |  31.48 |    336     |      238
1855   |  32.92 |    299     |      212
1856   |  30.73 |    332     |      268
1857   |  22.96 |    309     |      197
1858   |  23.55 |    278     |      167
1859   |  24.00 |    314     |      187
1860   |  31.15 |    254     |      161
=======+========+============+================


It is to be noted here that in the years 1850–1860 the penal law was
changed. The correlation is not constant but appears in many cases. The
years of the crisis, 1846–1847, are especially interesting.


            =======+=============
            Years. | Infanticide.
            -------+-------------
            1845   |      5
            1846   |     17
            1852   |      7
            1853   |     13
            1854   |     12
            1855   |     14
            =======+==============


England.

=======+===============+===================
Years. |Price of Wheat.|    Number of
       |               |Criminal Offenders.
-------+---------------+-------------------
 1816  |     78.6      |      9,091
 1817  |     96.11     |     13,932
 1846  |     54.8      |     20,072
 1847  |     69.9      |     22,451
 1852  |     40.9      |     24,443
 1853  |     53.3      |     27,187
 1854  |     72.5      |     27,760
 1855  |     74.8      |     31,309
 1856  |     69.2      |     29,591
 1857  |     56.4      |     26,542
 1858  |     44.2      |     24,303
=======+===============+===================


—The value of Dr. Weisz’s information would be greater if he had given
us the relation of the figures for criminality to those for
population.—




XII.

W. STARKE. [62]

The first chapter that interests us is Chapter V (“Die Umgestaltung des
Volkslebens, ihre Einwirkung auf die Kriminalität,” etc.) Sec. 3 (“die
Sorge für die nothwendigsten Lebensbedürfnisse und die
Lebensmittelpreise”).


[PLATE I. (STARKE)]


Just as the influence of the price of food makes itself felt in the
number of marriages and births, it is also visible in the figures for
criminality. So, when the temperature of the winter is very low (e.g.
1855, ’56, ’65, and ’71), since men have greater wants than ordinary,
criminality rises. Thefts of wood increase during these years, for
example. But it is in only one part of the year that the cold makes
itself felt, while the high price of food lasts the whole year. Hence
the latter has much more influence on criminality.


[PLATE II. (STARKE)]


In the first of the plates which the author gives (see Plates I–VI),
the effect of the rise in prices is distinctly seen in the period
1849–1855. The fall that follows is also accompanied by a diminution in
the number of crimes. When, at the close of 1858, the price of rye and
potatoes begins to rise again, criminality also increases, though not
so much. We do not see this agreement during the years 1861–1865. While
prices rise in 1866, criminality declines as a consequence of the war
with Austria, and of economic events.

The years 1870–1871, during which prices rose, show a fall in the
figures for crime, a second exception to the rule therefore, since
1866. At the close of 1875 criminality increased greatly, although
prices rose but little, and when, in 1877, prices begin to come down,
the curve for criminality goes on rising. As for the years 1870–1871,
the explanation is to be found in the war, which strengthened the
feeling of solidarity (as in a less degree in 1866). Further, the
development of manufacturing had already begun by the end of the war,
and the war itself withdrew from ordinary life many persons who,
without it, might have committed crime. The author mentions also the
great diminution of crime in France during these years.

We note, however, that the French statisticians (Lafargue, for example)
consider these years as of little importance in the study of
criminality, since the police and the courts were then much less active
than at ordinary times. The same causes may be supposed to have been
active in Prussia also, though in a less degree than in France.

At the close of the middle of this century manufacturing was but
slightly developed in Prussia. But after the war its development
assumed gigantic proportions. Wealth increased, but was not evenly
distributed, as the following table from the income tax returns shows:


============================================+==========+==============
                                            | Persons. | Percentage.
--------------------------------------------+----------+--------------
I.  Having an income of   1000   thalers    |   139,556|      1.2
II.   ,,   ,,   ,,   ,, 400-1000   ,,       |   643,628|      5.6
III.  ,,   ,,   ,,   ,,  140-400   ,,       | 4,207,163|     36.4
           Not liable to the income tax     |          |
IV. (Average income, 120 Th.)               | 6,582,066|     56.8
                                            +----------+--------------
           Total                            |11,572,413|    100

Total number of those having an income of 400 thalers or under, 93.2%.
======================================================================


Education (Men and Boys over 10).

==============================+===========+============
         Classes.             |  Persons. | Percentage.
------------------------------+-----------+------------
I.   Higher education         |    93,000 |     1.023
II.  Intermediate education   |   193,000 |     2.122
III. Elementary education     | 7,885,423 |    86.703
IV.  Illiterate               |   923,274 |    10.152
                              +-----------+----------
          Total               | 9,094,757 |   100.00
==============================+===========+============


There were 96% of the population, then, with no education or only an
elementary one.

Little by little manufacturing so forged ahead of agriculture that the
necessary food was no longer produced in the country. From this time
dates the importation of large quantities of grain.

The year 1873 saw the beginning of the terrible reaction that made
itself felt in all strata of the population. The number of marriages
diminished as well as the number of births, and criminality increased.
(See Plate I.)

At first the curves for theft and criminality in general run parallel
in their rising and falling. But with 1854 they begin to diverge, and
this divergence is especially plain from 1871 on. Consequently
something else must have had an influence upon criminality. And this
other thing, according to Starke, is the modification of the political
position of the people. According to him the participation of the mass
of the people in politics, made possible by the right of suffrage, has
been one of the causes of the increase of the number of crimes against
the authority of the state, as the socialistic movement has been a
second cause. [63]


[PLATE III. (STARKE)]


—Without doubt the participation of all classes in the political life
will lead to crimes, especially when in the strife of classes the
propertied class makes use of violent means. The assertion that the
socialistic movement causes many crimes has only a semblance of truth.
It is rather because of the manner in which the socialists are treated,
than because of their doctrine that they are driven to acts of
violence. For the socialists wish to attain their end by pacific and
legal, political and economic means, and it is only when they are
opposed by force that they are incited to the use of violent means.—


[PLATE IV. (STARKE)]


Starke finally draws the following conclusion as to the causes in the
movement in criminality: “Hardly ever in the short space of a
generation have so many mighty factors of different kinds influenced
the life of our people, as in the years from 1848 to 1878; a complete
metamorphosis of the courts and the police; so extraordinary an
increase in the numbers and density of the population that the soil
could no longer produce enough to feed such numbers; connected with
this a great development of manufacturing with repeated crises, brought
on by the high price of the necessaries of life, and by epidemics; the
development of intercourse and commerce world-wide in extent; bloody
wars, which, through the system of universal military service, disturb
the whole population of every class; a politico-economic crisis so
severe that there has been none like it hitherto; and in addition to
and at the same time with all these factors, the entrance of the people
into the exercise of political rights; and finally, dependent upon
these, a deep-seated socialistic agitation.

“All these factors have their part in the moulding of the life of the
people in good as well as bad directions and accordingly influence the
movement of criminality. In the first rank stand the effects upon the
physical life of the lack of warmth and nourishment. The great
significance of the coldness of the winter upon the increase and
decrease of the theft of wood has been noted. Much greater is the
effect of the anxiety about daily bread, which finds expression in the
movement of the price of provisions.... Parallel with the curve of
food-prices runs that of thefts and the movement of the latter is again
impressed upon the curve of crimes and misdemeanors in general.” [64]
Let us consider now some of the important kinds of crime.



OFFENSES AND CONTRAVENTIONS AGAINST PROPERTY.

“It is egoism which chiefly governs man, shows itself positively in the
desire to acquire as much as possible, and negatively in the desire to
lose as little as possible, and which reduces activity to
insatiability, and economy to avarice.” [65] Now, cupidity leads to
most of the crimes against property, while hatred, vengeance, etc.
drive men to malicious mischief.

Examining now Plates II and III, the influence of the years of high
prices (1856 and 1867), of the years of war (1866 and 1870–1871), and
of the years of crisis shows itself very plainly. It is to be noted
that the curve of crimes of “malicious mischief” takes a course totally
different from that of crimes against property committed from other
motives. Plate III shows the great influence of economic events upon
fraudulent bankruptcies (1857 and 1873 having been years of crisis).



OFFENSES AGAINST PERSONS.

We see that the curves of these crimes shown upon Plates IV and V have
a course quite different from that of the curves of the crimes against
property. It is only in 1870 that both fall together. Starke deduces
the rule, confirmed by many statisticians, that an improvement in
economic conditions is accompanied by an increase in assaults, etc.,
and vice versa. The facts confirm this rule during the first part of
the period that Starke has studied, but not later. (Compare Plates I
and IV.)

In studying the curve of infanticide we note that it reaches the
highest point in the bad years, 1857, 1863, 1866, 1867 (Eastern
Prussia), and 1868. In 1857 the first commercial crisis took place, and
in 1864 and 1866 the cholera raged and war was declared; a number of
fathers of illegitimate children died, leaving the mothers unable to
support the children.

A comparison between the curve of crimes of arson, with those of the
crimes against property in Plate III, committed with the same end,
shows a great resemblance; the increase in this crime also shows itself
in bad years.




XIII.

RETTICH. [66]

The part of this author’s work dealing with crimes and misdemeanors
against property contains some observations which are of importance for
our subject.


[PLATE V. (STARKE)]


I cannot show the views of the author better than by quoting the
following: “That the number of offenses against property must be
related to the prevailing economic conditions, seems to need no proof.
For the man who lives in the possession of abundance, the motive for
appropriating the property of others is lacking, even though the
inclination to commit all possible crimes slumbers within him. It is a
favorite expression of the Social-democrats, that the abolition of
private property would cause all crimes against property to disappear.
They forget, while maintaining this, the probability that just as
earlier private individuals were robbed, so under the new order the
state would be, by people of the same kind—those who today, without
living in want, still are not content with their lawful gains, and
reach out after unlawful ones. The apostles of state-ownership, in
order to make their contention credible, must at least offer proof that
the offenses against property which are now punished, are entirely due
to hunger and need on the part of those convicted. They cannot however,
offer such proof. This is not because the government statistics ...
give no data with regard to the economic condition of the convicts, but
because, as a matter of fact, the worst offenses against property are
not committed by the hungry. The merchant who goes into a fraudulent
bankruptcy, the banker who embezzles deposits, the worldling who forges
drafts, have all taken the step into crime from a life, if not of
abundance, at least of a competence. People of this kind will not
disappear from the socialistic state. In their case the lack is not in
the social system, but in their individual make-up.” [67]


[PLATE VI. (STARKE)]


—We have given this quotation simply to furnish a typical example of
the incorrect way in which many authors represent the socialistic
opinion with regard to the genesis of crime. What nonsense, to assert
that according to the theory of socialism all crimes against property
find their causes in hunger and misery! See the second part of this
work, where the reader will find that socialists hold an entirely
different opinion, and that they have facts to prove the truth of their
theories.—

With regard to the relation between the movement of the price of
certain important cereals and a great part of the crime against
property, the author gives the following table:


========+=========================================+================
        | Average Price Per 200 Kilogr. in Marks. |   Arrests for
 Years. |-------------+--------------+------------+     Theft to
        |    Wheat.   |    Grain.    |     Rye.   | 10,000 Persons.
--------+-------------+--------------+------------+----------------
1882    |    22.57    |    23.63     |    18.81   |      26.0
1883    |    19.04    |    19.29     |    16.30   |      25.2
1884    |    18.44    |    18.75     |    17.17   |      22.7
1885    |    17.92    |    18.11     |    16.17   |      21.5
1886    |    17.68    |    17.94     |    14.69   |      20.7
1887    |    18.88    |    18.95     |    15.26   |      20.5
1888    |    20.23    |    20.64     |    16.19   |      20.3
1889    |    20.03    |    20.52     |    16.50   |      21.4
1890    |    21.43    |    21.71     |    17.97   |      21.2
1891    |    22.48    |    22.92     |    19.26   |      19.3
========+=============+==============+============+================


There is at first a certain correlation between the figures in the
different columns, but there is none in the later years. It is very
probable that the diminution in crimes against property is due, during
these years, to a combination of favorable economic circumstances at
that time.




XIV.

A. MEYER.

The second section of the second chapter of the work, “Die Verbrechen
in ihrem Zusammenhang mit dem wirtschaftlichen und sozialen
Verhältnissen im Kanton Zürich”, [68] treats of the influence of the
price of provisions and crop-returns (see Plate I).

The author first calls attention to the years 1853–1861. We see that
the curves of the price of cereals and of offenses against property are
then quite closely parallel. However, the curve of the price of cereals
was lowest in 1858, and that of offenses in 1859. It is a well-known
fact that economic phenomena make their influence upon criminality felt
only after some time. Further, it is only by the following year that a
part of the offenses are counted in the criminal statistics. Crimes
against persons increase when prices fall, and vice versa. The less the
price of food is influenced by bad industrial conditions, the more its
influence upon criminality will strike the eye.

The section following is entitled: “Schuldbetreibungs- und
Konkurs-statistik als Ausdruck der wirtschaftlichen Lage der
Bevölkerung und Kriminalität.” When we examine Plate II for the period
1832–1852, we see that the curves of bankruptcy and of offenses against
property are parallel. From Plate III (1852–1892) we note that offenses
against property are influenced by failures as well as by the price of
grain. At times the two forces act in the same direction and reënforce
one another, and at times their direction is opposite, and they more or
less neutralize each other. It must be remarked that in 1867 an
epidemic of cholera raged in the canton, and that the relief fund which
was then given out kept the figure for criminality below what the
economic situation would have produced.


[PLATE I (MEYER)]


Dr. Meyer’s conclusion from what has been said is this: “The result of
the researches proves that in the course of years the number of crimes
against property is strictly bound up with material conditions; the
greater the difficulty of getting a living, the more numerous the
crimes against property. The statistics of crimes against property show
at the same time the degrees of the prosperity of the country, as the
statistics of failures, for example, prove.” [69]


[PLATE II (MEYER)]


Plate IV gives a comparison of crimes against persons with economic
conditions, and shows that these crimes increase when economic
conditions improve, and that vintages more or less abundant are not
without importance.

On page 44, the author commences his examination of the criminality in
the different districts of the canton of Zürich, investigating its
distribution, both as to where the crimes are committed, and where the
criminals come from.

According to the first distribution the districts of Zürich, of
Dielsdorf, and of Horgen have the highest figures; those of Hinweill,
of Meilen, and of Pfäffikon the lowest. According to the second
distribution it is again the districts of Dielsdorf and of Horgen that
have the highest figures, while Hinweill, Meilen, and Pfäffikon take
the last place here also. Zürich and Winterthür, which in the first
distribution held the first place, in the second have the eighth and
tenth. We see from this that, however great the number of crimes the
last two districts produce, the authors of the crimes are outsiders.

Dr. Meyer then compares the districts of Hinweill and Pfäffikon, which
have the lowest figures, with the districts of Horgen and Dielsdorf,
which have the highest. He concludes that the two former districts are
the poorest, and the two latter the most well-to-do, a conclusion which
he bases upon different facts, among others upon the appropriations
which the public charities of the different districts receive from the
state. And according to him it follows that in this case the connection
between criminality and economic conditions is not direct.

The author then explains the indirect connection as follows: “In
Hinweill as in Pfäffikon, there exists a general impoverishment, caused
by the unfavorable state of the soil and of the population, heavy
mortgages, bad cultivation by the small farmers, the diminution of
industry, the lack of education, etc,—an impoverishment that threatens
the ruin of entire communities.” [70] Then, an increase of crime is not
to be feared in countries where poverty strikes the whole population,
for the thief has nothing to steal. Since in the well-to-do districts
the differences of possessions are more marked, the opportunity for
wrong-doing is greater, and it is this which makes criminality greater
also.

The conclusion of Dr. Meyer upon what has gone before is this:
“Criminality is an historical product, and economic conditions are only
one, though a significant, factor. Under like economic conditions ...
the number of crimes against property need not necessarily be like. It
depends upon how the population has accommodated itself to the economic
situation, whether it makes higher or lower demands upon life, what
views it holds as to the end of human existence, etc.” [71]

As to the occupations of those convicted the data of Dr. Meyer are
incomplete. The conclusion drawn from them is that the agricultural
population is less criminal than the industrial proletariat. Here is
the reason, according to Dr. Meyer: “An explanation of this phenomena
that agrees fully with our investigations has already been given by von
Valentini when he says: ‘Small holdings make direct and exhausting
demands upon the labor of the whole family, while, on the other hand,
they provide sufficiently for the immediate and indispensable needs of
the household, so that idleness as well as anxiety about sustenance are
generally both excluded from such a family.’” [72]

“It is otherwise in manufacturing. The greater independence of the
industrial worker, his receiving his wages in money exclusively, the
dependence of industry upon the conjunctures of the market, give
instead of the stability of existence, enjoyed by agriculture, a life
fluctuating and insecure. Abundance as well as want visits industrial
workers, and each of the two begets in him a corresponding kind of
crime.” [73]

—The expression “abundance” as describing the state in which the
proletariat live, is a strange one. A man who is not indigent and has a
few sous does not on that account live in abundance. The author adds a
quotation from Garofalo to point out how the proletariat spend a great
part of their “abundance” in the wine-shops. The reader is, however,
referred to Part II of this work, where I have pointed out the social
and economic causes of alcoholism.—

Dr. Meyer concludes his work by saying that he does not believe that an
improvement of economic conditions will inevitably lead to an increase
of crimes against persons, but that the causes of them are rather to be
found in frivolity, grossness, and dissipation consequent upon an
improvement of conditions.


[PLATE III. (MEYER)]


But—youth does not possess wisdom! It is only by advancing in age that
rash, rough youth becomes wise and gentle. Now, in the same way society
will lose, one by one, the faults of its youth!


[PLATE IV. (MEYER)]




XV.

M. TUGAN-BARANOWSKY.

“Die sozialen Wirkungen der Handelskrisen in England”, [74] by this
author, aims to prove that the commercial crises in England in the
years 1823–1850 had a much more violent character than those of the
years 1871–1896, which occurred less suddenly, and made themselves felt
for a long time afterwards. Since criminality is one of the social
phenomena pointed out as caused by these crises, it is worth while
giving a résumé of the work in question.

Dr. Tugan-Baranowsky has examined the influence that commercial crises
have exercised, first, upon the agricultural counties, Cambridge,
Essex, Norfolk, Oxford, Lincoln, Suffolk and Wilts (Diagrams 1 and 4);
second, upon the industrial counties of Lancaster and Chester (Diagrams
2 and 5); third, upon all England (Diagrams 3 and 6).

Let us study the first three diagrams. The first shows that the
commercial crisis of 1825 had a very slight effect upon criminality. It
was the high price of grain in 1829 that made crime increase. The same
effect was produced by the famous law of 1834 (by which not only was
the aid given to poor working people very much limited, but which
prescribed the placing in work-houses of those who were without means
of support) and by the crisis of 1836. In 1844–1845, years of good
harvests, criminality declined, after which the bad crops of 1847
brought about a contrary effect.

We note from Diagrams 2 and 3 that the effect of commercial crises was
much greater in the manufacturing than in the agricultural counties
(more plainly seen in 2 than in 3). The crisis of 1825 made the curve
of criminality rise considerably; the favorable years 1833–1836 made it
descend from 1834 on; while the crisis of 1836 caused a considerable
increase in the number of crimes in 1837. The bad years 1840–1843
caused a formidable increase in the criminal population, which must
also be attributed, at least in part, to the Chartist movement. The
favorable period that followed had the contrary effect. It is
interesting to compare the curves (in Diagram 3) of exports and crime,
which cross continually.

Let us consider now the last three diagrams. Dr. Tugan-Baranowsky
attributes the descent of the curve of criminality in Diagram 4 to the
improved condition of the agricultural population. Further, the number
of crimes was greatly diminished by the alteration in the criminal
procedure in 1879, and it goes without saying that this influence must
also be taken into account in studying the last two diagrams. By
Diagrams 5 and 6 we see that the influence of criminality is much less
marked. Thus, for example, the diminution of criminality was not
prevented by the crisis at the beginning of the period 1890–1896.

The final conclusion of Dr. Tugan-Baranowsky is this: “The first three
diagrams give a picture of the life of the English people in the second
quarter of this century [the nineteenth]. We see abrupt periodical
changes of important phenomena in the life of the people, which are
plainly connected with the changes in the industrial situation.
Especially sudden are the variations in the life of the industrial
population. Each crisis has a devastating effect upon the ranks of the
working-classes, the workhouses are swamped with the unemployed, the
prisons fill up as well, mortality mounts enormously, the mass of
people out of work readily take up with any political agitation, and
the years of crisis are likewise years of revolutionary movements.

“At the same time the manufacturing and commerce of the country
increase rapidly. The enormous growth of exportation in England, the
curve of which mounts continually, is in sharp contrast with the
deterioration of the living-conditions of the working-class.

“The last three diagrams show us an entirely different picture. English
exports no longer increase. In place of a steady rise of the curve with
a sharp depression in the critical years, there are regular, wave-like
variations in the same plane. The industrial development of the country
proceeds at a slackening pace.

“And at the same time in the life of the people there are signs to be
noticed of increasing well-being. Mortality, criminality, and pauperism
fall quickly. Crises no longer have their former influence upon the
condition of the people. Even in manufacturing districts business
stagnation no longer has its former disastrous effect upon the
working-class; crime and the death-rate no longer increase, and even
the increase in the number of paupers is hardly noticeable. Organized
labor supports even the unemployed. Wages are only a little lower in
years of industrial depression than they are in a time of prosperity!”


[DIAGRAM No. 1. (TUGAN-BARANOWSKY)]

[DIAGRAM No. 2. (TUGAN-BARANOWSKY)]

[DIAGRAM No. 3. (TUGAN-BARANOWSKY)]

[DIAGRAM No. 4. (TUGAN-BARANOWSKY)]

[DIAGRAM No. 5. (TUGAN-BARANOWSKY)]

[DIAGRAM No. 6. (TUGAN-BARANOWSKY)]




XVI.

E. TARNOWSKY. [75]

At the end of his study the author gives the following table, which
contains some data upon the relation between the price of grain and
abundance of the crops, on the one hand, and criminality on the other.
The figures in the second column have to do with the different kinds of
theft. The law of May 18th, 1882, having considerably modified the
penal code, the figures for the years 1882 and 1883 cannot be compared
with those of preceding years. This is why they have been suppressed.


================+================+==============+===================
                |  New Cases to  |  Price of a  |  Ratio of Cereal
Years.          | 100,000 of the | “Pud” of Rye | Crop to Average of
                |  Population.   | in Kopecks.  |  25 Years (= 100).
----------------+----------------+--------------+-------------------
1874            |       76       |      75      |        105
1875            |       77       |      73      |         90
1876            |       78       |      76      |         95
1877            |       86       |      80      |        103
1878            |       95       |      76      |        106
1879            |       90       |      86      |         93
1880            |      104       |      99      |         87
1881            |      103       |     129      |        105
average 1874-81 |       89       |      87      |         --
1884            |       45       |      90      |        108
1885            |       46       |      77      |         90
1886            |       44       |      74      |        100
1887            |       45       |      67      |        114
1888            |       43       |      65      |        108
1889            |       43       |      70      |         83
1890            |       46       |      68      |         97
1891            |       52       |     129      |         73
1892            |       52       |      89      |         87
1893            |       50       |      61      |        104
1894            |       50       |      50      |        121
average 1884-94 |       47       |      76      |         --
================+================+==============+===================


According to the author it may be doubted whether the years of poor
harvests could cause an increase in the number of thefts in Russia. For
the agricultural population is benefited by the high price of grain.
However, it is proved by the figures given above that these years have
an unfavorable effect upon criminality, which can be understood if we
take into account the fact that most of the Russian peasants only raise
grain for their own consumption, and that bad crops accordingly affect
them seriously.




XVII.

H. MÜLLER.

In the introduction to his work, “Untersuchungen über die Bewegung der
Criminalität in ihrem Zusammenhang mit dem wirtschaftlichen
Verhältnissen”, Dr. Müller describes the result of his researches as
follows: “In the course of our discussion it will appear that with time
the state of industry, the greater or less chance to get work, the
activity or depression of the general economic life, have gradually
become of far more significance for the increase or decrease of crime,
than a rise or fall in the price of provisions, and that at present
these factors have reduced the economic meaning of the price of
provisions to a minimum.” [76]

The period examined (1854–1895) is divided into two parts, because the
criminal statistics of the empire, which are to be had from 1882 on,
give the number of crimes and criminals, while the Prussian statistics
give the number of new cases brought before the examining magistrate.

The figures for these years are as follows:


Prussia, 1854–1878. New Cases to 100,000 of the Population.

======+=================+================+==================
      |                 |                |Against the State,
Years.|Against Property.|Against Persons.|Public Order, and
      |                 |                |     Religion.
------+-----------------+----------------+------------------
1854  |      416        |       78       |        --
1855  |      436        |       78       |        41
1856  |      472        |       81       |        47
1857  |      324        |       95       |        55
1858  |      288        |      103       |        54
1859  |      295        |      103       |        51
1860  |      310        |      102       |        56
1861  |      314        |       93       |        52
1862  |      313        |      105       |        54
1863  |      288        |      111       |        53
1864  |      290        |      115       |        56
1865  |      325        |      121       |        58
1866  |      314        |      109       |        55
1867  |      360        |      112       |        51
1868  |      392        |      117       |        52
1869  |      338        |      126       |        53
1870  |      296        |       99       |        46
1871  |      254        |       75       |        41
1872  |      281        |       94       |        56
1873  |      266        |      106       |        64
1874  |      295        |      125       |        81
1875  |      284        |      135       |        84
1876  |      315        |      142       |        89
1877  |      341        |      160       |        87
1878  |      370        |      164       |       103
======+=================+================+===================


Prussia, 1882–1895. Persons Convicted to 100,000 Inhabitants
over 12 Years.

========+=================+================+==================
        |                 |                |Against the State,
 Years. |Against Property.|Against Persons.|Public Order, and
        |                 |                |     Religion.
--------+-----------------+----------------+------------------
  1882  |      545        |      328       |       180
  1883  |      520        |      343       |       174
  1884  |      527        |      382       |       188
  1885  |      492        |      385       |       185
  1886  |      488        |      402       |       196
  1887  |      475        |      421       |       203
  1888  |      466        |      404       |       200
  1889  |      503        |      423       |       197
  1890  |      496        |      449       |       199
  1891  |      520        |      443       |       190
  1892  |      575        |      458       |       199
1882-91 |      510        |      404       |       194
  1894  |      528        |      527       |       219
========+=================+================+==================


Now, the causes that make crime increase when there is an economic
depression are, according to the author, the following: “The instinct
of self-preservation, which in its harmonious development is the motive
for the lawful and moral struggle of men for existence, and in more
restricted form is the principal ground for industrial activity, in its
degeneration ... demands a certain, often high, percentage of victims,
who fall into crime, especially theft, fraud, embezzlement, and other
offenses against property. And experience shows that the greater the
care to maintain existence, or often simply to procure daily bread, the
greater is the number of offenses against property. When need appears,
at the same time comes the instinct impelling a man to seize the
property of another, better situated than himself. Infractions of
property are in part to be ascribed to other motives. There is nothing
to show, however, that these motives (greed and covetousness, for
example) are stronger in one year and weaker in another throughout a
whole people. We must rather ascribe to them a certain uniformity in
their influence upon criminal activity. The determining factor in the
increase and decrease of crimes remains the general well-being of a
people, in earlier times the price of the necessities of life, at the
present the opportunity for employment.” [77]

Let us study in the first place crimes and misdemeanors against
property:


I. Offenses, against Property.

Prussia, 1854–1878. New Cases to 100,000 of the Population.

=======+========+===============+============+=============+==========+==========+===========
       |        |               |  Robbery   |  Receiving  |          |          |
Years. | Theft. | Embezzlement. |    and     |   Stolen    | Perjury, | Forgery. | Malicious
       |        |               | Blackmail. | Goods, Etc. |   Etc.   |          | Mischief.
-------+--------+---------------+------------+-------------+----------+----------+-----------
 1854  |  334   |      28       |     1.0    |      40     |    17    |   5.4    |    10
 1855  |  354   |      29       |     1.1    |      34     |    16    |   5.7    |     8
 1856  |  386   |      31       |     1.1    |      43     |    17    |   6.0    |     8
 1857  |  246   |      23       |     1.0    |      38     |    15    |   7.0    |    10
 1858  |  213   |      22       |     0.8    |      30     |    12    |   7.3    |    11
 1859  |  219   |      22       |     0.8    |      25     |    12    |   7.5    |    12
 1860  |  229   |      24       |     0.8    |      30     |    13    |   7.7    |    12
 1861  |  232   |      24       |     0.8    |      26     |    13    |   8.1    |    12
 1862  |  229   |      24       |     0.9    |      25     |    13    |   8.2    |    14
 1863  |  206   |      23       |     0.8    |      21     |    14    |   7.5    |    15
 1864  |  206   |      24       |     1.0    |      25     |    13    |   7.4    |    17
 1865  |  227   |      24       |     0.8    |      25     |    14    |   7.6    |    17
 1866  |  222   |      23       |     0.8    |      24     |    14    |   7.2    |    17
 1867  |  265   |      25       |     0.9    |      32     |    15    |   8.1    |    17
 1868  |  293   |      27       |     1.2    |      36     |    16    |   8.0    |    17
 1869  |  241   |      25       |     1.0    |      30     |    15    |   7.1    |    18
 1870  |  211   |      22       |     0.9    |      27     |    14    |   6.4    |    17
 1871  |  190   |      18       |     0.8    |      33     |    10    |   3.2    |    14
 1872  |  209   |      20       |     1.4    |      46     |    11    |   3.4    |    17
 1873  |  196   |      19       |     1.4    |      46     |    11    |   3.5    |    18
 1874  |  216   |      22       |     1.7    |      50     |    13    |   3.7    |    19
 1875  |  209   |      23       |     1.7    |      49     |    13    |   4.2    |    19
 1876  |  223   |      25       |     1.9    |      50     |    16    |   4.9    |    21
 1877  |  238   |      28       |     2.4    |      51     |    18    |   5.5    |    22
 1878  |  257   |      30       |     2.4    |      55     |    20    |   5.6    |    24
=======+========+===============+============+=============+==========+==========+===========


Prussia, 1882–1896. Persons Convicted to 100,000 Inhabitants over 12 Years.

=======+========+===============+============+=============+==========+==========+===========
       |        |               |  Robbery   |  Receiving  |          |          |
Years. | Theft. | Embezzlement. |    and     |   Stolen    | Perjury, | Forgery. | Malicious
       |        |               | Blackmail. | Goods, Etc. |   Etc.   |          | Mischief.
-------+--------+---------------+------------+-------------+----------+----------+-----------
 1882  |  337   |      44       |     1.5    |      30     |    29    |    8.0   |    38
 1883  |  323   |      42       |     1.4    |      27     |    29    |    7.7   |    37
 1884  |  322   |      44       |     1.7    |      27     |    31    |    8.4   |    41
 1885  |  289   |      44       |     1.4    |      25     |    30    |    8.0   |    41
 1886  |  282   |      43       |     1.5    |      24     |    32    |    8.3   |    41
 1887  |  267   |      42       |     1.4    |      24     |    35    |    8.6   |    43
 1888  |  262   |      43       |     1.2    |      23     |    36    |    8.6   |    38
 1889  |  289   |      46       |     1.4    |      25     |    41    |   10.0   |    40
 1890  |  278   |      46       |     1.5    |      25     |    41    |   10.0   |    42
 1891  |  292   |      47       |     1.6    |      25     |    44    |   10.9   |    41
 1892  |  329   |      52       |     1.6    |      30     |    48    |   11.7   |    42
 1893  |  298   |      45       |     1.5    |      26     |    36    |    9.0   |    41
 1894  |  276   |      51       |     1.4    |      25     |    51    |   12.9   |    47
 1895  |  271   |      53       |     --     |      24     |    52    |   13.2   |    --
 1896  |  259   |      50       |     --     |      22     |    50    |   12.8   |    --
=======+========+===============+============+=============+==========+==========+===========


The following table gives the prices of certain important foods (per 50
Kilogr.):

         =========+===========+===========+==========
         Years.   |   Wheat.  |    Rye.   | Potatoes.
         ---------+-----------+-----------+----------
          1848    |    7.49   |    4.82   |   1.84
          1849    |    7.29   |    3.87   |   1.45
          1850    |    6.91   |    4.55   |   1.55
          1851    |    7.47   |    6.26   |   2.08
          1852    |    8.59   |    7.72   |   2.48
          1853    |   10.25   |    8.50   |   2.47
          1854    |   12.90   |   10.40   |   3.17
          1855    |   14.21   |   11.45   |   3.37
          1856    |   13.51   |   10.64   |   3.13
          1857    |   10.18   |    6.87   |   2.18
          1858    |    9.08   |    6.38   |   1.91
          1859    |    8.93   |    6.79   |   1.98
          1860    |   10.48   |    7.65   |   2.41
          1861    |   11.04   |    7.71   |   2.79
          1862    |   10.68   |    7.79   |   2.47
          1863    |    9.18   |    6.78   |   2.04
          1864    |    7.95   |    5.69   |   2.10
          1865    |    8.13   |    6.24   |   2.03
          1866    |    9.80   |    7.30   |   2.05
          1867    |   12.89   |    9.87   |   2.95
          1868    |   12.48   |    9.84   |   2.62
          1869    |    9.70   |    8.08   |   2.16
          1870    |   10.14   |    7.78   |   2.58
          1871    |   11.70   |    8.60   |   3.05
          1872    |   12.10   |    8.40   |   2.95
          1873    |   13.20   |    9.60   |   3.00
          1874    |   12.00   |    9.90   |   3.35
          1875    |    9.80   |    8.60   |   2.75
          1876    |   10.50   |    8.70   |   2.82
          1877    |   11.50   |    8.85   |   3.18
          1878    |   10.10   |    7.15   |   2.82
          1879    |    9.80   |    7.20   |   3.08
          1880    |   10.95   |    9.65   |   3.25
          1881    |   11.00   |   10.10   |   2.85
         =========+===========+===========+==========


A comparison of these figures with those of crime will show that the
crimes against property increase in the years of high prices up to
1855. In 1857 prices fell and crime decreased.



In the figures for foreign countries we see this relation much less
clearly. Dr. Weisz has indeed succeeded in establishing a similar
relation in France, but in Belgium it is much slighter. In England it
is not possible to show that there is any parallelism between the
curves of criminality and of the price of grain. In the years 1831–1840
and 1841–1850 the curve of crime even goes down, while provisions were
then very dear. There must therefore be some other cause, and this is
probably that England had a great industrial development long before
any other country.

After an extremely rapid development up to 1847, manufacturing had to
pass through a formidable crisis. While the average annual number of
persons convicted in England and Wales was 20,455, and this figure fell
to 18,100 and 17,400 in the prosperous years, 1845–1846, it rose during
the years of crisis, 1847–1848, to 21,500 and 22,900, falling again to
21,000 in 1849, when business had resumed its normal course.

In the years following, industry received an enormous impetus, in
consequence of the discovery of gold in California, the repeal of the
Corn Laws, and many other causes. In 1857 came the panic, which
affected all industrial countries, especially England. In 1856–1860
there was an annual average of 13,565 convictions; in 1857 it was
15,307, an increase of 12%. That the consequences of this crisis are
not to be observed in the figures for crime in Prussia, is to be
attributed to the fact that in that country manufacturing was little
developed.

After the very dear years 1852–1856 the price of grain remained fairly
constant in Prussia. It was only in 1860–1862 that it rose a little and
caused an increase in the cases of fraud and theft. 1867–1868 were
years which were marked by an extraordinarily high price for grain,
which had some influence upon crime, without equalling that of such
years as 1852–1856.

Crime decreased in the years of war, 1866 and 1870–1871, due as Dr.
Müller thinks, to two facts; first, that a great part of the population
capable of committing crimes were then out of the country; and second,
that the feeling of solidarity is stronger in time of war.

Notwithstanding the rise in the price of grain in 1871–1874, crime
decreased greatly after the war of 1870. A modification of the penal
law could not be the cause of it; its origin was deeper. Since 1871
Germany has seen its industries develop prodigiously. The period of
prosperity was of short duration, for in the summer of 1873 came the
crisis, which lasted till 1878. Now it is during these years that the
crimes against property were much increased.

When we study this period in other countries, in Austria and England,
for example, we see a great industrial development, accompanied by a
decrease in crime. The average number of criminals in Austria for the
years 1860–1870 was 32,800, and 26,900 for the years 1871–1875. In
England the figures for the same period were 14,100 and 11,200
respectively. France alone was an exception, for in this country
manufacturing did not begin to develop immediately after the war. [78]
But in Austria and England the effects of the crisis upon crime were
felt just as in Prussia. In Austria, for example, criminality increased
10%. From 1878 on, business improved in Prussia and in other countries
also, and little by little the number of crimes against property
decreased (between 1885 and 1890 7% in France, 9% in Austria, and 20%
in England).

In 1889 there was another great disturbance in the economic field,
which was prolonged till 1892. During these years there was a new
increase of crime; in Austria, for example, the average number of
convictions was 29,483 in 1890–1894, as against 28,834 for the five
years preceding. In England we see the same phenomenon, and in Prussia
as well.

Dr. Müller calls attention to the marked fall in the price of grain in
1892, and sees in it a proof that prices have no longer any great
influence. Since 1892 there has been a new period of prosperity, and at
the same time a constant diminution of crimes against property.

Dr. Müller reminds us that preceding moralistic statisticians have
brought out the fact that crimes against persons increase when the
price of grain falls, and vice versa, as is distinctly seen in the
tables for the years 1854–1860. But there is a change during the ten
years following. In 1867–1868 the price of grain was high, but crimes
against persons and the public order rose also. Crimes against persons
decreased in the years of war, 1866 and 1870, just as crimes against
property did. Since 1871 crimes against persons have in general
diminished, principally because of favorable economic conditions. (The
diminution of crimes against morals is chiefly due to a modification of
the law, which prescribed that a case could not be prosecuted except
upon complaint. The increase after 1876 was caused by a revocation of
this requirement.) The crimes in question increased anew considerably
after the crisis of 1874. Here is an important exception, then, to the
rule that the earlier statisticians laid down, namely that crimes
against persons decrease when economic conditions grow worse.



II. Crimes against Persons.

a. 1854–1878. New Cases to 100,000 Inhabitants.

=======+==========+=========+===========+==========+===========+==========
       | Offenses |         |  Murder   | Assault  |  Bodily   | Offenses
Years. | against  | Insult. |    and    |    in    | Injuries  | against
       | Morals.  |         | Homicide. | General. | Punished  | Personal
       |          |         |           |          | as Crime. | Liberty.
-------+----------+---------+-----------+----------+-----------+----------
 1854  |    8.7   |   32    |    1.1    |    34    |    6.7    |   0.9
 1855  |   10.2   |   32    |    0.9    |    32    |    4.5    |   0.7
 1856  |   10.8   |   34    |    0.9    |    37    |    3.0    |   0.8
 1857  |   12.6   |   36    |    0.9    |    42    |    1.8    |   1.0
 1858  |   12.5   |   40    |    0.8    |    46    |    1.8    |   1.1
 1859  |   13.1   |   39    |    0.8    |    47    |    1.8    |   1.0
 1860  |   12.4   |   40    |    0.9    |    46    |    1.5    |   0.8
 1861  |   11.6   |   33    |    0.7    |    44    |    1.7    |   1.0
 1862  |   12.9   |   39    |    0.8    |    49    |    1.4    |   1.4
 1863  |   14.2   |   40    |    0.7    |    53    |    1.6    |   1.2
 1864  |   14.0   |   43    |    0.9    |    54    |    1.6    |   1.4
 1865  |   14.9   |   44    |    0.8    |    58    |    1.7    |   1.3
 1866  |   13.4   |   40    |    0.8    |    50    |    1.5    |   1.3
 1867  |   14.0   |   44    |    0.9    |    50    |    1.6    |   1.0
 1868  |   14.8   |   47    |    0.9    |    52    |    2.8    |   1.0
 1869  |   14.9   |   45    |    1.0    |    58    |    2.8    |   1.3
 1870  |   12.3   |   39    |    0.8    |    49    |    1.9    |   1.1
 1871  |    5.3   |   26    |    0.7    |    39    |    1.2    |   1.2
 1872  |    6.2   |   34    |    0.8    |    50    |    2.0    |   1.8
 1873  |    6.7   |   38    |    0.9    |    56    |    2.4    |   2.8
 1874  |    7.8   |   47    |    1.1    |    64    |    3.0    |   3.3
 1875  |    8.2   |   50    |    1.2    |    65    |    2.9    |   3.6
 1876  |    9.3   |   51    |    1.2    |    73    |    5.5    |   4.1
 1877  |   11.1   |   54    |    1.3    |    86    |    5.0    |   4.7
 1878  |   12.3   |   54    |    1.4    |    89    |    2.5    |   5.5
=======+==========+=========+===========+==========+===========+==========


b. 1882–1895. Persons Convicted to 100,000 Inhabitants over 12 Years.

========+==========+=========+===========+==========+===========+==========
        | Offenses |         |  Murder   | Assault  |  Bodily   | Offenses
 Years. | against  | Insult. |    and    |    in    | Injuries  | against
        | Morals.  |         | Homicide. | General. | Punished  | Personal
        |          |         |           |          | as Crime. | Liberty.
--------+----------+---------+-----------+----------+-----------+----------
  1882  |    7.8   |   117   |    1.0    |    60    |    111    |    10
  1883  |    7.6   |   119   |    1.0    |    63    |    121    |    11
  1884  |    7.6   |   127   |    0.8    |    68    |    142    |    15
  1885  |    7.6   |   119   |    0.9    |    65    |    151    |    17
  1886  |    8.9   |   124   |    0.8    |    68    |    153    |    19
  1887  |    8.8   |   133   |    0.8    |    68    |    163    |    19
  1888  |    9.1   |   130   |    0.6    |    64    |    156    |    18
  1889  |    8.4   |   131   |    0.6    |    68    |    166    |    21
  1890  |    8.8   |   138   |    0.6    |    74    |    175    |    23
  1891  |    8.5   |   133   |    0.6    |    74    |    173    |    24
  1892  |    9.0   |   137   |    0.9    |    76    |    177    |    26
1882-91 |    8.3   |   129   |    0.8    |    68    |    153    |    18
  1894  |   10.5   |   156   |    0.7    |    87    |    208    |    29
  1895  |   10.9   |   161   |    0.7    |    --    |    220    |    --
  1896  |   11.1   |   158   |    0.6    |    --    |    220    |    --
========+==========+=========+===========+==========+===========+==========


“The great economic crisis beginning in 1873 was accompanied by the
characteristic phenomenon that dissatisfaction with the existing
economic, social, and political conditions affected wider circles than
heretofore, that this embittered people’s minds, and brought about
sharp oppositions and struggles of the industrial classes against each
other, especially the struggle of labor against capital. The need of an
economic reform was more and more felt, which is to be attained, in the
opinion of the powerful, by force, and in that of the thoughtful, by
social legislation. All public life since the seventies has been
dominated by this idea.” [79]

Here also economic conditions are causes of crime, and show themselves
principally in resistance to officials, etc. The tables show also an
increase in the cases of perjury, bodily injuries, and other crimes
that are the consequences of grossness. The increase is due, according
to Dr. Müller, to bad economic conditions. For as a consequence of
these the number of civil cases rose from 60,000 (the average for
1871–1873) to 120,000 and 135,000 (1876–1877) and it is by these cases
that perjury becomes possible. It is necessary to attribute to the same
causes the great increase in the number of cases of crimes against
personal liberty (also, since 1876, to the abolition of the requirement
of a complaint for prosecution).



III. Crimes against the Public Order.

a. 1854–1878. New Cases.

========+============+===============+==========+=================+==============
        |            |   Offenses    |          |                 |
 Years. | Rebellion. |    against    | Perjury. | Counterfeiting. | Leze-majesty.
        |            | Public Order. |          |                 |
--------+------------+---------------+----------+-----------------+--------------
 1854   |    18.6    |      --       |   3.0    |      0.83       |    0.63
 1855   |    18.2    |     16.7      |   2.6    |      0.64       |    0.71
 1856   |    18.0    |     23.2      |   2.7    |      0.71       |    0.40
 1857   |    19.5    |     29.8      |   2.9    |      0.49       |    0.34
 1858   |    19.7    |     28.7      |   2.7    |      0.50       |    0.53
 1859   |    18.6    |     26.9      |   2.9    |      0.48       |    0.68
 1860   |    19.7    |     30.2      |   3.0    |      0.39       |    0.51
 1861   |    17.2    |     29.6      |   3.0    |      0.42       |    0.38
 1862   |    19.9    |     29.0      |   3.0    |      0.50       |    0.47
 1863   |    20.8    |     26.9      |   3.2    |      0.38       |    1.16
 1864   |    23.1    |     26.6      |   3.2    |      0.40       |    1.00
 1865   |    23.8    |     28.1      |   3.4    |      0.28       |    0.64
 1866   |    23.4    |     24.2      |   3.1    |      0.39       |    1.94
 1867   |    23.1    |     21.0      |   3.0    |      0.49       |    0.91
 1868   |    22.5    |     22.8      |   3.4    |      0.57       |    0.54
 1869   |    23.5    |     23.6      |   3.6    |      0.48       |    0.38
 1870   |    19.0    |     21.7      |   3.1    |      0.36       |    0.66
 1871   |    19.4    |     17.9      |   2.4    |      0.45       |    0.96
 1872   |    23.6    |     26.4      |   3.2    |      0.38       |    0.67
 1873   |    24.7    |     31.8      |   3.2    |      0.41       |    0.73
 1874   |    28.6    |     43.7      |   3.7    |      0.45       |    1.23
 1875   |    32.2    |     41.3      |   3.8    |      0.87       |    1.26
 1876   |    32.7    |     47.0      |   4.2    |      1.21       |    0.86
 1877   |    33.8    |     43.4      |   4.8    |      1.45       |    0.93
 1878   |    33.7    |     49.6      |   5.5    |      2.24       |    9.93
========+============+===============+==========+=================+==============



b. 1882–1896. Persons Convicted.

========+=============+==============+==========+==================
 Years. | Violence to | Violation of | Perjury. |  Embezzlement in
        |  Officials. |   Domicile.  |          | Military Service.
--------+-------------+--------------+----------+------------------
  1882  |     40      |      56      |   3.1    |        49
  1883  |     39      |      52      |   2.7    |        54
  1884  |     42      |      60      |   3.0    |        55
  1885  |     40      |      57      |   3.0    |        57
  1886  |     42      |      61      |   2.5    |        61
  1887  |     43      |      58      |   8.8    |        66
  1888  |     39      |      53      |   8.5    |        72
  1889  |     39      |      58      |   8.6    |        61
  1890  |     40      |      59      |   8.7    |        61
  1891  |     40      |      57      |   8.5    |        56
  1892  |     41      |      59      |   8.5    |        58
1882-91 |     41      |      58      |   8.8    |        60
  1894  |     47      |      62      |   8.3    |        51
  1895  |     47      |      65      |   --     |        --
  1896  |     47      |      63      |   --     |        --
========+=============+==============+==========+==================


“The chief reasons why this crime (against personal liberty), like most
crimes against persons, has constantly increased up to the present, in
addition to the growing discontent with the present economic situation,
are two; first, the effect of the spread of great manufactories in
breaking up the family life, with concomitant lack of moral and
religious education, and the too early necessity for self-supporting
labor ...; and second, the present inordinate desire for pleasure,
whose results are seen not least in the harmful effects of the
immoderate consumption of alcohol; for that this is a prolific source
of the multiplication of crime can hardly be doubted.” [80]

Dr. Müller’s final conclusion is as follows: “We may regard it as an
established truth that, in the last analysis, the cause for the
increase and decrease of crime as a whole is to be found in the
presence or absence of a chance for employment and gain, in the
condition of individual lines of industry, and in the greater or less
degree in which the population as a whole in consequence of this, are
in a position to consume.” [81]

—Recently it has been proved that the conclusion of Dr. Müller with
regard to the slight influence of the price of grain upon criminality
was not entirely correct. Notwithstanding the growing influence of the
industrial situation upon criminality, the price of grain has retained
a certain influence. [82]—




XVIII.

CRITICISM.

The authors treated of in this chapter, and many others whom I have had
to put under other headings as belonging to some special school, all
have this point in common, that they try to find the causes of crime by
means of statistics. The first question that arises is this: do
criminal statistics give a real and complete picture of criminality?
The answer is categorically, No. To give only a few reasons, there are
a great many crimes, naturally insignificant, which remain unknown even
to the person injured; there are others of which justice never takes
cognizance, because the injured party has filed no complaint, either
because he has pardoned the offender, or fears the trouble of a
criminal trial, etc.

In general, not all the cases known to justice are included in the
criminal statistics but only those in which sentence is pronounced. An
exception is found in Mayr’s book (§ VI of this chapter), in which all
the crimes known to justice appear. In the first place the public
officer dismisses many cases because of their insignificance (Germany
is an exception—there the officer must prosecute); and in the second
place there are a number of crimes whose authors remain unknown.
Finally, only a part of those arraigned are convicted. Criminal
statistics, therefore, cover only a part of the crime that exists. [83]

The enemies of statistics have drawn from the preceding fact the
conclusion that criminal statistics are useless for the study of the
etiology of crime. This is an absolutely false conclusion, as false as
it would be to claim that doctors cannot find the cause of a disease,
because besides the thousands of cases known to them, there are at
least as many that remain unknown. The only question that arises is the
following: is the number known sufficient? is there a sufficiently
large body of facts in hand for inductive studies? As far as
criminality is concerned the answer can be perfectly positive. The
number of offenses that do not appear in the criminal statistics is
certainly large; they are, however, chiefly insignificant misdemeanors,
such as insults, trifling assaults, petty thefts, etc. These would have
little value in determining the etiology of crime, even if the
statistics included them all. Serious crimes, on the other hand, in the
majority of cases, without any doubt appear in the statistics. The
great reason why criminal statistics suffice for etiological
investigations is that the ratio of known crime to unknown remains
relatively constant. The proofs of this are to be found in the criminal
and judicial statistics themselves. The ratio between cases dismissed
and those prosecuted, between convictions and acquittals, etc., etc.,
remains practically the same from one year to another. Further, every
statistician of any experience is convinced that the law of averages
rules more absolutely than any despot.

Finally it must be noted that the fact that there are a number of
offenses which do not appear in the criminal statistics, does not mean
that there are many criminals of whom the same can be said. It is the
Italian school in particular that has maintained the proposition that
in the struggle between the criminal and society it is the criminal
that has the upper hand. This is a mistake; the criminal generally
loses, and in the great majority of cases very quickly. Certainly the
criminals are not punished for each crime, but the cases in which they
remain unpunished are very rare. In the world of criminals itself there
is no other opinion on this point. [84]

Although the value of statistics in studying the etiology of crime is
certain, it must not be thought that they tell us everything. [85] I
pass over here numerous things which most statistics still lack, for
example, a classification by motive rather than according to the
technical distinctions of the penal laws, [86]—and will simply call
attention to the difficulty of making international comparisons. The
difference merely in the penal laws makes the comparison very
difficult, and in many cases even impossible. Further, the
dissimilarity of procedure, the differences in the organization of the
police, etc., increase this difficulty. [87] In general, we can say
that international comparisons give results where the nature of the
crime (as homicide, for example) minimizes the difference between the
codes, and where the figures show considerable differences. We can
truly say that for the etiology of crime statics are much less
important than dynamics. When we apply the dynamic method to a fairly
long period, we have also to allow for the changes that have taken
place in the penal codes and in the police organization, etc.

The statistical method certainly contains many sources of error. It
goes without saying that this is not a reason for not using it at all,
but simply for being careful. We must guard against conclusions too
hastily drawn. If statistics show less criminality among the Jews—as is
generally the case—it is not safe to say, therefore, that the innate
morality of the Jew is greater than that of other men. If crime
increases during a certain period together with irreligion, we have no
right to conclude that there is a causal connection between the two.
The connection between the movement of the price of grain and that of
crimes against property has been proved many times, as we have seen; if
this parallelism of the two curves no longer occurs, we cannot say on
that account that economic conditions no longer play a part in the
etiology of these crimes; we have seen that in manufacturing countries
the industrial situation in general dominates the course of economic
criminality. Similar examples could easily be multiplied.

The statistical method is one of the most effective for discovering the
etiology of crime, and my readers will see that I use it much of the
time. Nevertheless, it must not be forgotten that this method, however
important, is only one among several. It is chiefly valuable in finding
the direct causes of crime; as to indirect causes it gives us much less
information. I would call attention to the following example: several
authors have proved that there is an inverse connection between
economic conditions and crimes against persons, i.e. that these crimes
increase in times of prosperity (this does not apply to recent times,
however). The conclusion has often been drawn from these facts that an
improvement in the lot of the working-class would lead, as a law of
nature, to an increase in crimes of violence. This is a typical example
of the insufficiency of the statistical method alone. When we seek for
the cause of this phenomenon in another way, in the structure of
society, we discover that it is to be found in the low moral and
intellectual condition of the working-classes. There can be no law of
nature at the root of the matter, else the well-to-do classes would be
the violent criminals “par excellence.” It goes without saying that
just the contrary is the case.



To sum up, I conclude that statistics furnish a powerful means of
discovering the causes of crime, provided they are used critically and
carefully. The statistical method is not the only one; to be a good
criminologist, it is necessary to be a statistician, but it is
necessary to be a sociologist also.



[Note to the American Edition: Upon the relation between sociology and
statistics see also Žižek, “Soziologie und Statistik.”

In recent years there has been a violent controversy over the
statistical method. It was opened by Hoegel in his “Die Grenzen der
Kriminalstatistik” and “Kriminalstatistik und Kriminalaetiologie”; then
came Wassermann with his “Begriff und Grenzen der Kriminalstatistik”,
and “Georg v. Mayr als Kriminalstatistiker und Kriminalsoziologe und
die moderne Methodenlehre”, which goes farther and denies almost all
value to the statistical method. On the other side, we find v. Mayr in
his “Statistik und Gesellschaftslehre”, II, p. 441, “Forschungsgebiet
und Forschungsziel der Kriminalstatistik”, “Kriminalstatistik und
Kriminalaetiologie”, and Wadler in his “Erkenntnistheorie und
Kriminalstatistik.”]








CHAPTER III.

THE ITALIAN SCHOOL. [88]


I.

C. LOMBROSO.

In “Crime, Its Causes and Remedies”, [89] one of his last works,
Professor Lombroso treats, among other things, of the influence of
economic conditions upon criminality.

Chapter VI, bearing the title, “Subsistence (famine, price of bread)”,
is the first in which we find any observations especially interesting
to us. By the aid of data from von Oettingen, Starke, Corre, and
Fornasari di Verce, which we treat separately, the author calls
attention to the fact that the course of criminality is very little
influenced by the price of provisions. He closes by drawing the
following conclusion:

“But, admitting the action of scarcity of food upon the increase of
thefts and of abundance upon the increase of homicides, assaults, and
debauchery, it is easy to understand its slight influence upon the
variation of criminality in general, if one group of crimes increases
with a given state of the market, and another group decreases under the
same conditions, and vice versa. Even when the price of food moves in a
constant direction it does not modify essentially the proportion of
certain crimes. For example, in Italy the effect of the rise in price
of food upon aggravated thefts is very marked; yet the greatest
difference is between 184 and 105, that is to say, a variation of 79 to
the 100,000. Likewise, when the sexual crimes increase on account of
the low price of food, the greatest difference is 2.14 to the
100,000,—a fact easy to understand when one thinks of the greater
influence of heredity, climate, and race.” [90]

The circumstance that the thefts of food represent hardly 1% of the
total cases of theft (according to Guerry), that in London bread
occupies only the 43d place among 43 categories of articles stolen, and
that Joly has shown that the cases of theft of money are much more
numerous than those of meal, domestic animals, etc.—all of this leads
the author to the conclusion that the proportion of crimes caused by
lack of food and real misery is not so great as has been supposed.

—I will not make any criticism of the preceding at this point, but wait
until I analyze the works themselves. The exposition of the work of Dr.
G. Mayr, for example, shows how superficial the observations made by
Professor Lombroso are. (See also the analysis of the work of Dr.
Müller, in which it is shown that now the industrial situation plays a
preponderating part in causing crime.) I would only call attention to
the naïve error involved in Professor Lombroso’s last remark, that
there are only a few articles stolen that could immediately provide for
pressing needs, and that this proves that poverty is not an important
factor in criminality. If society were not based upon exchange this
might be true, but the assertion has no basis in the present state of
things, when anything may be bought for money. The reason that more
money than food is stolen is to be found, in part, in the facts; first,
that money is less bulky, and consequently can be more easily taken and
concealed; and second, that money has more value than the same quantity
of provisions, so that more can be procured with the same effort. But
this proves nothing with regard to the influence of poverty upon crime.
[91]—

In the second part of the chapter Professor Lombroso tries to show that
the effect of hunger upon revolts is not very great. He cites a number
of cases where there were no revolts although prices were high and work
scarce. Thus, for example, in Strasburg from 1451 to 1500 and from 1601
to 1625, the price of beef rose 134% and that of pork 92%, and during
many years wages fell 10%; and yet there was no insurrection.

—I must vigorously protest against any such argument, which, in my
opinion, has no value. I will leave out of consideration the last
example, which proves but little, since during these periods the price
of bread may have been very low, neutralizing the effect of low wages
(it is quite problematical whether the poorer classes of the population
were great consumers of beef and pork!). But it is inaccurate to
conclude from the fact “that prices were high and there was no
insurrection” an absence of influence of the economic conditions. There
may have been a number of factors working in the opposite direction,
which prevented the manifestation of the economic factor. To cite but
one example, it may be that during those times an excessively severe
penal law was in force, threatening the least attempt at insurrection
with cruel death.—

We shall next sum up Chapter IX, “Influence of Economic
Conditions—Wealth.” After saying that it is difficult to estimate the
wealth of a country at all accurately, the author produces the
following data in the first section of the chapter. He divides the
provinces of Italy into three groups according to the total wealth
(estimated from taxes on consumption, direct taxes, and taxes on
business), and compares the figures thus gained with some of the
principal kinds of crimes, reaching the following results:


==============+=============================++==============================
              |      Wealth, 1885-86.       ||  Wealth, 1890-93 (Bodio).
              |----------+-------+----------++----------+--------+----------
              | Maximum. | Mean. | Minimum. || Maximum. |  Mean. | Minimum.
--------------+----------+-------+----------++----------+--------+----------
Fraud         |   70.6   |  66.0 |   43.0   ||   55.13  |  39.45 |  37.39
Sexual crimes |   15.6   |  13.4 |   19.4   ||   16.15  |  15.28 |  21.49
Thefts        |  206.0   | 143.0 |  148.0   ||  361.28  | 329.51 | 419.05[92]
Homicides     |   11.3   |  17.0 |   23.0   ||    8.34  |  13.39 |  15.40
==============+==========+=======+==========++==========+========+==========


Professor Lombroso draws the conclusion, “that fraudulent crimes
increase positively with the increase of wealth, and the same is true
of thefts, but if we add rural thefts we get the maximum where wealth
is least; and this last is always true of homicides.” [93]

“The results for sexual crimes are more unexpected. They show their
minimum in Italy where wealth is moderate, and their maximum where
there is the minimum of wealth. Italy thus presents an exception, as
the usual course of sexual crimes is to increase with the increase of
wealth.” [94]

Another way of estimating the wealth of a country is by means of the
inheritance tax. For different Italian provinces the following results
are thus obtained:


(Indictments. Average to 100,000 Population, 1887–89.)

===========+=========+=========+=========+============+============+==========
           | Average | Thefts. | Frauds. |  Highway   | Homicides. | Assaults.
           | Wealth. |         |         | Robberies. |            |
-----------+---------+---------+---------+------------+------------+----------
Latium     |  3333   |   639   |   116   |     18     |     25     |    513
Piedmont } |         |         |         |            |            |
Liguria  } |  2746   |   267   |    44   |      7     |      7     |    164
Lombardy   |  2400   |   227   |    44   |      3     |      3     |    124
Tuscany    |  2164   |   211   |    34   |      6     |      7     |    165
Venice     |  1935   |   389   |    43   |      3     |      4     |     98
Reggio     |  1870   |   320   |    49   |      7     |     13     |    287
Emilia     |  1762   |   250   |    38   |      6     |      6     |    130
Sicily     |  1471   |   346   |    65   |     16     |     26     |    410
Naples     |  1333   |   435   |    47   |      6     |     21     |    531
Marches }  |                   |         |            |            |
Umbria  }  |  1227   |   222   |    33   |      3     |     10     |    239
Sardinia   |   --    |   670   |   113   |     14     |     20     |    277
===========+=========+=========+=========+============+============+==========


This table gives very little information as to the influence of wealth
upon criminality, since we can draw from it the most contradictory
conclusions. Note, for example, that the highest figures for theft are
to be found in the regions of Latium and Sardinia, i.e. in the richest
and the poorest provinces, etc., etc.

—I have more than once had occasion to show that the value of such
researches is fictitious. It is not the total amount of wealth but its
distribution that bears upon criminality. (See, for example, Quetelet
and Colajanni)—

In the 3d section the author treats of the effect of involuntary
unemployment. Wright tells us that in Massachusetts of every 220
persons convicted, 147 are without regular work, and that 68% of
criminals have no occupation. According to Professor Lombroso this is
easily explained by the fact that criminals do not like to work.
According to Bosco there were only 18% of murderers in the United
States without work (—the proportion not being given for non-criminals,
these figures have little value—). Finally, Professor Lombroso mentions
the opinion of Coghlan, who says that unemployment has no influence
upon criminality in New South Wales (—upon what he bases his opinion,
we do not know—).

—Such data as these (to a subject of such high importance as this the
author gives but thirty lines) suffice for the conclusion that the
phenomenon in question has little significance for criminality. I have
only to recall the extensive studies of Mayr, Denis, Müller, Lafargue,
and others, upon this subject, to prove the inaccuracy of this idea.—


=====================================================================================================
                       |        Number of Persons (to the 100,000 Inhabitants) convicted for:
Days of Work Equivalent+------------------+------------------+------------------+--------------------
   to a Year's Food.   |    Homicide.     |     Assault.     | Sexual Offenses. |       Theft.
-----------------------+------------------+------------------+------------------+--------------------
          1            |          2       |        3         |        4         |         5
-----------------------+------------------+------------------+------------------+--------------------
England and Wales }    |Scotland      0.51|England+Wales 2.67|Spain         1.03|Spain          59.63
Scotland          } 127|England+Wales 0.56|Ireland       6.24|Ireland       0.85|Belgium       110.44
Ireland           }    |Ireland       1.06|Scotland     11.59|Scotland      1.41|France        110.95
Belgium             130|Germany       1.11|Spain        43.17|England+Wales 1.66|Italy         165.89
France              132|Belgium       1.44|France       63.40|Italy         4.01|Ireland        65.81
Germany             148|France        1.53|Germany     126.40|Austria       9.33|England+Wales 165.63
Austria             152|Austria       2.43|Italy       155.35|France       10.26|Scotland      208.39
Italy               153|Spain         8.25|Belgium     175.39|Belgium      13.83|Germany       226.02
Spain               154|Italy         9.53|Austria     230.45|Germany      14.87|
=======================+==================+==================+==================+====================


Note.—Column 1 is taken from Mulhall’s Dictionary of Statistics (quoted
by Coghlan, op. cit.); and columns 2–5 are figured from the data
published by the Director of Italian Statistics (“Movimento della
Delinquenza secondo le Statistiche degli Anni 1873–83”, Rome, 1886).


In the table on the preceding page the figures for criminality of
different countries are compared with the number of days’ wages
equivalent to the annual cost of food for one individual. These figures
give us a composite picture of the price of food and the wage-scale.

This table shows; first, that excessive labor with a low wage, i.e.
with a lack of proper nutrition, has a certain correspondence with
homicide; second, there is also a certain correspondence with assaults
(Spain and Belgium furnishing exceptions); third, sexual crimes are
most common where we find the fewest days’ work and vice versa (Great
Britain and some other countries being exceptions); fourth, that theft
shows no correspondence. [95]

In another way Lombroso attempts to compare the economic conditions of
different countries and their criminality, namely, by means of the
number of savings-bank books. For Europe the figures are as follows
(taken from Coghlan):


=============+=================+================================
             | Persons to Each | Crimes to 100,000 Inhabitants.
             |  Savings-bank   +---------------+----------------
             |     Book.       |   Homicide.   |     Theft.
-------------+-----------------+---------------+----------------
Switzerland  |       4.5       |      16       |      114
Denmark      |       5         |      13       |      114
Sweden       |       7         |      13       |      --
England      |      10         |       5.6     |      163
Prussia      |      10         |       5.7     |      246
France       |      12         |      18       |      103
Austria      |      14         |      25       |      103
Italy        |      25         |      96       |      150
=============+=================+===============+================


These figures show how homicides move in inverse ratio to the number of
savings-bank books, while the contrary is the case with thefts. The
author forgets to point out that there are five exceptions to this
rule.

In Italy the greatest number of accounts corresponds to the smallest
number of homicides, as the following table shows:


=======================================================================
Average Number of Crimes in 20 Provinces in which the Wealth (According
to the Number of Savings-Bank Books) is:
---------------------+--------------+-------------------+--------------
                     |   Maximum.   |   Intermediate.   |   Minimum.
---------------------+--------------+-------------------+--------------
Fraudulent crimes    |      57      |       45          |      45
Sexual crimes        |      11      |       12.6        |      20
Thefts               |     132      |      133          |     160
Homicides            |      10      |       12.6        |      27.4
=====================+==============+===================+==============


There are several exceptions to this rule; for example, the richest,
like Palermo, Rome, Naples, and Leghorn, give very high figures for
homicides. According to Professor Lombroso the explanation in the case
of Palermo and Naples is to be found in the geographical situation; in
the case of Palermo, in race and the abuse of alcohol; and in the case
of Rome, in race, the abuse of alcohol, and in the political situation.

For France we get the following results:


=================================+=====================================
 In Departments where the        |            Average Number of:
   Degree of Wealth is:          +--------------+-----------+----------
                                 |  Homicides.  |  Thefts.  |  Rapes.
---------------------------------+--------------+-----------+----------
Minimum                          |      64      |    83     |    17
Medium                           |      86      |    99     |    26
Maximum                          |      89      |   186     |    29
=================================+==============+===========+==========


Here is just the opposite of what we get in Italy. The author explains
this in the following manner: first, the richest districts are those
that are industrial, where the influx of immigrants is greatest (these
latter committing four times as many crimes as the French); second,
because of ethnic and climatic factors; third, because of the greater
wealth of France, which is four times as rich as Italy; and fourth,
because of the demoralizing influence of quickly acquired wealth. [96]

The industrial activity of a country causes a considerable increase of
criminality, especially when it displaces agriculture. Of 42
agricultural departments only 11, or 26%, go beyond the average number
of assassinations in France; while the average is exceeded by 10 out of
the 26 departments of mixed industry, or 38%, and by 7 out of 17
manufacturing departments, or 41%. Rapes upon adults and crimes against
persons show similar results. [97]

Percentage of departments exceeding the average of all France in:


=====================================+============+====================
                                     |  Rapes.    |   Crimes against
                                     |            |      Persons.
-------------------------------------+------------+--------------------
Agricultural Departments (42)        |    33%     |        48%
Mixed (26)                           |    39%     |        39%
Manufacturing (17)                   |    52%     |        59%
=====================================+============+====================


Not only poverty, but often wealth as well may cause crime. This is why
some very wealthy districts show a figure for criminality as high as do
the very poor. “The cause of all this is only too clear. On the one
side poverty and the lack of absolute necessities impel toward the
theft of indispensable things for the satisfaction of the individuals’
own needs. This is the first cord binding poverty and assaults upon
property. On the other hand, poverty makes men impulsive through the
cortical irritation following the abuse of wine and alcohol, that
terrible poison to which so many of the poor resort to still the pangs
of hunger. Account must be taken also of the degeneration produced by
scurvy, scrofula, anemia, and alcoholism in the parents, which often
transforms itself into epilepsy and moral insanity. Poverty also drives
men to commit brutal eliminations of individuals who are an unwelcome
burden upon the family, ... Poverty is indirectly a cause of sexual
crimes, on account of the difficulty which the poor have of obtaining
satisfaction through prostitution; on account of precocious promiscuity
in factories and mines; etc., ... On the other hand, when a slight
temptation toward evil is presented to an individual in comfortable
circumstances, he is rendered physically and morally stronger by
sufficient nutrition and a sounder moral training, and is less pressed
by need, so that while he feels the impulsion to do evil, he can more
easily resist it.

“But wealth, in its turn, is a source of degeneration from other
causes, such as syphilis, exhaustion, etc. It drives men to crime
through vanity, in order to surpass others, and from a fatal ambition
to cut a figure in the world.” [98] It may be asked why it happens then
that the inmates of prisons are almost always poor and rarely rich. The
answer, according to the author, is that because of the influence of
his fortune, family, etc., the rich man can more easily extricate
himself from the clutches of the law than the poor man, who knows no
one, cannot employ a famous lawyer, etc. etc.

Professor Lombroso sums up his opinion as follows: “The economic factor
has a great influence upon crime, not, however, that poverty is the
principal cause of it, for excessive wealth, or money too quickly
acquired, plays a large part as well; and poverty and wealth are
frequently neutralized by the effect of race and climate.” [99]




II.

R. GAROFALO.

In Chapter III of his “Criminologie”, and more especially in the first
part, bearing the title “la Misère”, this author treats of the
influence of economic conditions upon criminality. [100] The question
which must be answered with regard to this subject, according to
Garofalo, is the following: “Whether the so-called ‘economic iniquity’,
a condition by which all citizens are either proprietors or
proletarians, is the chief cause or, at least, one of the most
important causes, of criminality.” [101]

It may be that a workman, i.e. a person who can only provide for his
own needs and those of his family by selling his labor, can find no
work, and for that reason falls into theft; but the author is of the
opinion that in our days this almost never happens (leaving aside
periods of crisis), and that if it happens the worker will generally
find some one ready to help him, and that crime is therefore not a
necessity. There is, indeed, absolute poverty, but it is almost always
the result of a lack of courage and energy, and not due to a lack of
work. It is not hunger, but a desire to procure the same pleasures as
those enjoyed by the favored of fortune, that impels the working-man to
commit crime. But this is not only the case with the working class but
with other classes as well. For this desire belongs to every man; the
millionaire envies the multimillionaire, etc. In order that this desire
should lead to crime, it is not necessary that there should be a
particular economic situation, but only a particular psychic
condition—the individual must have his sense of honesty weakened or
wanting. Desire will cease to lead to crime only when there is no
longer any advantage to be gained by it, and since this is
inconceivable, crime will always exist. This explains why the number of
crimes committed by the proletariat is very great, but at the same time
why the cases of forgery, bankruptcy, etc. are very numerous among the
other classes. In 1880 the figure for crimes against property (and
analogous crimes) committed in Italy by proletarians, compared with
those committed by property-owners, was as 88 to 12, while the ratio of
the number of proletarians to that of property-owners was as 90 to 10.
These proportions are nearly the same, which proves that as regards
these crimes the proletarian class is no more criminal than the others.

Some authors are of the opinion that crimes against persons are equally
caused in large measure by bad economic conditions, since bad
education, lack of discretion, etc. are consequences of these
conditions. In Garofalo’s opinion this idea is inaccurate, since the
bad conditions in which the proletariat live lead indeed to roughness,
i.e. make them insensible to the suffering of others, but it does not
follow that the proletarians are totally deprived of moral sentiments.
The criminal statistics of Italy show that 16% of the correctional
criminality was committed by property-owners, though they form but 10%
to 11% of the population. Garofalo attempts to prove the truth of his
thesis also by a classification of criminals by trades. The
agricultural class in Italy, the poorest and most ignorant, form 25.39%
of those brought before the correctional tribunals, while those engaged
in manufacturing, commerce, the army, etc., those with some education,
therefore, who are much less numerous in the population, form 13.58%.
In 1881 the Italian population included 67.25% of illiterates, and in
1880 68.09% of those correctionally convicted were illiterate. Further
it has been proved many times that an improvement in economic
conditions is accompanied by an increase of crime. In France, for
example, wages have risen, the consumption of cereals, like that of
meat, has increased, and the number of children enjoying the advantages
of a primary education is more extensive and yet criminality has grown
greatly in the same period. To the possible objection “that many
authors, like Mayr, have proved that the rise in the price of grain is
accompanied by an increase of crimes against property, and vice versa,
and that economic conditions are consequently an important cause of
crime”, Garofalo responds that crimes against persons increase with the
fall in the price of grain, and that consequently, by the changes in
the economic life there has been brought about a change in the kind,
but not in the extent, of criminality. Exceptional occurrences, such as
famines, commercial crises, etc., increase crime only in appearance. If
the question is probed to the bottom (the author appears not to have
done so himself, at least he does not record any results) it is
probable that it will be discovered that what happens is only that the
form of crime becomes more serious, that the vagrant, for example,
becomes a highway-man, etc.

The conclusions that the author draws are the following:

“First. The present economic order, that is to say, the distribution of
wealth as it exists today, is not a cause of criminality in general.

“Second. The fluctuations which are wont to occur in the economic order
may bring about an increase in one form of criminality, but this
increase is compensated for by the diminution of another form. These
fluctuations are, therefore, possible causes of specific criminality.”
[102]

—My criticism of what has gone before will be limited to some principal
points only.

First. The author dodges the question when he includes under economic
conditions poverty only, and this in the very limited sense of the lack
of the absolute necessities. He who writes upon the connection between
crime and economic conditions must analyze the whole present economic
system, and not stop with one of the consequences of that system, the
poverty in which the proletarians find themselves. Consequently
Garofalo’s whole argument, tending to show that the bourgeoisie have a
great part in the crimes against property, is beside the mark, for
capitalism results in great uncertainty of existence for the
bourgeoisie also. It is then quite comprehensible that this class
should be guilty of crimes of this kind. According to Fornasari di
Verce, however, the Italian statistics show that the well-to-do class
take less part in crime than the poor. According to him 13% of all
those convicted in 1887 were well-to-do, a class which, roughly
speaking, forms 40% of the whole population. (See also Colajanni, “La
Sociologia Criminale”, II, pp. 536 ff.)

In consequence of this arbitrary restriction of the subject the
author’s remarks are of little value. But aside from this there are
still serious charges to be made against his manner of treating the
subject.

Second. The assertion of Garofalo that in general in our present
society he who wishes to work can find work, is not worth combating in
a serious book. To say that machinery does not every day make some
workers unnecessary, that there are no industrial crises causing an
enormous amount of involuntary unemployment, is conclusive proof that
one does not know the present mode of production. The existence of a
group of the population, the so-called lower proletariat
(“bas-prolétariat”, “Lumpen-proletariat”) cannot be a natural
phenomenon, since it has not been always and everywhere present; it is
strictly bound up with certain modes of production.

Third. As I have had occasion to show already in more than one place,
the increase of crimes against persons during periods of prosperity has
a very great, though indirect, connection with economic conditions.

Fourth. That poverty in the strict sense of the word is not the sole
cause of economic criminality, that cupidity plays also an important
rôle, I do not wish to deny. Only, this cupidity is not an innate
quality of man, present everywhere and always, but is awakened only
under certain economic conditions. This is especially the case in our
present society.

Fifth. According to the author there are certain circumstances which
may lead to the commission of a crime, but the true cause of crime is
to be found in the absence or weakness of the instinct of honesty. That
there exists such an “instinct of honesty” is one of numerous
assertions made by Garofalo for which he produces no proof, and, in
accordance with the general opinion of sociologists, I class it among
the most profound errors. A moral disposition is innate in man, and
varies greatly with individuals, but moral concepts—for example, that
it is forbidden to steal—are certainly not innate. The very way in
which Garofalo puts the question is wrong; we must not set the
circumstances that have influenced a man at a certain moment over
against an innate quality of honesty (fictitious besides) but must
examine all the conditions which have influenced his innate moral
disposition through the whole of his life, as well as his environment
at a given moment.

To say that the influence of environment cannot be great, because
persons well brought up sometimes commit crimes, is very superficial.
Upon this point there is something deeper and more important to be
said.—




III.

E. FERRI.

In order to present Professor Ferri’s views, I shall analyze
“Socialismo e criminalità” and a passage connected with our subject,
taken from “Sociologia criminale.” [103] This analysis will be more
detailed than that of most of the other authors, since in reality the
opinion of Professor Ferri is the synthesis of the opinions of many
other authorities. For this reason and others it is of the highest
importance.

“Socialismo e criminalità” is a polemic work directed in part against
“Il delitto e la questione sociale” of Turati, and in part as Professor
Ferri himself says in “Socialismo e scienza positiva”, against
socialism as far as that involves the revolutionary method and the
concomitant “nebulous romanticism.”

In his “Preliminari” the author gives some definitions of socialism;
combats socialism of every kind, declares it to be unscientific, and
sets in opposition to it sociology, which is entirely scientific. [104]
We pass over this part of the work in silence, since it has little
importance for our subject, and turn our attention to the end of the
“Preliminari”, where the author gives an exposition of the ideas which
the socialists, according to him, have about crime:

“I. The origin of the phenomenon of crime is to be found in society as
at present constituted.

“II. More especially, the economic disorder of the population caused by
the unjust inequality of individuals and classes, is the cause of every
other disorder, moral or intellectual, and therefore of crime also.

“III. When the social transformation or revolution which the socialists
desire has taken place, the social atmosphere will be most favorable.

“IV. In the socialistic order the individual also will be much superior
to the man corrupted or demoralized by present conditions.

“V. And then crime, like poverty, ignorance, prostitution, and
immorality in general, will have ended its unhappy tyranny over the
human race.”

—It is not certain that an adherent of scientific socialism would agree
that these theses are entirely accurate; for example, the second, that
the bad economic condition of the population is the cause of crime—for
the expression “economic condition” has here too limited a meaning,
namely that of poverty, misery, etc. In place of this he would rather
make use of the expression, “mode of production.” It is this which, in
the last analysis, rules the whole social life, according to the
Marxists.—



The first chapter of Professor Ferri’s work, bearing the title of “la
genesi sociale e individuale del delitto”, begins by remarking that the
socialists blame society as the cause of all evils, including poverty
and crime. On the one hand, they do this because of their “strategy of
propaganda”, on the other hand it is a reaction against the extreme
individualism which sprang from the French Revolution. They generally
pay no attention to individual factors, or perhaps recognize them in
part, but attribute their origin to society also. Between these two
extremes is to be found criminal sociology, which says that the causes
of crime are manifold.

According to the author there are three groups of the factors of crime:
the anthropological or individual factors, the cosmic or physical
factors, and the social factors. Since many authors, wholly or
partially, share this view, which constitutes an attack against the
very foundation of the idea of the social origin of crime, we will
examine it here fully.

We take from “Sociologie criminelle”, where this doctrine is best set
forth, the following statement of it. “Every crime is the resultant of
individual, physical, and social conditions.” [105] The individual
factor is, according to the author, the most important, the primordial
factor, so to speak, for he says: “The social environment gives form to
the crime; but this has its origin in an anti-social biological
constitution (organic or psychic).” [106] The factors pointed out are
the following:

“The anthropological factors, inherent in the person of the criminal,
are the first condition of crime, and divide themselves into three
subclasses, according as the person of the criminal is looked at from
an organic, psychic, or social point of view.

“The organic constitution of the criminal constitutes the first
subclass of anthropological factors and includes all the anomalies of
the skull, brain, viscera, sensibility, reflex activity, and all bodily
characteristics in general, such as physiognomy, tattooing, etc.

“The psychical constitution of the criminal includes anomalies of
intelligence and feeling, especially of the moral sense and the
peculiarities of the criminal dialect and literature.

“The personal characteristics of the criminal include the purely
biological features of his condition, such as race, age, sex; and the
bio-social features, such as civil status, profession, residence,
social class, and education, which have been up to this time the almost
exclusive subject of criminal statistics.

“The physical factors of crime are the climate, nature of the soil,
length of nights and days, the seasons, the annual temperature,
meteorological conditions, and agricultural production.

“The social factors include the density of population; public opinion,
morals, religion; condition of the family; the educational system;
industrial production; alcoholism; economic and political conditions;
public administration, the courts, the police; and in general the
legislative, civil, and penal organization:—that is to say, a medley of
latent causes, which interlace and combine in all parts of the social
organism, and almost always escape the attention of ... criminologists
and legislators.” [107]



ANTHROPOLOGICAL FACTORS.

Let us consider first the “personal characteristics of the criminal.”
Professor Ferri draws the following conclusions with regard to the
existence of anthropological factors in general: “In fact, if crime
were the product of the social environment exclusively, how could the
fact be explained, that in the same social environment and in like
circumstances of poverty, abandonment, and lack of education, out of
100 individuals, 60 commit no crime, and of the 40 that remain, 5
prefer suicide to crime, 5 become insane, 5 become beggars or
non-dangerous vagrants, and only the 25 others become real criminals?
And why is it that among these, while some limit themselves to theft
without violence, others commit robberies, and even, before the victim
resists, or threatens, or calls for help, commit a murder with the sole
aim of theft?” [108]

—It seems to me that there are many objections to be made to this
rather carelessly drawn conclusion. In the first place, Professor Ferri
is of the opinion that it may be assumed that it will be easy to find
groups of persons only a quarter of whom become criminal, though they
all live in the same bad environment. Leaving out of account the
individuals who, because of their physical condition are incapable of
crime, I do not believe that there are, for example, 60% who have never
been convicted. However, even admitting that this assertion is
accurate, then, that out of 100 persons living in the same environment,
only one part will fall into crime, I believe that it is impossible to
find even two persons who live, and have lived, in an environment
exactly similar, and whose parents also have always lived in the same
surroundings. In this way only can the question be clearly put. It is
not only present conditions that influence a man; all past conditions
have their part in the motives of present acts. It cannot be denied
that the present includes the past. Nor ought the conditions which have
influenced the parents to be excluded. Let us put the following case:
A, B, and C live in the same very bad surroundings. A commits suicide,
B becomes crazy, C commits a crime. The parents of A were well-to-do,
gave their child a good education, and accustomed him to consider many
things as necessities. Fallen into poverty, then weakened and become
incapable of good work, A believes that it is impossible for him to
restore himself. His moral ideas, acquired in his youth, are opposed to
his engaging in crime. And then the few francs that he would be able to
steal would not be sufficient to maintain him in the life to which he
has been accustomed. Consequently he commits suicide. B is the child of
a father who became an alcoholic from actual poverty. Inferior on this
account, B cannot keep up the struggle for existence and becomes
insane. The parents of C were indigent. He received no education; moral
ideas are totally unknown to him; he has never lived in anything but
poverty, and commits a theft when the opportunity presents itself
without any hesitation. In these three cases, which occur daily,
circumstances are the only factor that enters into consideration.

I have said above that there are no two persons who live in exactly the
same circumstances. This word “exactly” is not used by Professor Ferri,
and in this, in my opinion, he is wrong. In ordinary life we speak of
great and small causes. But in treating of scientific questions this is
surely forbidden. For no one is ignorant that what is apparently the
least important occurrence may have the most extensive consequences.

May I here be permitted to make a quotation from an interesting page of
Professor Manouvrier upon this question: “That the effect of
environment is generally understood in too limited a way, we see proved
every day in the appreciation expressed, of the causes that have
determined certain differences of productive power or moral conduct. It
is a question, perhaps, of two brothers. It is said that they have been
brought up exactly in the same manner, that they have received exactly
the same education, and that the question of environment is thus
settled. Immediately the doctors begin to call in atavism, to feel the
bumps of the head, to study facial asymmetry, etc. Anatomy must be
appealed to, since the influence of environment has been eliminated. It
can be put down to bad luck if some bump, some depression, some
asymmetry is not found that will serve, whether or no, to account for a
solution of the question. There remains always, further, the resource
of invoking invisible, hypothetical vices of the internal constitution.
The phrenologists were in a relatively difficult situation; they had to
find a fixed anatomical character, a bump for a function specified in
advance, or they were obliged to imagine a conflict of bump with bump.
The present method is less exacting; it is enough to find no matter
what deviation from morphological perfection, without its being
necessary to show the connection between this deviation and the
physiological inferiority to be explained. But what am I saying? The
question is often of an inferiority of a sociological order, and
trouble is not even taken to make sure, to begin with, that this
corresponds to a psychological inferiority. Yet however indispensable
this may be as a preliminary, it is not enough; it must be ascertained
that this inferiority implies a functional trouble before calling in
pathological anatomy at all hazards.

“The statement is made that the two brothers have been subjected to the
same environmental influences merely because they have been brought up
in the same house, taught in the same school, fed and clothed alike.
Yet the mere fact of having been born first or second is not without
importance. To have been reared with an older or with a younger brother
constitutes a difference of environment that may contribute powerfully
to differentiate character. Add to this the differences of environment
proceeding from nurses, servants, diseases, games, etc., and you will
have opened headings under which may be classed differences
innumerable. There are no small things in such a matter. Biographies as
now written are no more than outlines when one thinks of what truly
psychological biographies ought to be. To have been taught in the same
college in the case of two brothers is a similarity that may, and
certainly does, conceal the greatest differences. They have not had the
same teachers, the same fellow-pupils, nor, above all, the same
comrades. Between the education given, and that actually received, the
difference may be great....

“The influences that act upon the child outside of the curriculum have
the more chance to be effective, since the curriculum is carried out in
the less agreeable manner.” [109]

In consequence of what has been said, I believe that the conclusion of
Professor Ferri that there are anthropological factors of crime, is too
hasty. But there are still other objections to be urged to it.

Let us suppose that two persons who live, and have lived, in the same
circumstances are in a position to commit a very advantageous crime,
and their morality does not prevent. At the moment when the time comes
to act, one commits the crime and the other does not—he lacks the
courage. Courage, then, is a factor of crime, and the lack of it a
factor of virtue! Not so, that depends upon circumstances. In another
case, he who commits a crime is stupid, and does not consider the risk,
and he who does not commit it is a crafty man. Stupidity, then, is a
factor of crime, and craft of virtue! Not so, that depends upon
circumstances. The reverse is also true, probably more true still.
Thousands of great criminals so far from being stupid have had
something of the genius in them.

The famous individual factors are only ordinary human qualities, like
courage, strength, needs, intelligence, etc. etc., [110] which men
possess in differing degrees, and which in like circumstances lead the
one rather than the other to commit a crime. These qualities in
themselves, however, have nothing to do with crime. Professor
Manouvrier expresses my thought on this subject in the following:
“There are, however, certain individuals more moved to crime than
others, in circumstances otherwise equal. Certainly, as man is more
given to crime than woman, as a robust and bold man is more given to
crimes of violence than one who is miserable and timid, etc., yet each
type of character finds some kind of crime practicable, if only arson.
The athlete will be more inclined to strike, the smooth talker to play
the confidence man, but we do not for that reason indict muscular
strength, nor ready speech, nor boldness, nor agility, nor address. No
more do we indict violence or trickery, qualities defined from the
vicious use made of qualities valuable for honest purposes.” [111]

The reasoning of Professor Ferri, that there is in every crime, besides
others, an anthropological factor, is only the statement of the fact,
known long before the rise of modern criminology, that the
predisposition to crime is not the same with all men. This
predisposition, as we have seen, considered by itself, has nothing to
do with crime as such. So much the more is the conclusion of Professor
Ferri and the Italian school in general absolutely false, when they
deduce from the undeniable fact that the predisposition is not the same
for all, the notion that this predisposition is by nature pathological.

Thus we have finally come to two other groups of anthropological
factors: the organic constitution of the criminal, as, for example, the
anomalies of the skull, brain, etc. and the psychical constitution of
the criminal, as, for example, the anomalies of intelligence and
feeling. [112] This is the special territory of the Italian school: the
criminal is a being apart—“genus homo criminalis”—with special stigmata
peculiar to him; there is a criminal type, anatomically recognizable;
most criminals are born-criminals, etc. The explanation of this special
character is to be found in atavism, an hypothesis later replaced by
that of epilepsy; finally it has been claimed that the character of the
criminal is in general of a pathological nature.

In our purely sociological work, though it combats in an indirect way
the hypothesis of the Italian school, we do not have to concern
ourselves with the conflict between the different anthropological
schools, with regard to the origin of crime. We demonstrate merely,
what no one who judges fairly will attempt to deny, that the hypothesis
of the Italian school is erroneous. The anthropological authorities
like Manouvrier, Baer, Näcke, and others, have broken this doctrine
down. [113] There are no stigmata belonging to criminals only, nor is
there any criminal type; the atavistic hypothesis is one of the
profoundest errors.

Although the doctrine of Lombroso and his school is in general
abandoned by anthropologists, it still persists in the acceptance of
one fact, to which it is its immortal merit to have called attention,
namely that there are a number of criminals (though a very limited
number) who show a truly pathological nature, and whose criminal
character can only be explained by this pathological nature. For
example, when someone in an epileptic condition commits a murder,
without any motive; or the case in which a well-to-do individual steals
continually useless articles, of little value, etc., etc. Even in most
of these instances, which are a small minority in the colossal mass of
criminality, the social environment plays its part; but it must be
recognized without reserve that here we have to do with true individual
factors, peculiar to certain individuals. The hypothesis of the Italian
school is, then, accurate for the exception, but false as a rule.—



PHYSICAL FACTORS.

It is evident that the nature of the soil, the climate, the physical
environment in a word, must have an important influence upon the mode
of production, and consequently upon society. [114]

It is easily understood why those who inhabit the regions of Siberia
covered with snow have not become agriculturists; and why Holland,
without mines of iron and coal has not become a great manufacturing
country, but instead, situated upon the sea and traversed by great
rivers, has become commercial. But these physical factors have remained
constant or nearly constant during historical periods, while the
organization of society has undergone changes that have great effects.
We cannot explain these changes by a constant factor.

Plechanow formulates this very well in his “Beiträge der Geschichte des
Materialismus.” He says: “The character of man’s natural environment
determines the character of his productive activity, of his means of
production. The means of production, however, determines the reciprocal
relationships of men in the process of production as inevitably as the
equipment of an army determines its entire organization, and all the
relationships of the individuals of which it is made up. Now the
reciprocal relations of men in the social process of production
determine the entire structure of society. The influence of the natural
environment upon this structure is therefore incontestable. The
character of the natural environment determines that of the social
environment. For example: ‘The necessity of computing the time of the
rising of the Nile, created Egyptian astronomy and with it the
domination of the priestly caste as guides in agriculture.’

“But this is only one side of the matter. Another side must also be
considered if one is not to draw entirely false conclusions. The
circumstances of production are the result, the productive forces are
the cause. But the effect becomes a cause in its turn; the
circumstances of production become a new source of the development of
the productive forces. This leads to a double result.

“1. The mutual influence of the circumstances of production and the
productive forces causes a social movement, which has its own logic and
a law of its own, independent of the natural environment. For example:
Private property in the primitive phase of its development is always
the fruit of the labor of the property-holder himself, as may be very
well observed in the Russian villages. There necessarily comes a time,
however, when it becomes the reverse of what it was before: it supposes
the work of another, and becomes capitalistic private property, as we
can likewise see any day in the Russian villages. This phenomenon is
the effect of the immanent law of the evolution of private property.
All that the natural environment can accomplish in this case consists
in accelerating this movement through favoring the development of the
productive forces.

“2. Since the social evolution has its own logic, independent of any
direct influence from the natural environment, it may happen that a
people, though inhabiting the same land and retaining almost the same
physical peculiarities, may have at different epochs of its history
social and political institutions which are very little similar, or
even totally different one from another.” [115]

Crime being a social phenomenon, and society being influenced, as we
have seen, by the physical environment, one might say that this
environment is a factor in criminality. He who reasons thus would have
to grant that the physical environment is only an indirect factor, and
therefore a very remote cause. It would be as fair to say that the
invention of gunpowder was one of the causes of all murders committed
with fire-arms. However, in reasoning thus I believe we forget that
crime is an historic phenomenon, modifying itself according to the
condition of society, and consequently regulated by laws that are
independent of the physical environment. In other words, the
environment is the reason why a people provides for its needs by
working the material that nature has furnished; but the manner in which
this work is done is independent of this environment. And it is upon
this manner of working that criminality depends. An example taken from
practice will make clear what I have been saying.

From the nature of the soil of Sicily it is possible to work sulphur
mines there. The criminality of Sicily is very great, especially in the
parts where the mines are found, and many murders particularly are
committed there. We might be disposed to believe that here the physical
factors came into play. Now it is true that the nature of the soil is
the cause of the exploiting of the mines, but the criminality is
dependent entirely upon the way in which the exploiting is done, and
this has nothing to do with the physical environment. To particularize:
these mines are exploited in the capitalistic fashion, i.e., with the
aim of getting as much profit as possible, which brings it about that
the workers are untaught, demoralized and made degenerate by ill-paid
labor, excessively severe, and carried on in an unwholesome atmosphere.
Hence come the higher figures for criminality. [116]

Most authors who have concerned themselves with the influence of these
physical factors, have only observed their direct influence upon man.
Many of them have paid no attention to the importance that these
factors may have for the character of society, and they have taken no
account of the fact that society develops according to laws independent
of the physical environment. Phenomena have been ascribed to the direct
influence of the physical environment, which have no such relationship.
It is a fact pretty generally recognized, for example, that the number
of violent crimes is greater in the South than in the North. The cause
frequently given is the obvious one that it is the difference of
climate. But this overlooks the fact that the phase of social
development reached in the southern countries is totally different from
that in the northern countries, and this difference explains that of
the criminality against persons. Upon this subject Professor Tarde
says: “Statistics compiled in epochs when, civilization not having
passed from the South to the North, the North was more barbarous, would
certainly have shown that crimes of blood were more numerous in the
northern climates, where now they are more rare, and would have induced
the Quetelets of that day to formulate a law precisely the reverse of
the one now stated. For example, if we divide Italy into three zones,
Lombardy, Central, and Southern Italy, we shall find that at present
there are in the first 3 homicides to the 100,000 inhabitants annually,
in the second nearly 10, and in the third more than 16. But shall we
estimate that in the palmy days of Grecia Major, when Crotona and
Sybaris flourished in the south of a peninsula which, in the North, was
totally peopled with brigands and barbarians, except for the Etruscans,
the proportion of bloody crimes would not have been reversed? At
present there are in Italy, in proportion to the population, sixteen
times as many homicides as in England, nine times as many as in
Belgium, and five times as many as in France. But we could swear that
under the Roman Empire it was quite otherwise, and that the savage
Britons, and even the Belgians and the Gauls surpassed the effeminate
Romans in habitual ferocity of manners, in vindictive fury and bravery.
According to Maine the Scandinavian literature shows that homicide
during the period of barbarism was a ‘daily accident’ with these
peoples of the North, at present the mildest and most inoffensive in
Europe.” [117]

It is plain from what has gone before that I have not wished to deny
the direct influence of the physical environment upon man. Indeed, it
is a fact which the whole world has observed. According to many
persons, then—and a number of scientific researches have proved it—a
high degree of criminality against persons proceeds from a hot
temperature, while a low temperature, on the other hand, leads to many
crimes against property. This implies not only that the kind of crime
is different in hot countries from that in cold, but also that the
change of the seasons with their variations in temperature have the
corresponding effects.

I will not fatigue the reader by citing an unlimited number of examples
to prove that the exceptions to this rule are very numerous. We cannot
find a greater number of crimes against persons and a smaller number of
crimes against property with each degree nearer the equator. If this
were the case dishonesty would be unknown at the equator, and everyone
there would be very violent. There are countries which, though in the
same latitude, are very different as to crime, as there are others,
much alike as to crime though situated far from each other, etc., etc.
[118] The adherents of the theory of the “physical environment” explain
these exceptions by saying that they are caused by the “social
environment.” By so doing they recognize that the latter may entirely
alter and even annihilate the influence of the former. Let us concern
ourselves rather with the different kinds of crime, and investigate the
influence which the physical environment exercises upon it.

In the first place, as to the assertion that cold increases the number
of crimes against property it is unnecessary to speak at length, for
nearly all authors are agreed that not physical but economic causes
come into play here. Cold increases men’s needs; they must have warmer
clothing and a well heated dwelling. But it is clear that all this is
no motive for stealing. For the person of means gets what he wants with
his own money. It is the present social organization that, during the
severe weather, does not permit people to provide for the needs that
are more numerous then, for the opportunity to work is more often
lacking in winter than in summer.

As to crimes against persons Professor Ferri is of the opinion that the
direct influence of temperature is as follows: “The increase of acts of
violence to persons, which is observed in connection with higher
temperatures, must be chiefly dependent upon the direct physiological
effect of heat upon the human organism. For by the greater warmth the
consumption of material for the production of animal heat is cut down,
and hence a surplus of force is stored up capable of being used for
other purposes. But this, in union with the heightened irritability of
temper, may easily degenerate into that criminal activity which shows
itself in acts of violence to persons. With this psychological effect
of the heat, it is true, there is coupled, in the case of the poorer
classes who form the majority of the population, the effect of more
easily obtained and more plentiful food, but this social cause in this
connection is of less importance than the direct biological influence.”
[119]

The first explanation of Professor Ferri is astonishing because
everyone feels that the heat has a different effect upon himself than
the one given. The fact that during hot weather the consumption of
bodily fuel is not so great as in cold weather cannot be considered as
the most important point in treating of the question of crime. Heat
enervates men, weakens their organism, and is the cause of men’s doing
as little as possible. It has, then, just the opposite effect to that
ascribed to it. [120]

More than once I have had occasion to point out that it is unjust to
say that the improved food of the poorer classes in summer can be the
cause of the greater criminality during that season. If this were the
case the persons who are well nourished at all times would furnish the
greatest number of violent criminals. Now we know that just the
contrary is the case. In my opinion the explanation is to be sought in
the fact that in summer people come into contact with one another more,
and consequently there is more opportunity for evil doing. [121] But
this in itself cannot naturally explain the increase of crimes.
Watering-places, where the bourgeoisie attempt to escape from the
effects of the heat, are not places where crimes against persons occur
in great numbers. Yet the concentration of many people in a limited
space is there very great. The degree of cultivation of the people
determines the greater or less ease with which quarrels arise. And what
proves that this degree need not be very high is the fact that acts of
violence are very rare among the bourgeois, the greater number of whom
have only a superficial culture.

The most convincing proof that the increase of violent crimes in spring
has no direct connection with the heat, is found in the fact that this
increase is already very great in the months in which in the North of
Europe there is absolutely no question of heat properly so called (i.e.
in March and April); and in the second place the course of crimes
during the week must be noted, with the maximum on Sunday, when
naturally the heat is no greater than on other days; and in the third
place, the maximum is not to be found at the hottest time of the day.
[122]

The increase of sexual crimes in hot seasons is in part only apparent,
because those who commit these crimes then operate more out of doors,
and a greater number of arrests results. For the rest, it must be
conceded that the sexual instinct in general is quickened a little
during the spring and summer, and as a consequence sexual acts
increase. But this does not mean that these acts are therefore
criminal. The principal reason why sexual crimes increase during the
hot weather is to be found in opportunity, which occurs much more
frequently than in cold weather. The proverb says: “opportunity makes
the thief”, and this is still more applicable to sexual criminals.
[123]

I am therefore of the opinion that the social factors must not be
included in the etiology of crime. They have their influence upon the
structure of society, they have also their influence upon man, but it
depends upon social conditions whether this influence takes a criminal
direction or not. [124]

Before taking up our analysis of “Socialismo e criminalità”, I would
remark that this division of the factors into three groups has to do
exclusively with the individual criminal, and thus loses sight of the
question why such an action in any place whatever, at any time
whatever, is regarded as criminal? Such a query brings out the fact
that we are here concerned with social factors only.

Let us take up now the exposition of Chapter I of “Socialismo e
criminalità.” Turati, in his “Il delitto e la questione sociale” has
made the following objections to Professor Ferri’s theses. Professor
Ferri distinguishes five categories of criminals: insane criminals,
incorrigible born-criminals, habitual criminals, criminals from
passion, and occasional criminals. In the first two categories
individual factors play a very important rôle; however, according to
Professor Ferri’s investigations these two groups include but 20% to
25% of the whole number of criminals, and deducting the insane, only
10% remain. Since criminals form only the minority of the population,
and physical factors have only a slight influence, it follows that
these factors influence rather the form than the cause of the crime.
The three factors work nearly all the time. It is clear, therefore,
that the two other factors alone will not be strong enough to produce
crime at a time when the social factor is eliminated, as has been
proved by the socialistic colony at New Lanark, which preserved an
exemplary morality for four years. Then, without taking account of the
crimes that are the consequence of viciousness of life or of the
abnormal economic condition, the authors of great crimes (except
technical and professional ones) are less numerous among the well-to-do
than among the lower classes, where the anthropological elements are
nearly the same. And if the different classes show anthropological
differences, this is not because these differences are innate in
individuals on account of being born in the lower classes, but because
they are produced and brought about by poverty, bad education, etc. The
true causes of crime are consequently social conditions, and in the
last analysis economic conditions.

Professor Ferri’s argument against what has just been said may be
summed up as follows: Will there be no social atmosphere in a
socialistic state? Or rather, will this atmosphere be so perfect that
the germ of the smallest social factor of crime will be absent? Do we
suppose that when poverty is suppressed, jealousy will disappear at the
same time? If legal marriage is abolished will that prevent an ugly man
from violating or killing a beautiful woman who refuses to accept him?
It may be objected that in this case the man is not an habitual or an
occasional criminal, but a born-criminal, or an insane criminal, or a
criminal from passion. Well and good, but then in this future state we
shall still be far removed from an earthly paradise.

Turati commits the following errors in his reasoning: First, he sets
aside the insane criminals; wrongly, according to Professor Ferri, for,
although insane, they are criminals. Second, 20%, the figure to which
born and insane criminals count up, is a very large number out of
60,000 prisoners. Third, Professor Ferri claims that it is incorrect to
say that the other causes are reduced to zero the moment the social
factors of crime are suppressed. For even with occasional criminals,
where the environment plays a very important part, an individual factor
must make its effect felt, or the individual would not become criminal.

Professor Ferri asks, on the other hand: How does it happen that out of
a hundred working-men living in the same environment, only a very few
fall into crime? This can be explained only by admitting individual and
physical causes. When socialists say that these individual differences
are innate simply in consequence of the poverty in which ancestors of
the persons in question have lived for thousands of years, the author
admits this reasoning in great part, but thinks nevertheless that he is
right in maintaining that these qualities are innate in certain
individuals at the present time.

With regard to the fact that a very high morality was maintained in New
Lanark, the author says: first, that he would very much like to
convince himself with his own eyes, especially since he has read that
in this colony the habit of celebrating Christmas eve with excessive
drinking was kept up; second, that he knows that crimes were committed
in a communistic colony of that time; further we are not to forget that
difficulties are increased in a great city.

The following chapter is entitled: “Benessere e criminalità.” To the
unproved assertion of the socialists that bad economic conditions are
the principal if not the only cause of crime, the author opposes some
facts to prove that this statement is largely incorrect. To this end he
divides crimes into three groups: first, crimes against property,
second, crimes against persons or crimes of blood, and third, crimes
against morals. Besides these three categories there are many crimes
which have neither directly nor indirectly any connection with bad
economic conditions; for example, crimes against honor, insults, or
abuse of power.

First, then, the crimes against property. The author recognizes that
most of these crimes are caused by bad economic conditions. But it is
an exaggeration, he says, to say that all these crimes result from such
conditions. This is to overlook crimes against property committed out
of revenge. However, in a communistic society there would necessarily
be cases of theft still, without taking into account kleptomania, etc.
For the articles of consumption would still remain private property;
and why should one not rob his fellow-citizen from jealousy? Or is it
not probable that someone would prefer to take from his neighbor the
thing he needs rather than make a trip of some miles to get it from a
central store? But if we admit that the bad economic conditions of the
time are the cause of the crimes against property, it remains to find
the causes of the crimes of the other groups. Though he recognizes that
economic conditions occupy a place in the etiology of these last
crimes, as, for example, murder from cupidity, the author does not
believe that this can be made a general rule. When socialists object
that the man of the future will be morally improved, Professor Ferri is
of the opinion that at the present moment we have to do with the men of
today and not with the men of the future.

The study of criminality in France during the years 1825–80 has shown
an extraordinary increase in crimes against persons and against morals
during the years 1848–52. A minute examination shows the author that it
was due to the great increase in the consumption of meat and wine, both
very cheap at this time, and also to a rise in wages. The result of the
betterment in economic conditions was, therefore, an increase in the
crimes mentioned.

Professor Ferri finds another proof in the following table:


Number of Persons Arraigned to 100,000 of Each Class (France).

===============================+==============+===============+=========+==============+===============
                               | Agricultural | Manufacturing |  Arts   |    Other     |    Without
            Crimes.            |     Class.   |    Class.     |   and   | Professions. |  Occupation,
                               |              |               | Trades. |              | Vagrants, Etc.
-------------------------------+--------------+---------------+---------+--------------+---------------
Thefts                         |    6.6       |      12.9     |   18.1  |     11.1     |    136.3
Forgery                        |    0.7       |       1.3     |    2.1  |      3.4     |      8.3
Arson                          |    0.4       |       0.4     |    0.5  |      0.3     |      5.2
Infanticide                    |    0.4       |       0.3     |    0.4  |      0.4     |      4.1
Serious assaults               |    1.0       |       1.2     |    1.8  |      0.8     |      2.7
Homicide                       |    0.5       |       0.4     |    0.6  |      0.5     |      2.4
Murder                         |    0.9       |       0.7     |    1.1  |      0.9     |      5.8
Sexual crimes with violence    |    0.4       |       0.7     |    1.0  |      0.4     |      1.9
  ,,     ,,   against children |    0.7       |       1.4     |    2.1  |      1.1     |      5.5
-------------------------------+--------------+---------------+---------+--------------+---------------
    Average of all crimes      |    13.9      |      23.0     |   32.5  |     22.4     |    193.0
===============================+==============+===============+=========+==============+===============


It follows from this table that the farming class, which, if you except
vagabonds, is the class with the least means, shows the figure
relatively lowest, and that the assertion of the socialists, that those
who are brought to the bar of justice are almost all from the
proletariat, is inaccurate.

—I shall not discuss the question, whether the proletariat furnishes a
disproportionately large contingent of criminals. The arguments of
Professor Ferri do not seem very strong to me. “Agricultural class”,
for example, is too vague a distinction. What an enormous distinction
between the rich farmer and the poor day-laborer, who earns only a few
francs a week! Yet both are included in the first group.—

When we examine the course of crime in France during the period
1826–80, we see a considerable increase in the crimes against property,
morals, and persons, while the economic conditions have improved during
these years even for the proletariat. To what cause is this increase to
be ascribed? It is impossible to attribute it to a relaxation of the
strictness of the police and the courts, for the activity of these has
become greater. Further, where it is evident that there are such strong
causes of crime, it would be madness to think that a greater severity
of penalties leads to a diminution of criminality. It is for this
reason that the school to which the author belongs insists not upon the
increase of penalties, but rather upon the elimination of causes. Hence
the doctrine of “penal substitutes.”

The true cause is the following: The more abundantly a man is
nourished, the more his organic forces are developed; there is,
therefore, a greater activity which may express itself in more acts of
honest labor, but may also express itself in an increased number of
unlawful acts. And then we must not lose sight, especially with regard
to sexual crimes, of the existence of a biological and of a
sociological law, namely, first, that the generative force of animals
and of man increases in proportion to the abundance and ease of
nutrition; second, that by a continual development of foresight, the
nations which follow the advice of Malthus are more and more giving the
lie to the law that he formulated, since with them population shows a
tendency to increase less rapidly than the means of existence, and
almost in inverse proportion to wealth. This is why criminality is
increasing in France, where the system of foresight is greatly
developed, and where the population enjoys better nutrition than
formerly.

Professor Ferri is of the opinion that we can derive from the observed
facts the following rules: first, criminality increases in extent but
diminishes in violence; second, scarcity makes crimes against property
increase, and decreases those against persons, while abundance has the
opposite effect; third, civilization decreases the number of homicides,
but increases that of suicides; fourth, a development of foresight with
regard to births prevents an excessive increase of the population, and
consequently an excessive increase of pauperism, but increases the
figures for sexual crimes.

Turati makes the following objections to these statements: In the first
place, in civilized countries, crimes against persons are much less
numerous than crimes against property, and just in proportion to the
degree of civilization. Why is it not likely that in the end the
criminogenous influence of nutrition will disappear in consequence of
the law in accordance with which crimes increase in number, but
decrease in grossness and intensity? Further, it is doubtful whether
this influence is so strong. The true cause is not good nutrition but
the Malthusian check, and it is this last which leads to crime,
precisely in the proletariat, since in this class prostitution cannot
act as a safety valve; and bad economic conditions are the cause of the
“moral restraint.”

Professor Ferri recognizes that there is a partial truth in this
reasoning, but makes the following objections: that crimes of blood are
more numerous than crimes against morals and yet have no relation to
the Malthusian check; that, as regards crimes against morals, it is not
correct to say that the proletariat are driven to them by economic
causes; that it is the proletarians that multiply the fastest, and the
well-to-do classes who do not wish to have many children; and that the
individual and biological factors would always remain, and lead to
crimes against persons, even if the aforesaid cause of sexual crimes
were to disappear. In the following chapters the author treats of the
assertion of Turati that an improvement in education and the new
“social atmosphere” will bring about a change.



—The criticism of the chapter of which I have just been speaking may be
summed up as follows: Like so many other authors, Professor Ferri
understands the expression, “economic conditions”, in a very limited
sense. He includes only direct influences, and in this way it is very
easy to prove that they explain only a part of criminality. But this
interpretation is very incomplete, since all social life is influenced
by economic conditions. In proving, therefore, like many other authors,
that while an improvement in the economic condition of the
working-class is accompanied by a decrease in crimes against property,
it is also accompanied by an increase of sexual crimes and crimes
against persons, Professor Ferri forgets not only that the lack of
education leads to crimes of violence, but also that in our present
society the possibility of satisfying the sexual appetites depends upon
the social position of the individual. The argument, in opposition to
Turati, “that Malthusianism is applied chiefly by persons of some
means” is not a happy one for one who wants to prove that economic
conditions have not a considerable influence. For the reason of this is
just the difficulty of procuring a good position for many children,
and, in the case of landholders, the desire to avoid a too great
division of the land. These are purely economic causes.—



“Educazione e criminalità” is the title of the third chapter. The human
brain is an organic mechanism, similar (but with numerous exceptions)
to an inorganic mechanism in this, that it is subject to the great law
of the conservation of energy, which manifests itself, among other
ways, in inertia. From which it comes that man at all times has had an
irresistible tendency to make use of a general principle as a basis for
his logical structures. Without this he would always be forced to build
each new structure from the ground up, which would involve the waste of
too much cerebral energy. Opposed to this law is another which teaches
us that life is impossible in a state of absolute repose, but that it
requires a perpetual changing of the organic and physio-psychic
materials. Hence it comes that eternal and absolute truths change at
different epochs, and that they seem stable only when compared with the
secondary truths, which are subject to the fashions of the time.

According to the author, then, there are truths that are more general
and nearly inalterable, but there are others which, though general
also, are more secondary, only retain their force during several
generations, and end by being changed. Such, for example, are the views
concerning human life, formulated by the great thinkers, then accepted
by the majority, and finally supplanted by other truths. This is why
science makes progress by dogmas. It is modern science that has made
the great step in recognizing that these dogmas are relative and
alterable.

Against this reasoning two objections can be alleged. First, that
Spencer has given the name “hypothesis” to his doctrine of evolution,
while Professor Ferri calls it a dogma. The author on the other hand
thinks that his opinions and those of Spencer are exactly alike, for he
calls the doctrine in question a relative and alterable dogma, and
Spencer says of it: what I have given is an hypothesis; but so long as
there is nothing better, that will explain a greater number of facts, I
have a right to consider it as the image of the knowable truth, until
the contrary is proved. In the second place, it may be asked: “Does man
always oscillate between truth and error; will he never know an
absolute and eternal truth?” According to Professor Ferri the answer to
this question is not difficult. The origin as well as the aim of faith
is the effort to give to men a relatively stable support, which they
cannot find elsewhere. All discussion with the adherents of a
theological opinion is excluded; and as for the others, ought they not
to recognize that the life of human thought is just the constant proof
of the continual modification of the so-called eternal verities?

After this introduction the author enters upon the subject itself. At
the beginning of the 19th century the dogma was dominant, that
instruction was the panacea for all crimes. Later many of the
publicists, including the socialists, advanced the opinion that the
true remedy for criminality was education. Just as the first theory was
incorrect, Professor Ferri would show that the second is equally so.

The question is, can education lead man to good or to evil; and if it
can, how far can it lead him? The scientific pedagogues have not
treated this question, as far as the author knows. Without furnishing
proofs the socialists admit that education can modify man in many
respects. Owen, for example, says: “every child may be brought up to
have in his later life only good habits, or bad, or a mixture of the
two, according to his education.”

It is necessary to distinguish three kinds of education—physical,
intellectual, and moral. First, a general observation applicable to all
kinds of education. In his physical, intellectual, and moral make-up,
each individual is the product of a countless number of ancestors, to
whom he is bound by unchangeable laws of heredity. From this it is
clear that the power of education, which acts only during a limited
number of years, is small compared to that of the influences to which a
man’s ancestors have been subjected for thousands of years. The
question becomes, then: “what are the limits of such modification?”
Further it is necessary to determine just how far this modification is
due to education, and how far to environment. For education, properly
so called, i.e. the direct and methodical influence of the educator
upon his pupil, differs in many respects from that of the physical and
social environment. This is why the author treats this latter in a
special chapter, and limits himself now to education alone. The
question is therefore reduced to this: “how far can a man (the
educator) modify the constitution of another man (the pupil)?”

One more observation should precede the study of the question, namely
that a force, or a complexus of forces, can be influenced only by other
homogeneous forces. Now when we examine how far physical or biological
education can make its influence felt, we see that this influence may
be very great, though naturally limited, in proportion to the knowledge
we have of the structure and functioning of the organs which it is
attempted to modify. As to intellectual education, the results are much
less, since the knowledge of the organs involved is much smaller. As to
moral education, the following question is one to which pedagogues have
given little attention: “how far do morality or immorality, good or bad
character, depend upon the education received at home and in school?”

Spencer lays down the fundamental rule that the moral conduct of man
can be studied scientifically only on condition of being considered as
forming part of the conduct in general, and also of the activity in
general, of all living beings. Sergi is of the same opinion. And this
is correct, Professor Ferri thinks, if, as these two authors do, one
studies the conduct and character of man in their constituent elements,
in their genesis and development, without taking into consideration the
variability of the character, and consequently of the conduct, of man
because of his education. In our case, in studying the constituent
elements, the genesis, the development, and the variability of the
moral part of the character and conduct of man, it is necessary to
separate these parts, and to limit ourselves to a special study of one
of them.

All psychologists are agreed that the moral conduct of a man (including
criminal conduct) although having naturally a certain relationship with
his muscular and intellectual condition, depends directly and
intimately upon the condition of his feelings, emotions, and passions
in their moral aspect. Hence it is clear that the problem is: “how far
can these feelings be modified by education?”

Let us first of all note that the expression, “a man of good (or bad)
birth”, does not imply that there are persons who are totally good or
totally bad, for these two qualities always appear in combination. It
only indicates whether the good or the bad qualities predominate.

It is certain that some persons have become criminals from lack of
moral education, added to bad surroundings. In this case this lack of
education has favored the greater development of the bad germs, which,
however, gives us no right to conclude that the converse would be true:
that education can improve the moral character, strengthening the good
germs to such a point that they have the mastery over the bad. For we
must not lose sight of two things: first, that the bad germs that show
themselves in our present society are the anti-social instincts,
opposed to the sociability and sympathy upon which life is based, while
the good germs are the social instincts; second, that, since
individuals reproduce morphologically and physiologically during life
the different phases that man and animal have gone through, it is in
the lowest strata of his character that man preserves the savage and
anti-social feelings that are the consequences of the condition in
which the race has lived heretofore, while the germs of the modern
social ideas are to be found in the higher and more recent parts. Hence
it follows that the anti-social instincts, being of a more ancient date
than the social instincts, are stronger than they and are not stifled
by them. And then, the environment, the present civilization, is also
partly the cause. This is why the author agrees with Sergi that in our
present society there are individuals who are constantly driven to
crime by their organic and psychical constitution, made up in great
part of the deeper, anti-social strata (the born-criminals and
incorrigibles), and that there are others whose constitution is formed
primarily of the more recent, social strata, and who become criminal
only under extraordinary impulses, in consequence of a volcanic
eruption, as it were, from the deeper, anti-social strata (criminals
from passion). While Sergi is of the opinion that the anti-social
instincts will little by little become latent, lose their force, and
cease to act, Professor Ferri thinks that this will be the case only
with the minority of men.

Now in order to weaken the anti-social tendencies, it is, according to
the author, necessary to know, first, their seat; second, their
composition. Up to the present, psychology has made no study of the
human passions, emotions, and feelings, and consequently cannot give us
this information. It must therefore be considered as impossible that
education should so stifle the existing bad germs and strengthen the
good ones that these last should finally have the upper hand.

Moral education consists only of a series of auditory and visual
sensations, impressed upon the individual by means of advice and
example, which brings it about that it is more especially a moral
instruction, which makes its mark in the intellect, but leaves intact
the seat of the passions and feelings, which are the true motive forces
of the moral conduct. Moral education becomes little by little more
systematic, bases itself more than formerly upon the biological
principle that each organ and function is developed by exercise, and
consequently is improving. The author believes that we must
nevertheless not deceive ourselves into fancying that too much has been
accomplished, so long as the origin and condition of the moral and
immoral germs are unknown. Further, he is of the opinion that the
product of centuries is not to be destroyed in a few years.

In order to prove what has just been said the author cites the
following example, which, according to him, is not uncommon. A family
includes four or five children; all are reared with the greatest care,
each in a different manner according to his character. The result is
that three or four of them become more or less good and industrious
citizens, while one becomes an incorrigible vagabond. This difference
does not depend upon education.

Now it will be asked: is education, then, always and altogether
useless? Here a distinction must be made. There is one small category
of persons who are good and honorable and remain so under all
circumstances, and this exclusively from their organic condition.
Opposed to this is another group who are always bad and show
anti-social instincts. These last are such from an innate organic and
psychic anomaly. Between these two is to be found the very numerous
class of individuals in whom the good and bad qualities are combined.
For this last class education may be of some importance, but
environment is still more so. Hence, in order to lower the number of
occasional criminals, criminal sociology demands “penal substitutes.”
For it is from this intermediate class that criminals are recruited.
However, environment and education are of less importance for this
category than heredity.

The conclusions drawn by the author are, then: first, that a
development of the physiology and psychology of the human passions is
very desirable, in order to improve the means at the disposal of
education; and second, that the opinion of Owen, that education can
make a bad man good, is incorrect.



—In my criticism I shall limit myself to the principal questions. In
the first place I believe that the argument of Professor Ferri, based
on the supposition that scientific socialists believe that “education
is the omnipotent fact”, is futile. For scientific socialists do not
hold this opinion. Owen (who belongs to the Utopists) might be thought
to hold it, though he does not use the word education in the narrow
sense given by Professor Ferri, but it will be very difficult to find
such an opinion in Marx, or Engels, or any of their followers. Although
holding that circumstances have a very great influence upon the
individual, they do not attribute this to the systematic, conscious
influence of one individual upon another, which is what is commonly
meant by education. For the purposes of Professor Ferri’s argument it
may be very useful to make a nice distinction between education and
atmosphere, but this distinction is not therefore justified. The
impressions gained by a child whether from the atmosphere in which he
lives or deliberately impressed upon him by his teacher, are hardly
distinguishable. Just out of class he plays with his comrades, and this
easily makes him forget the moral lessons he has just received. A
mother forbids her child to do a certain thing, and a little later he
sees an older member of the family do with impunity what has been
forbidden in his own case. It is because of this over-nice distinction
that the argument of the author loses much of its value.

In the second place, as the author himself partly admits, the influence
that education may exert cannot be exactly fixed, no matter what
progress pedagogical science may make, for the following reasons. It is
only in school that the scientific pedagogical method is applied, and
plainly in an incomplete and imperfect manner. In order that children
shall be taught and developed they must be well fed and well clothed.
Without this the results will be very small, but pupils insufficiently
fed and clothed are to be counted by thousands. It is also necessary
that a class include as few pupils as possible, in order that the
instructor may not have to divide his attention too much. Yet how many
cases are there where this is found? For these reasons, to which might
be added others, all of an exclusively economic nature, the school does
not contribute as much as it might to moral education. The advantage of
the education given in school over that furnished by the parents
consists in its practical application, at least in part, according to
pedagogical rules. The parents who set themselves to bring up their
children on scientific principles are so few as to be easily counted.
Almost all are novices in this very difficult trade; little attention
is paid to whether parents are ignorant or educated, good or bad,
patient or irascible, capable or incapable, in short, of bringing up
their children. The present organization of society is based upon the
fiction that the person who gives life to a child is also fitted to
bring it up. Further, existing social conditions put many parents,
however capable they might otherwise be, in a position where they
cannot give their children any care, on account of the long
working-day, the labor of married women, etc. These remarks, it seems
to me, are in themselves enough to show that we cannot just now come to
a definite conclusion, that the influence of education may extend to
such and such a point, but no further.

In the third place, it remains to make valid objections to the
principal thesis that forms the foundation of the chapter. Here it is
in brief. There was a time when men lived in anti-social conditions;
all were enemies one of another. This situation lasted for ages until
the social sentiments grew up and civilization developed. But these
anti-social germs having lasted for ages, while the social germs are
only of recent date, it follows that the former are generally much
stronger than the latter. This is why the tendency to evil has
predominated in man, and why crime has such enormous dimensions.

I am of the opinion that this argument is based upon an error. In Part
II of this work I shall attempt to show that the opinion of Professor
Ferri (and other authors), that in the early ages all men were enemies
and animated by anti-social feelings, is false. I shall endeavor also
to show that the present constitution of society does not give rise to
social feelings, but anti-social. Finally it is very problematical
whether the hypothesis the author uses, namely that acquired
characteristics may be inherited, is defensible; the contrary is coming
more and more to be believed. But we cannot in any case admit the
transmission of morality itself by heredity, as Professor Ferri does,
when he speaks of men who remain good under all circumstances, and
consequently of men who must have been born with innate moral
prescriptions. A child is never born with positive knowledge; he is
born with a brain more or less fitted for the reception and development
of knowledge. There was never a child who, from his birth, knew the
rules “thou shalt not steal”, “thou shalt not kill”, etc. But the
organs destined to become the seat of morality differ with each
individual like other organs. When the author says, then, that there
are men who remain good under all circumstances, he says, in effect,
that there are men whose moral organs are very susceptible, and who
consequently remain better than men whose organs are less susceptible.
Therefore the accumulation of anti-social feelings in man of the
present day, through heredity, is imaginary. Finally, Professor Ferri
neglects to note the difference in nature and intensity between the
needs of different men. For this is the cause of the great inequality
of results obtained from the same education given to persons of equal
capacity for receiving moral impressions. If a man has great needs it
takes a much more intense moral effort to keep him from satisfying them
in an immoral manner, than is the case with a man whose needs are
slight.—



The following chapter, “Ambiente e criminalità”, begins with the
assertion of Professor Ferri that the thesis of the socialists
concerning the influence of the social atmosphere upon all the
manifestations of human activity, and consequently upon criminality, is
in great measure correct. The difference between the views of socialism
and of sociology, therefore, is here only a question of limits.

According to the author here is the thesis in question: as soon as the
social revolution or transformation which the socialists desire has
taken place, the social atmosphere will become excellent, and man will
then be morally higher than he is at present. He then examines the
parts of this statement one by one.

First, Professor Ferri gives the classic formula of historic
materialism, set forth by Marx in his “Zur Kritik der politischen
Oekonomie”, taken by the author, however, from Loria’s criticism of the
work of Puviani in the “Rivista critica delle scienze giuridiche e
sociali.” “In the memorable preface to the Kritik der politischen
Oekonomie, published in 1859, Marx sets forth for the first time the
daring theory that all the manifestations of mankind, in the juridic
order as well as in the religious, philosophical, artistic, criminal,
etc., are exclusively determined by economic relations, so that to each
phase of these there corresponds a different form of human
manifestations, as its necessary product.”

Just as in biology the phenomena of nutrition are related to the other
vital phenomena, so is the economic aspect of human activity related to
the other aspects. Economic conditions have, then, a great influence on
the social life, but the author believes it an exaggeration to say that
economic conditions fix it exclusively. Further, in this statement no
attention is paid to the fact that the other phenomena react in their
turn upon the economic conditions, and therefore become determining
factors.

Then it is said that man will be morally better when he finds himself
in a purified atmosphere. This the author admits in part—how far he
admits it will be easily understood by one who knows his opinion with
regard to the physical, individual, and social factors of crime, and
his ideas about education.

Like most of the statements of the socialists, this has, according to
Professor Ferri, the fault of being too simple and consequently too
absolute. Human life is already so complicated (and social life still
more so) that only very little can be explained by simple formulae. It
is easy to say, “Abolish private property and all the cases of theft
will disappear”; “abolish legal marriage, and adultery, uxoricide,
infanticide, and the other crimes against morality will disappear.” But
it is not therefore true. For, even in a communistic society a
born-vagabond, who has a constitutional aversion to work, will commit
thefts just the same. To all this it may be objected that these cases
are pathological, and that these persons should be shut up in an insane
asylum—but in reasoning thus one admits at the same time that such a
society would not yet be an earthly paradise. Further it is pure
metaphysics to believe that social institutions like property and the
family are the consequences of a caprice of man or of a dominant class,
and can therefore be abolished by a stroke of the pen. Everything that
exists, in nature as in society, is the result of causes that are only
the links in an infinite chain. Hence it is impossible to modify
society at a stroke, in accordance with a plan drawn up by a theorist.
This does not mean that every modification of society is excluded; but
the situation predicted by the socialists is so much more beautiful
than the present that it would not be a step, but a leap, forward. And
by their prediction they deny evolution, for they constantly preach to
the proletariat that the whole will be realized in the very near
future.

We come now to the major premise of the socialistic thesis, namely the
social revolution or transformation. The question which Professor Ferri
puts to the socialists in regard to the matter is this: how long will
it take you to realize your projects? There are two answers to be given
according as one believes this realization possible by revolution or by
evolution.

First, that by revolution. Leaving out of consideration the fact that a
revolution could not take place without cruel acts being committed,
with a consequent upsetting of the moral feelings, it must first of all
be asked whether it is easy to bring about a revolution. The author is
of the opinion that Laveleye is perfectly right when he says: “that a
revolution has become an easy thing; that a social evolution is
inevitable; but that a social revolution is impossible, since one
cannot change by force in a single day the economic constitution of
society.”

Neither the word nor the fact of revolution inspires the author with
fear. He recognizes that it may be in the line of evolution, although
it remains an exception and is in fact a pathological manifestation of
evolution. Nevertheless the question arises, what does the revolution
of a day, a month, or even a year signify in comparison with the
evolution that goes on during thousands of years? Does not a revolution
always lead to a reaction? Suppose, however, that this reaction does
not happen; will the whole people have become more moral at a single
shock? What did the great French Revolution accomplish? Much, in
appearance; in reality, little. It follows from what has gone before
that we can modify the environment in a way and with a rapidity that
will seem great to one generation but not at all great to the whole of
humanity.

Now the solution by evolution. As we have already remarked, Professor
Ferri recognizes that criminality will be diminished by an improvement
of the environment. However, since it is impossible to make all at once
general and substantial changes, it is necessary to make every effort
to obtain partial improvements. This is why the positive penal school
defends the doctrine of “penal substitutes.” In his “Il delitto, etc.”,
Turati calls them palliatives; he says that it is impossible to find a
specific remedy for each crime; that there is only one universal
remedy: the equal distribution of wealth, education, and the happiness
coming from love and knowledge, in so far as this will be socially
possible. Professor Ferri thinks that Turati’s objections are not based
upon good reasons, because, first, the theory of penal substitutes is
not limited to the designation of special means of treating special
crimes, but it gives also universal means for all kinds of crimes;
second, the improvements suggested by the author and his adherents have
the great advantage of having been drawn up according to scientific
researches, and of being immediately practicable. How could the desired
transformation ever be reached if the whole system of penal substitutes
were only a useless palliative?

There are only two roads leading to success; that of a violent
revolution—which Turati rejects—and that of successive improvements.
But it is just this which the positive penal school desires, and this
is why the difference between this school and the scientific socialists
has entirely disappeared. However, the error of the socialists is
always that they want to get everything at one blow, and they attach
too little value to what is within reach. There are many socialists who
fear that the bourgeoisie will never give up their privileges without
force, and who consequently have still much sympathy with revolution.
However, this fear is not well founded. For most social improvements
have been made by the dominant class without being compelled by
revolutionary force.

Professor Ferri draws the conclusion that the social environment is
circumscribed by economic conditions for the most part, and that these
have a very great influence upon criminality. The socialists and the
evolutionary sociologists differ, then, in this, that the first believe
they can make themselves useful by protesting and prophesying, while
the others think that it is more practical and more scientific to apply
themselves to partial improvements.



—One cannot read this chapter without being astonished at the decided
tone with which the author declares himself against a theory which he
only knows from what he has heard said about it. The classic formula of
historic materialism is quoted at second hand from a criticism of
Professor Loria upon a work of Puviani, who says that the economic
evolution is in its turn determined by the constant increase of the
population (a theory entirely opposed to that of Marx).

And how the idea of this theory is treated! Let the reader judge for
himself. In the original we read: “In the social production of their
life men enter into fixed, necessary relationships in production,
independent of their will, relationships which correspond to a definite
stage in the development of their material powers of production. The
sum total of these relationships forms the economic structure of
society, the real basis upon which the juristic and political
superstructure is erected, and to which definite forms of social
consciousness correspond. The form of production of the material life
conditions the social, political, and intellectual life-process in
general. It is not the consciousness of mankind that determines their
being, but their social being that determines their consciousness.”
[125] 3

It is unnecessary for us to linger over this point. Professor Loria has
stated the theory inaccurately, and Professor Ferri, who has depended
upon Loria, combats something that Marx never said, and thinks that he
has discovered the further error that account is not taken of the fact
that each cause is in its turn an effect, and vice versa. This too it
is an injustice to impute to the founders of historic materialism.
Engels says upon this subject: “... according to the materialistic
conception of history, production and reproduction of the material life
are, in the last analysis, the determining factors in history. Marx and
I have never claimed more. When the proposition is distorted thus: the
economic factor is the sole determinant, the proposition is transformed
into one devoid of sense, abstract, absurd. The economic situation is
the basis, but the different factors of the superstructure—political
forms of the struggle of the classes and its results—constitutions
imposed by the victorious class after the battle has been won,
etc.—juridical forms, and also the reflections of all these actual
conflicts in the minds of those who have taken part in them, political,
juridical, and philosophical theories, religious conceptions, and their
ulterior development into systems of dogmas, have also their influence
upon the march of the historic struggles, and especially in many cases
determine the form of it. All these factors act the one upon the other,
and finally the economic movement ends necessarily by dominating over
the infinite crowd of chances.... Without this the application of the
theory to any historic period would be easier than the solution of a
simple equation of the second degree.” [126]

Among the reproaches that Professor Ferri throws at the head of the
socialists there is also that they wrongly believe it possible to
change society at a single stroke. The author adds here some
observations upon revolution and evolution. It is necessary to take up
this question, since again Professor Ferri does not correctly represent
the opinions of the Marxists. There is no question that Marx and his
adherents do not suppose that they can change society at a stroke.
Although evolutionists, Marx and his followers call themselves
revolutionists. Many of their adversaries consider this a
contradiction. I think that they are wrong, and that on the contrary
the opposite is true, that every evolutionist in social matters who is
not a revolutionist, has not the courage to support the consequences of
his doctrine. For he who believes that society constantly undergoes
quantitative changes ought to recognize that these must lead in the
long run to a qualitative difference, in which case a revolution has
taken place. The Marxists are consequently at once evolutionists and
revolutionists, since, recognizing that there are continual
quantitative changes, they strive for the total overturning of society
as based upon the capitalistic system, and consequently for the
foundation of the socialistic order. All this relates, then, only to an
economic and social revolution. It follows, then, logically from what
has gone before that the scientific socialists do not aspire primarily
to a political revolution; on the contrary they wish to attain their
ends as far as possible by legal means; as far as possible, which
means, if the ruling classes do not prevent them from obtaining by
legal means what they want. But in the contrary case they do not dread
undertaking even a political revolution as soon as the proletariat
shall be sufficiently prepared and organized. Professor Ferri is
further of the opinion that there is no longer any difference between
the socialists who are at the same time evolutionists, and the
sociologists, since all reach out toward quantitative changes. However,
Professor Ferri forgets to say that the abolition of the private
ownership of the means of production is not one of his “penal
substitutes”, and that there is consequently a fundamental difference,
since socialists advocate only the modifications which accord with the
tendencies of collectivism.

Finally, Professor Ferri is of the opinion that the bourgeoisie will
voluntarily relinquish their privileges, as the ruling classes have
often already done. For this tremendous assertion he does not give any
proofs, and would find it difficult to do so.—



The title of the fifth chapter is: “L’avvenire morale dell’umanità.”
The socialists—so the author begins—believe that there is a great
difference between them and the positivist sociologists, in that the
latter consider crime as an inevitable social evil, while the
socialists see in it only a passing phenomenon. Professor Ferri, on the
contrary, claims that crime, that is, the act which endangers the
conditions of existence, as well as the penalty, the corresponding
reaction, defensive or preventive, both have their roots in the animal
kingdom, and are consequently phenomena more or less inseparable from
humanity. However, this sociological induction is not to be taken in an
absolute, but in this relative sense: first, that in criminality it is
necessary to distinguish two divisions, of which the one is determined
by the normal saturation, and the second by the abnormal
super-saturation; second, that the author and his adherents do not
understand by the “absolute necessity” of crime that crime will always
exist, but only that it will exist in the immediate future (19th and
20th centuries), and that they retain this expression because they
regard it as useless and impossible to make predictions concerning
times more remote than this.

With regard to future morality Professor Ferri considers in this
chapter the two following socialistic theses:

I. The struggle for existence which has hitherto reigned among men,
will find no place in the socialistic society.

II. In the socialistic society, egoism, which has been the basis of the
moral and social life, will have to give place to altruism.

First, then, the question of the permanence of the struggle for
existence. Professor Ferri cites here the opinions of Labusquière
(“Rivista internazionale del socialismo,” 1880) and of Professor Loria
(“Discorso sur Carlo Darwin,” 1882). Abridged, Labusquière says as
follows: Is the struggle for existence, an integral part of the
evolution of animals, also a “conditio sine qua non” of the development
of humanity? No, since it prevents the total development by putting the
majority of men in a most precarious situation. We cannot picture man
as living all alone. He has always lived and will always live in a
society. This demands a certain solidarity, without which a society is
not imaginable. We cannot admit, then, the necessity of a continual
struggle—at least we cannot admit the necessity, on the part of some,
of receiving the fruits of the labor of others. The struggle for
existence is necessary among animals, since they are not able to
produce, and consequently must live upon such fruits as nature gives.
But man can produce, and the productive forces increase just as men
support one another more.

The opinion of Professor Loria is summed up as follows: the thesis that
the Darwinian theory is entirely applicable to political economy is
false. It is said that it justifies social inequality; nature being
aristocratic, in society also the aristocracy occupies the place that
belongs to it. According to Professor Loria this argument is as without
sense as the argument that, since nature is a murderess, murder is
justifiable. The view in question is not a legitimate conclusion from
the theory as advanced by Darwin, but is simply a false interpretation
made by some of his followers. There are no reasons why this struggle
should always exist, but we are quite justified in supposing that it
will disappear, having been but a transitory stage. For as long as
egoism was the sole human motive, the struggle for existence was a
necessary condition of initiative and progress. But altruism is more
and more developing, and it is not Utopian to believe that some day man
will reach out after physical and moral perfection, not with the aim of
conquering his less-favored fellows, but with the higher aim of
self-development. We forget too much how different is the struggle for
existence among animals and among men. While in nature it is the
strongest, hardiest, and most skilful who come out of the contest
victorious, and consequently survive, in the present contest it is not
the best (the workers and the capitalists who introduce improved
methods of work), but those who are enriched by the labor of others,
who are the conquerors. In the social struggle we perceive three
phenomena which do not appear in the struggle in nature: military
selection (which is an obstacle to the perfection of the human race);
sexual selection (in which not strength and beauty, but money and
class-prejudice determine the choice); and the economic system (which
by the accumulation of capital in the hands of a few, forces the
workers to lead a life that exhausts them, and is the reason why the
ill-nourished classes form the majority). This is why the results of
the struggle for existence are so different for man from those of the
combat in nature.

Professor Ferri makes the following objections to what has been said
above: In treating questions like these it is necessary not to confuse
two theories, that of Spencer and that of Darwin. For the latter is
connected with the former as a part with the whole. Darwinism is
expressed in the law of natural selection, while the theory of Spencer
is that of evolution, a law which rules not only the animal and human
world, but also the whole knowable universe.

After this introductory observation he attacks the theses that
Labusquière and Loria have developed. The great error committed by
Labusquière and by most of the socialists is their failing to grasp the
idea of the continuity and naturalness of social phenomena. There
results in such cases an erroneous distinction between societies of man
and those of animals; hence they do not see that the combat, proved as
always existing in the case of animals and men as well, is a natural
law. And then Labusquière and his followers forget that while the
sociologists explain this combat, that is not at all saying that they
justify it. In any case the assertion of the socialists that it will be
possible to make this combat cease at once, after only a very brief
delay, is false. As to the question of knowing whether it will ever
cease, this will be examined later.

Then Professor Ferri remarks that we must not confuse the principle of
a natural law with its manifestations. In the case in question this
would be saying that in recognizing that the struggle for existence is
a law which rules in the animal kingdom and among men, it is necessary
also to think that the forms of the combat have been, and remain, the
same. The author believes, for example, that it would be desirable to
mitigate the present economic combat and to carry it to a higher plane,
without therefore being an adherent of the maxim, “each one according
to his needs”, the application of which would ruin the human race
entirely.

In criticising the law of the struggle for existence, we very often
forget that it does not stand alone, but that there is another beside
it, which in the long run levels all the inequalities produced by this
conflict. We see thus that individuals, families, and races raise
themselves above the general plane, reach the maximum of power, wealth,
and intelligence, to fall again below the average.

We cannot admit that the struggle for existence, which is a principle
of life, and the cause of human and animal evolution, will disappear
some day because men, animated by humanitarian ideas, ardently desire
it. The opinion that in the course of time this struggle is becoming
and will become less and less violent and brutal, is scientifically
more correct and humanitarian as well. It may be that after centuries
and centuries a day will come when every individual will have his
material existence assured. But the struggle for moral existence will
not yet disappear on that account. For every need satisfied causes in
its turn new needs to spring up, and rekindles the conflict. The
socialists evince great one-sidedness in understanding by the struggle
for existence only the struggle for food, forgetting that there is a
struggle in every sphere.

It is claimed that there is a great difference between the struggle for
existence among men and that among animals, and that consequently the
results differ; that in the animal kingdom it is the strongest who
remain victorious, while among men it is only a small minority of the
weaker and less industrious who rule over the majority making up the
ill-nourished classes. According to Professor Ferri this opinion also
is incorrect; otherwise the consequences of the conflict would have a
result entirely contrary to that in the animal kingdom; the human race
would deteriorate instead of advancing. And the facts prove that the
human race has made progress, organic, mental, social, and economic.
The survival of the weaker, the less industrious, is only partial and
apparent. Malon says that in our present society it is not those who
are individually superior who conquer, but those who have the exclusive
disposition of the social forces. But how have these forces fallen into
the hands of these few? Only because in this phase of human evolution,
they were the stronger, the best fitted. It is forgotten that there is
not only a struggle between classes, but also between individuals, and
that, by the greater and greater increase of altruism it is also the
more altruistic workmen and employers who conquer. For an altruistic
workman, who works with zeal and has his employer’s interests at heart,
and an altruistic employer who treats his employes well, will be more
able to maintain themselves than those who act differently. It is only
in appearance, then, that the less strong and industrious
property-owners are the victors; if this were the case it would soon
cease to be so.

The conclusion of the author, then, is that the struggle for existence,
which is a normal aspect of honorable activity, and an abnormal aspect
in criminal activity, is the supreme law of the human race in the past
and in the present, and consequently in the future; but this struggle
will be carried on by means less and less rude and bloody.



The second part of the chapter treats of egoism and altruism. The
individual, considered as such, is only egoistic; but considered as a
member of a community he is also altruistic. We must therefore
interpret the subject in the following manner: that a gradual evolution
is taking place from egoism to altruism, between which, accordingly, is
found ego-altruism.

There are now two questions that must be answered, first, will man ever
come to be purely altruistic? second, if so, how long will it take to
bring it about?

According to the author every evolutionist must answer affirmatively to
the first question (at least if we exclude the absolute form in which
it is put by many socialists, namely that egoism will disappear
entirely), for the slow and continual evolution of morality teaches us
that egoism is always decreasing and altruism increasing. But how much
time is needed to realize this moral paradise? The answers made to this
question by the socialists and by the sociologists differ greatly. The
former are of the opinion that this will be possible almost
immediately, or at least in a little while, while the latter think that
it is impossible that it should take place so quickly. Since the author
has busied himself in the preceding chapters with the influence of
education upon morality he limits himself now to treating the question,
how much time is needed for this moral progress?

According to Professor Ferri we do not properly grasp this question if
we do not recognize that the evolution of morals has progressed but
very slowly during the past centuries. Doubtless much has been
accomplished, but not enough to justify the prediction of the
socialists. Soury is quite right when he says: “we deceive ourselves
greatly if we think that the man of the present day differs much from
the man of antiquity, from the barbarian, and the savage.” When we
examine the period of barbarism we see that homicide, cannibalism, and
theft form the greater part of the criminality, while the first two are
not often punished by the tribe, or are even obligatory. Impetuosity of
the passions, ferocity, insensibility to pain in self or others,
disloyalty, implacable revenge, improvidence, and superstition form the
principal part of the moral life. All these traits still exist, though
less strongly than formerly, in the man of the present, and especially
in the individual born in the lower classes. Except in pathological
cases cannibalism no longer appears in the civilized world, but this
does not make it impossible that it would reappear in time of great
famine. However, the high moral qualities which present-day man can
show, are also to be found among savages, only with gradual
differences. [127] The number of honorable and moral persons has
increased relatively, which makes it certain that in the future
morality will rise higher than at present, but this will not take place
quickly, but very slowly, like all the other changes that have taken
place.

It is therefore impossible that the predictions of the socialists
should come true in a short time, and that crime, poverty, ignorance,
and immorality should disappear as soon as society is transformed and
revolutionized. It will only be the sublime end toward which the human
race must always aspire.



—In order to avoid repetitions I will make no criticism of this
chapter, since I should have to refute almost all the theses here laid
down, but will treat of the questions of the struggle for existence,
and egoism and altruism, in Part II of this work.—



In his “Conclusione” [128] Professor Ferri compares society to a sick
person at whose bedside there meet three friends of his, who all wish
him well. The first declares confidently that the soul dominates the
body and that consequently material remedies are of no avail. The
second says, on the contrary, that it is only a total change of the
environment in which he is living that can cure the invalid. The third
also believes that modifications are necessary, but he contents himself
with partial improvements, though the second friend calls them only
palliatives. The first is the spiritualist, [129] the second the
socialist, and the third the sociologist.



—Having given my opinion after each chapter, a general criticism of
“Socialismo e Criminalità” is superfluous. The impression that the book
makes is strange. The author attacks the socialists as “excessively
anti-scientific and sentimental”, while he vaunts the “great scientific
character of the sociologists.” Yet these last, notwithstanding their
great scientific character, combat a doctrine which they know only in
part or not at all. Scientific socialism is left out of the discussion.

The best proof of the weakness of his attack against socialism is to be
found in the fact that the author has for several years ranked himself
among the socialists, of whom he has become one of the most fervent and
intelligent chiefs.

As regards his opinion on the criminal question Professor Ferri has
made no change, or almost none. [130]—




IV.

H. KURELLA.

This author gives some pages of his “Naturgeschichte des Verbrechers”
to the subject we have in hand. What he says may be summed up as
follows.

The attempts to draw parallels between the fluctuations of the price of
grain and those of the figures for criminality, according to the
author, prove nothing, inasmuch as it is impossible to compare them
with the statistics of wages and of forced unemployment. In fact any
one who tries to show in this way the correlation between criminality
and economic conditions, begs the question, that poverty is the
principal cause of crime. Further, the hypothesis that the regularity
with which human acts occur is fixed by the condition of the society in
which they take place, is little by little giving way. From personal
examinations, and from the information given by Ferri and von Oettingen
(this proves that the literature of our subject is little known to the
author) Dr. Kurella thinks he can draw the conclusion that insufficient
food, caused by scarcity or low wages, does not cause the commission of
crimes. Malnutrition may perhaps influence criminality indirectly; that
is it may cause degeneration after some successive generations, which
in its turn predisposes to crime.

A priori it is incontestable that we cannot picture to ourselves a
society, if established by the socialists, [131] in which cupidity,
hatred, and the instinct of the oppressor, the principal motives of
crime, will have been annihilated or deprived of their influence
because of social institutions. Nevertheless it is of importance that
Morrison, Garofalo, and Ferri [132] have, according to the author,
shown that poverty is not a factor of crime. At the International
Congress of Criminal Anthropology at Brussels, the attempt was made to
defend the contrary, but, according to Dr. Kurella, without success.
(According to him it can only be in case of being suddenly thrown out
of work that a person hitherto honest commits a crime from indigence.)

The necessity of the moment being consequently only rarely a cause of
criminality, not only do the present social anomalies produce an
increase of degeneracy, as has been said above, but also there are a
number of persons who live in badly built and unsanitary dwellings, so
that the family life is injured, and the development of feelings of
honesty, modesty, etc., is interfered with. And it is also the social
anomalies that strongly influence alcoholism, which is one of the
important factors of crime.

The author draws the following conclusion: “As little as a change of
environmental conditions can change an individual of one kind
immediately into an individual of another kind, as little as we ever,
under however modified circumstances, see a chimpanzee change himself
into a gorilla, so little do social factors change a normally endowed
man into a criminal. In isolated cases it may appear as if passion or
opportunity had caused a crime; social forces do indeed have their
effect upon the individual, but they do not essentially change his
fundamental attributes—which include his character; the slight
modifications through environment that individuals experience, must
constantly recur, heap themselves up in the course of generations,
until a socially significant change of type has arisen. Accordingly it
is the permanent social distresses, the chronic evils of society which
influence criminality, because by unnoticeable influences they go on
for generations gnawing at the inmost kernel of man; misery and
intellectual and moral neglect must be as long continued as in the
Papal States, in the Kingdom of Naples, in Ireland, and among the
Poles, drained by the territorial nobility for centuries, before an
entire people becomes inoculated with the ‘penchant for crime.’” [133]



—I will refrain from making any criticism. One does not argue with a
man who gives convincing proofs that even the meaning of criminal
sociology is unknown to him. Assertions, for example, that the
character of man is invariable, that the distance between the honest
man and the dishonest man is as great as that between the chimpanzee
and the gorilla, are only absurdities. What author will deny at this
time that the differences between men are, in the last analysis, only
quantitative?

In general, Dr. Kurella still shares the opinions of the Italian school
(cf., for example, “Anthropologie und Strafrecht”, which appeared in
1912); nevertheless he should have recognized, when he wrote “die
Naturgeschichte des Verbrechers”, that he was not familiar with the
social factors of crime. He has written the following remarkable words,
which do him honor. “I do not hesitate to confess that deeper
socio-political studies, which became possible to me only after the
publication of that work [“Naturgeschichte des Verbrechers”] show me
today the social factors of crime more plainly and sharply, than I was
able to recognize them ten years ago” (Vorrede, “Zurechnungsfähigkeit,
Kriminalanthropologie”).—




V.

E. FORNASARI DI VERCE. [134]

In the first chapter (on poverty and criminality in Italy) the author
calls attention to the following facts. According to the statistics of
1881 there were in Italy to the thousand (of both sexes over nine years
of age) 390.66 persons who were rich, well-to-do, moderately well-off,
or with enough to live on, and 609.34 who had scarcely the necessities
of life. Out of 100 persons convicted there were:


         1887    1888    1889

        56.34   57.45   56.00   Necessitous
        22.99   30.77   32.15   Having only the bare necessities
        11.54    9.98   10.13   Moderately well-off
         2.13    1.80    1.72   Well-to-do or rich


Here the favorable influence of means comes out distinctly. For 40% of
the population had some means and 60% were in need; but among those
convicted there were 13% with means and nearly 87% who were poor.

Then the author gives a sketch of the influence of poverty in causing
degeneracy among the proletariat and predisposing them to crime, for
poverty is very destructive to men’s mental faculties. He cites in
support of this many authors of weight.

By comparing the different Italian districts, grouped about the average
figure for wealth per capita, with the number of prisoners to the
100,000 of the population, grouped according to the place from which
they came, the following result is obtained.


          Wealth.                     Prisoners according to the
                                      Place from which they Came.

(3.333) Latium.                VII          --
          --                   VI           --
          --                   V            --
(2.746) Piedmont-Liguria.      IV           --
                                      { Lombardy (43)
(2.400) Lombardy.              III    { Piedmont-Liguria (51)
                                      { Venice (53)
          --                   II       Tuscany (76)
(2.164) Tuscany.               I        Emilia (95)
(1.935) Venice,            }          {
(1.876) Kingdom.           } Average. { Kingdom (118)
(1.762) Emilia.            }          {
         --                   1st       Marches-Umbria (137)
(1.471) Sicily.            }   2d     {
(1.333) Naples             }          { Sardinia (167)
(1.227) Marches-Umbria         3d       Naples (173)
(?)     Sardinia               4th          --
                               5th      Sicily (212)
                               6th          --
                               7th      Latium (250)


According to the author this table shows that wealth and criminality
present a certain symmetry, to this extent, that the wealthy regions
have in general a lower criminality than the poor ones. It is only
Latium that forms an exception, which is explained, according to Dr.
Fornasari di Verce, first, by the circumstance that the capital is
situated in that district, second, by the climate, and third, chiefly
by the fact that the absolute wealth of a country gives no indication
of the distribution of wealth. We can properly expect to find that
where great wealth is heaped up there will also be considerable
pauperism.

Not only does poverty predispose to crime, but it also furnishes the
motives for it. Leading to alcoholism it is the cause of violent
crimes; it drives persons who cannot find work to vagrancy and
mendicity, which in their turn are the preparatory school for greater
crimes; it puts the great number of those who cannot provide honestly
for their needs to the necessity of stealing. And when these factors
act upon a man already predisposed, they even lead as far as homicide.

In the following table the different Italian districts, as well as the
crimes committed, have been grouped about their average figures.


          Wealth.                    Crimes.

(3.333) Latium              VII        --
        --                  VI         --
        --                  V          --
(2.747) Piedmont-Liguria    IV         --
(2.400) Lombardy            III        --
        --                  II         --
                       }          { Lombardy (649)
                       }          { Tuscany (710)
(2.164) Tuscany        }    I     { Piedmont-Liguria (732)
                       }          { Emilia (749)
                       }          { Marches-Umbria (774)
(1.935) Venice         }          { Venice (857)
(1.876) Kingdom        } Average. { Kingdom (926)
(1.762) Emilia         }          { Sicily (1021)
        --                 1st      Naples (1150)
(1.471) Sicily         }          {
(1.333) Naples         }    2d    { Sardinia (1440)
(1.227) Marches-Umbria      3d      --
        Sardinia            4th     Latium (1797)


According to the author it appears from this table that, with the
exception of Latium, the districts with wealth above the average have a
number of crimes below the average. Nevertheless the regions with a
figure for wealth above the average, i.e. Piedmont-Liguria, Lombardy,
and Latium, show a greater number of crimes than one would expect,
while Sicily, Naples, Marches-Umbria, and Sardinia show lower figures
for crime than would be supposed. This contradiction is only apparent,
according to the author, and is to be explained as follows: first,
because where there is wealth there is also poverty and frequent
opportunities to steal; second, because dangerous individuals migrate
less to districts where there is less wealth; third, because, as John
Stuart Mill says, it results from the social conditions of our day that
the education of the poor is nil and that of the rich bad.

The second chapter, having as its title, “Il fattore economico e la
delinquenza.—Dinamica”, contains some data upon the trend of
criminality in the period in question. Criminality in general is
increasing; serious crimes remain nearly stationary, while less serious
crimes increase. As Ferri observes, criminality is decreasing, even in
Italy, as to its intensity and violence, but increasing as to its
extent.

Finally, the author considers the influence of emigration. It is
chiefly the crimes against property that feel the favorable effects of
it, as murder does among crimes against persons. The cause of this
favorable influence is easily explained. Emigration removes a number of
persons who, not having the means of existence, would easily become
criminals.

The consequences of agricultural vicissitudes are as follows: the years
of abundant harvests show a decrease in criminality, bad years, on the
contrary, an increase; good vintages, however, lead to the same result.
It is chiefly crimes against property (especially rural thefts) that
yield to the influence of the degree of the abundance of the harvest;
while among crimes against persons it is principally assaults that show
the effect of the character of the crops. It is plain that the
agricultural class is that which especially shows the effect of a bad
harvest. During the years 1887–1889 the proportion of the farming class
among those convicted rose from 35.3% to 37.8% and 38.2%.

The effect of the fluctuation of the price of food is the following:
criminality in general shows the influence of it greatly. When prices
fall crime diminishes, and vice versa. This is more clearly to be seen
in crimes against property. Crimes against persons increase especially
when the price of wine is low, and vice versa. When a fall in the price
of food coincides with a fall in the price of wine, the increase of
crimes against persons is great.

According to Dr. Fornasari di Verce the cause of the increase of crimes
against persons in the case of low food prices is not to be found in
the improved nutrition that results, but in the greater consumption of
alcohol. The other crimes feel the effect of the fluctuations in the
price of provisions less.

The author then takes up manufacturing. (As a consequence of the
defectiveness of the official statistics the data are incomplete.)
During the period of which the author speaks, manufacturing increased
enormously, and crime in general increased also. The serious forms,
however, decreased while the less serious ones increased. Industrial
crises bring an increase chiefly of crimes against persons.

The condition of the working-people. According to the author it would
be of the highest importance to establish for each year the number of
industrial workers. For this has a greater importance for criminality
than the price of food or the rate of wages. In default of official
data such an investigation cannot take place, and he has to limit
himself to an examination of wages. With some few exceptions these
wages increased about 35% during the period 1873–1889. However, to
obtain a clearer picture of the condition of the working-class, the
author has combined the fluctuation of wages with those of the price of
grain; that is, he has made a calculation of the number of hours each
man has had to work to get 100 kilograms of grain.

After having called attention to the fact that the average wage of the
Italian workman is lower than in other industrial countries, the author
gives the following results of his researches: the influence of the
fluctuation of wages upon crime in general is less than, and almost
always subordinated to, that of the fluctuation of food-prices.
However, it must not be forgotten here that wages do not always
represent exactly the condition of the majority of the proletariat.
With some few exceptions, all crimes against property decrease when
wages rise (in combination with the price of grain). This influence is
not noted in commercial crimes and counterfeiting. Crimes against
persons increase a little when wages rise; but when this rise coincides
with a low price of wine, they increase considerably.

The influence of strikes is exclusively limited to the crime of
rebellion.

From the investigation into criminality and commercial occurrences we
learn that fraudulent bankruptcy, and also forgery in great measure,
are almost entirely independent of economic occurrences; and the
fluctuations of the number of commercial crimes, in so far as they are
not influenced by other economic facts, are explained in great part by
commercial occurrences.

Financial occurrences (credit and deposits) do not make themselves felt
in criminality in general, but in crimes against property and
commercial crimes.

The author concludes finally from the increase shown by private
fortunes and the rise in wages, that there is a correlation of these
phenomena with a decrease of certain serious forms of crime.

The results of the study are summarized in the following table:


        {                    {            {             { a. Thefts of all kinds.
        {                    {            {             { b. Embezzlement, cheating, and other frauds.
        {                    {            { Much.       { c. Crimes against property (coming before the magistrate).[#]
        {                    {            {             { d. Commercial crimes.[#]
        {                    {            {
        {                    {            {             { e. Blackmail, extortion, and robbery.
        {                    {            { Moderately. { f. Crimes against the order of the family.
        { Subject to the     { Inversely. {             { g. Crimes against persons (coming before the magistrate).
        { Influence of       {            {
CRIMES. { Economic           {            {             { h. Crimes against the public order.
        { Occurrences and    {            { Little.     { i. Crimes against the public administration.[#]
        { varying with Them. {            {             { j. Forgery and counterfeiting.
        {                    {            {
        {                    {            { Crimes over { I. Assault and extortion (with homicide).
        {                    {            { which the   { II. Rebellion, and violence to the public authorities.
        {                    {            { Influence
        {                    {              of
        {                    {            { Alcohol is  { III. Homicide of every kind.
        {                    { Directly.  { Predominant.{ IV. Assaults and intentional injuries.
        {                    {            {               -- Sexual crimes.
        {
        {                                 { Hardly      { k. Attacks upon the safety of the state.
        { Outside of the                  { at All.     { l. Perjury, etc.
        { Influence of                    {
        { Economic                        {             { m. Fraudulent bankruptcy.
        { Occurrences.                    { Not at All. { n. Insults, and defamation of character.
        {                                 {             { o. Crimes against religion.
        {                                 {             { p. Arson and malicious mischief.


According to the author it follows from his investigation, that the
economic factors fill a very important place in the etiology of crime,
but that all crime is not to be explained by that means. He is of the
opinion that if we are to combat crime effectively we must make use of
the “penal substitutes” recommended by Professor Ferri.



The author treats the influence of economic occurrences upon
criminality in Great Britain and Ireland in the same way. Here are his
results:


              {                       {            { Much.       { Crimes against property without violence.
              {                       {            {
              {                       {            { Moderately. { Crimes against property with violence.
              {                       { Inversely. {
              { Subject to the        {            {         { Crimes against property with premeditated destruction.
              { Influence of          {            { Little. { Crimes other than those named above and those
CRIMES AND    { Economic Occurrences  {            {         { against persons and against the currency.
MISDEMEANORS. { and varying with      {
              { Them.                 {            { Crimes over which       {
              {                       { Directly.  { the Influence of        { Crimes against persons.
              {                       {            { Alcohol is Predominant. {
              {
              { Not subject to                     { Not at All.    { Misdemeanors and contraventions.
              { the Influence of                   {
              { Economic Occurrences.              { Only Slightly. { Forgery and counterfeiting.


His investigation gives the following results for New South Wales:


              {                              {            {        { 1. Theft and receiving stolen goods.
              { Subject to the Influence of  { Inversely. { Much.  { 2. Petty larceny.
              {  Economic Occurrences        {            {        { 3. Horse-stealing.
              { and varying with Them.       {            {             { 4. Minor offenses against property.
              {                              {            { Moderately. { 5. Domiciliary thefts.
CRIMES AND    {                              {            {             { 6. Sheep-stealing.
MISDEMEANORS. {                              {            {             { 7. Forgery.
              {                              {            { Little. { 8. Cattle-stealing.
              {                              {            {
              {                              {            { Crimes and          { 9. Murder.
              {                              {            { Misdemeanors over   { 10. Arson.
              {                              {            { which the Influence { 11. Homicide.
              {                              {            { of Alcohol          { 12. Assaults.
              {                              {            { is Predominant.     { 13. Extortion.
              {                              {            {                     { 14. Robbery.
              {                              {            {                     { 15. Other minor offenses.
              {                              { Directly.  {                     { I. Offenses against public decency.
              {                              {            {                     { II. Offenses against morals (homosexuality).
              {                              {            {                     { III. Offenses against morals.
              {                              {            {                     { IV. Minor offenses against persons.
              {
              { Not subject to the Influence                                    { A. Blackmail and cheating.
              { of Economic Occurrences.                                        { B. Perjury.


—It is incontestable that the researches of Dr. Fornasari di Verce must
be placed in the front rank of the works that show the correctness of
the thesis that the economic factors are the most important factors of
criminality. An objection may be made, however, that the question has
been conceived in too mechanical a fashion, in consequence of the
exclusive use of the statistical method. He seeks the correlation
between criminality and each economic phenomenon separately, in place
of that of the ensemble of these phenomena. For the economic life does
not exist in reality as separated and isolated parts, but forms a great
whole, a compact mass, of which the parts fit in together. When an
important economic occurrence takes place, in case the expected effect
upon crime is not observed, we must not be too quick to say that it has
no importance for criminality, for it may be that it is neutralized by
something else.

With this remark is connected a final objection. The author has not
proved the truth of his conclusion that criminality cannot be explained
exclusively by means of economic conditions. For, although his
researches include very important economic factors, the author leaves
out many economic factors and, with one exception (the degenerating
influence of poverty), the numerous consequences of economic
conditions, which are of the highest importance for the question in
hand. In other words the author has not called attention to the fact
that we live under an economic system of a comparatively recent date,
having peculiar characteristics that are of great significance for
criminality. He has indicated some very important consequences of the
system, but he has not analyzed the system itself.

I am of the opinion that the work that I have been treating, and which
has a great value for the subject, shows that economic conditions are
of great importance for criminality. However, it does not prove that
this influence is not greater than is shown by statistics.—




VI.

A. NICEFORO.

In the first part of his study, “Criminalità e condizioni economiche in
Sicilia”, the author calls attention to the fact that Sicily is one of
the Italian districts where crime is greatest and is increasing most
rapidly. One could draw upon the map lines enclosing a definite
criminal zone, taking in the provinces of Caltanissetta, Girgenti, and
Catania. This zone might, in its turn, be divided into two others, one
of which would give a high figure for robberies and homicides, and the
other chiefly for crimes against property and against morals.

The author divides the economic causes into direct and indirect. In
speaking of direct factors he treats successively:

a. Large real-estate holdings. The landed proprietor rents his lands to
the “gabelletto”, who in turn sublets them to the laborers. This system
exhausts the latter. The proprietor rids himself of all expense by
charging it to the “gabelletto”, and makes his profit; the “gabelletto”
does the same by the laborer and makes his profit. The latter is always
the person that suffers. Then the “gabelletto” advances the necessary
provisions to the laborer until the harvest comes in; but since he does
so at a high rate, the laborer is bowed down by the burden of his
debts. In consequence of this system the agricultural population is
ill-nourished and degenerate. The consequences of this system as it
affects criminality are apparent. In the province of Caltanissetta,
where large land-holdings are the rule, crimes against property, and
especially rural thefts, cattle-stealing, vagrancy, etc., are the most
numerous.

b. Small holdings. However, it is not only the agricultural population
dependent upon great property-holders that lives in poverty, for the
small farmers also have a hard life. They raise chiefly grapes and
citrous fruits. The price of citrous fruits has fallen greatly through
overproduction and foreign competition. Wine also has gone down in
price, and the cultivators have had enormous losses from phylloxera
besides. Consequently the small farmers are crushed with debts;
failures are the order of the day; their situation, then, is most
unfortunate. But that of the non-property-holders is still worse if
possible. For the small holder also often rents his land to others, and
from this follows a kind of “sweating-system.”

At the end of these observations the author gives, in the following
table, the movement of some prices in relation to criminality:


========+===========+=============+===========+=============+============
        | Price of  |  Price of   | Price of  |             | Robberies,
 Years. | Wheat per |  Wine per   | Meat per  |  Homicides  | Extortion,
        |   1000    | Hectolitre. |   Kilo.   | Prosecuted. | Blackmail.
        |  Kilos.   |  (Sicily.)  | (Sicily.) |             |
--------+-----------+-------------+-----------+-------------+------------
  1875  |   27.42   |    13.00    |    3.09   |      --     |     658
  1876  |   28.78   |    21.62    |    2.91   |      --     |   1,039
  1877  |   33.66   |    30.38    |    2.98   |      --     |     777
  1878  |   31.43   |    29.04    |    2.89   |      --     |   1,110
  1879  |   31.35   |    19.03    |    2.80   |      --     |   1,138
  1880  |   32.27   |    29.65    |    2.74   |    1,063    |     829
  1881  |   26.36   |    30.92    |    2.74   |    1,001    |     708
  1882  |   20.42   |    28.35    |    2.80   |      938    |     560
  1883  |   23.11   |    22.11    |    2.75   |      943    |     419
  1884  |   21.52   |    17.95    |    2.77   |      949    |     340
  1885  |   21.24   |    31.84    |    2.76   |      822    |     330
  1886  |   21.28   |    35.63    |    2.42   |      859    |     418
  1887  |   21.48   |    15.66    |    2.44   |      863    |     446
  1888  |   21.50   |    11.85    |    2.46   |      899    |     485
  1889  |   22.83   |    15.06    |    2.40   |      865    |     478
  1890  |   22.63   |    22.07    |    2.46   |      869    |     547
  1891  |   24.60   |    16.92    |    2.77   |      966    |     710
  1892  |   24.32   |    14.32    |    2.87   |    1,117    |     677
  1893  |   21.08   |    15.76    |    2.95   |    1,066    |     902
  1894  |   18.77   |    18.38    |    2.98   |      --     |     --
  1895  |   20.30   |    18.42    |    2.75   |      --     |     --
========+===========+=============+===========+=============+============


c. The mining zone. The production of sulphur, formerly of great
importance, when Sicily was the principal source of supply for Europe
and America, has decreased greatly now that sulphur is manufactured
from chemical products. The condition of the miners is pitiful. The
mines are often exploited by middle-men, which makes the condition of
the laborers worse. Degeneracy has consequently taken on enormous
proportions. When we compare the change in wages with the number of
thefts, we see that thefts decrease when wages rise, and vice versa,
and that the price of grain also influences criminality. It is the
provinces of Sicily where the sulphur mines are found that give the
highest figures for criminality in general, and homicide in particular.

d. The class-conflict. The property owners, whose economic position is
already very influential, also control the political forces, and
consequently the case of those who have nothing is made much worse.
Taxes, indirect for the most part, weigh most heavily upon the poor;
public property is exploited for the benefit of the rich, etc., etc.
Hence it follows that in the districts where the non-possessors are
unconsciously struggling against the possessors, this strife of classes
engenders class-hatred, and consequent crimes.

In the last part of his study the author speaks of indirect economic
factors, among which he includes:

a. The increasing decline in the altruistic feelings. The miner and the
laborer, both ill-nourished, humiliated, and despised, dwelling in
miserable hovels, are pariahs far removed from any feeling for their
fellow men.

b. Organic degeneracy. As a consequence of the economic conditions
named, degeneracy is always increasing more and more among the poor,
especially among the miners. This degeneracy becomes in its turn a
factor of criminality, since it predisposes individuals to crime.


See also: Virgilio Rossi: “Influence de la température et de
l’alimentation sur la criminalité en Italie, de 1875 à 1883” (“Rapport
Ier Congrès d’Anthropologie Criminelle. Actes”, pp. 295 ff.); N.
Pinsero: “Miseria e Delitto” (“Scuola Positiva”, 1898).








CHAPTER IV.

THE FRENCH SCHOOL (THE SCHOOL OF THE ENVIRONMENT).


I.

A. LACASSAGNE.

While the Italian school reigned supreme at the first congress of
criminal anthropology at Rome, Professor Lacassagne opposed it with his
so-called “hypothesis of the environment” in the following terms: “The
important thing is the social environment. Allow me to make a
comparison borrowed from a modern theory. The social environment is the
bouillon for the culture of criminality; the microbe, that is the
criminal, is an element which is only of importance when it has found a
medium in which it can grow.

“The criminal with anthropometric and other characteristics seems to us
to have only a moderate importance. All these characteristics may be
found elsewhere among honest men.

“But you should look at the different social consequences of these two
points of view. On the one hand is the fatalism which flows inevitably
from the anthropometric theory; and on the other, social initiative. If
the social environment is everything, and if it is so defective as to
favor the growth of vicious or criminal natures, it is to this
environment and its conditions of functioning that our reforms must be
directed.

“... This phrase ... sums up my whole thought, and is, so to speak, the
conclusion of what I have been saying; societies have the criminals
they deserve.” [138]

In his “Marche de la criminalité en France, 1825–1880”, the author
points out, among other things, the connection between criminality and
economic conditions. An examination of the movement of crimes against
property shows that the great fluctuations to be observed there are
intimately connected with economic conditions. The number of crimes
against property corresponds almost exactly with the fluctuation in the
price of wheat; and all the economic crises make their influence felt.

During the years 1828, 1835–1837, 1847, 1848–1854, 1865–1868, and
1872–1876, in which the price of wheat was high, there were also a
great number of crimes against property. The year 1855 was the sole
exception, for then crimes against property did not increase, although
the price of grain was very high. This is to be explained by the fact
that the government then took measures to lessen the consequences of
this calamity. Further, other provisions were then very cheap. From
1860 on the number of crimes against property decreases, which,
according to the author, is to be explained by the importation of
grain, which increased greatly at this time.

The influence of the production and consumption of alcohol is strongly
felt in crimes against persons, especially in assaults.

I would further call attention to the report made by Professor
Lacassagne to the Fourth Congress of Criminal Anthropology at Geneva,
entitled, “Les vols à l’étalage et dans les grands magasins”, in which
he shows how the display of goods on the counters in the great bazaars,
which are meant to fascinate visitors, and force them to buy, so to
speak, leads to crime in individuals predisposed to kleptomania.

Professor Lacassagne has always remained faithful to the judgment that
he pronounced at Rome; at the Congress at Brussels, [139] and at
Amsterdam as well [140], he repeated: “Societies have the criminals
they deserve.”




II.

G. TARDE.

This author considers criminality as being preëminently a social
phenomenon, which, like all social phenomena, is to be explained by
imitation.

“All the important acts of the social life are performed under the sway
of example. One begets, or one does not beget, through imitation; the
statistics of births have shown us that. One kills, or one does not
kill, through imitation; should we have the idea today of fighting a
duel, or declaring war, if we did not know that this is always done in
the country where we live? One kills himself, or he does not kill
himself, through imitation; it is recognized that suicide is an
imitative phenomenon in the highest degree.... How can we doubt, then,
that a man steals or does not steal, murders or does not murder,
through imitation?” [141]

Imitation, says the author, is governed by two laws, namely, that men
imitate one another more the more closely they come together, and that
imitation of the high by the low is what most often takes place (that
the customs of the nobility are imitated by the people, etc.). If we
test these rules in their application to crime, we shall find that they
hold good there also. The author gives the following examples, among
others, in support of this:

“Vagrancy, under its thousand actual forms, is an offense essentially
plebeian; but if we go back into the past it will not be difficult to
connect our tramps and street singers with the noble pilgrims and
minstrels of the Middle Ages. Poaching, another nursery of criminals,
which in the past, together with smuggling, has played a part
comparable with vagrancy in the present, is still more directly
connected with the life of the lord of the manor.” [142] “Arson, a
crime of the lowest classes today, was once the prerogative of the
feudal nobility. Was not the Margrave of Brandenburg heard to boast one
day that he had burned in his life 170 villages? Counterfeiting takes
refuge at present in mountain caverns, or subcellars in the city, but
we know that coining was long a royal monopoly.

“Finally, theft, so degrading in our day, has had a brilliant past.
Montaigne tells us, without being very indignant at it, that many young
gentlemen of his acquaintance, whose fathers did not give them enough
money, procured more by stealing.” [143]

There was a time, then, when criminality extended itself from the
higher classes to the lower; at present new forms of crime take their
rise in the great cities and spread out into the country. The increase
of crime in the cities is very considerable, and it is very probable
that, in accordance with the law cited, criminality will at length
increase in the country as greatly. It is especially the crimes of
assassination, sexual crimes against minors, abortion, and infanticide,
that have increased. So the opinion of several Italian criminologists,
“that crimes against persons decrease where crimes against property
increase, and vice versa”, is wrong, according to Professor Tarde,
since both kinds of crime increase in the great cities.

“To sum up, the prolonged action of the great cities upon criminality
is manifest, it seems to us, in the gradual substitution, not exactly
of trickery for violence, but of covetous, crafty, and voluptuous
violence, for vindictive and brutal violence.” [144]

Nevertheless, civilization improves men, and the growing criminality is
in opposition to the greater and greater increase of civilization. This
contradiction is explained by the author by means of another law of
imitation; the law of insertion, i.e. the alternate passage from
fashion to custom.

“All industry is thus fed by a stream of improvements, innovations
today, traditions tomorrow; every science, every art, every language,
every religion obeys this law of the passage from custom to fashion and
of the return from fashion to custom, but to an enlarged custom.

“For at each of these steps in advance the territorial domain of
imitation increases; the field of social assimilation, of human
brotherhood, extends itself, and this is not, as we know, the least
salutary effect of imitative action from the moral point of view.”
[145]

After having mentioned how these different currents of imitation meet,
the author applies the idea set forth above to the influence of
education upon criminality. He shows that instruction, by itself, is
not a remedy for crime, since it may furnish new means for committing
crimes, and hence may only change the character of criminality. Finally
the author points out the influence of labor upon criminality,
combating the theory of Poletti, who says that it is necessary to take
into account the economic development (for example, if during the
period 1826–78 criminality in France increased in the ratio of 100 to
254, and productive activity was quadrupled, criminality did not
increase, but really diminished). The fundamental error in Poletti’s
argument, according to Professor Tarde is, that he considers crime as a
regular, permanent, and inevitable effect of industrialism.

“Only, there is labor and labor; and if in a more laborious class the
work is badly divided, excessive for some, whom it enervates and
disorders, insufficient for others, who become dissipated, or if it is
badly directed, turned toward deleterious compositions and reading
which excite the senses ...—in this case it will probably happen that
progress in labor is accompanied by a growing lack of discipline and by
academic vices of different kinds. An analogous phenomenon takes place
in our cities, where the mad chase for luxury outruns the rise of
wages, and where sexual crimes are sextupled or septupled while wealth
is tripled and quadrupled. The socialists, then, are right in imputing,
in part, to unjust distribution and to the objectionable direction of
the productive activity, the moral evil that has grown with it, and
which, further, does not decrease when productive activity becomes
weaker. For since the period when Poletti made his observations upon
the prosperity of France, this has ceased to grow, and has even
decreased rapidly, as we know only too well, but crime has continued
its onward march with a more marked impetus.

“In short, there remains nothing of the law laid down by this
distinguished writer, and all the statistics contradict him.
Delinquency, as Garofalo remarks, is so little proportional to
commercial activity that England, where crime is on the decrease, is
the nation most remarkable for the increase of its commerce, and that
Spain and Italy, where the criminality is greater than that of the
other principal states of Europe, are far behind them in business
development. We may add that in France the most hard-working class is
without any doubt the peasant class, and this shows the smallest
proportionate number of delinquents, notwithstanding unfavorable
conditions. We may conclude that work is in itself the adversary of
crime, that if it favors it it is by indirect, not necessary action,
and that its relation to crime is like that between two antagonistic
forms of work.” [146]

In the following section the author treats the influence of wealth and
of poverty upon the criminal. He mentions the different opinions of
Turati and of Colajanni on the one hand, and of Ferri and Garofalo on
the other. The former tried to prove that poverty is often a cause of a
poor man’s becoming a criminal. Garofalo tries to disprove it by
calling attention, among other things, to the fact that, according to
the criminal statistics of Italy for 1880, property owners committed as
many crimes in proportion as the proletariat did.

In opposition to this Professor Tarde points out that the French
criminal statistics in 1887 show that there were, out of 100,000 of
each class of the population, the following number of persons
arraigned: 20 out of the class of domestics, one of the poorest
classes; 12 from the liberal professions including persons of
independent income; 139 from the class of vagrants and persons without
occupation (the most necessitous class, therefore); 21 from commerce;
26 from manufacturing (a very high figure considering the profits of
that year); and 14 from the farming class (a very low figure
considering their relative poverty).

The author explains these contradictions as follows: “Let us not forget
that, the desire for wealth being the ordinary motive and more and more
the preponderating motive of crime as it is the only motive of
industrial labor, the possession of wealth must keep the most dishonest
man from crime as it does the most laborious man from industrial
labor—for it is impossible to desire what one has—at least if the
satisfaction of this desire has not meant the over-exciting of it....
Now in business circles, where on account of men’s throwing one another
into a fever, a constant gaining of wealth, rather than wealth itself,
is the end pursued, a fortune is like those peppered liqueurs which
arouse thirst more than they quench it. Hence it comes, doubtless, as
well as from the excitement prevailing in these circles, that
criminality there is as great as among domestic servants. In the same
way, in the licentious environments, in the great cities, where there
are masses of working people, sexual crimes are as much more numerous
as the pleasures of the senses are there more easily come by. But we
can lay it down as a principle that where wealth is an obstacle to
activity it is also an obstacle to crime, very much as political power
ceases to be dangerous at the moment when it ceases to be ambitious.
This is the situation among the rural proprietors, small and great,
among stockholders, and even in the majority of the liberal
professions...; content with his relative well-being, man indulges in
an intellectual half-labor, artistic rather than mechanical, honorable
rather than mercenary, and abstains from flagitious means of obtaining
an increase of income which he desires moderately. The French peasant,
in general, partakes of this moderation of desires, and, rich from his
sobriety, his stoicism, his frugality, his plot of ground at last
acquired, he is happier than the feverish millionaire, financier, or
politician, driven by his very millions to sow the seed of his rotten
speculations, rascalities, and extortions upon a vast scale. Further
the well-to-do agriculturists are in general the most honest people.
Let us not speak of wealth and poverty, to tell the truth, not even of
well-being and the reverse, but rather of happiness and unhappiness,
and be careful how we deny this truth, as old as the world, that the
wicked man’s excuse is often to be found in his being unhappy. Children
of this century ... let us confess that under its brilliant exterior
our society is not happy, and if we had no other assurances of its
great evils than its numerous crimes, without giving a thought to its
suicides, and its increasing cases of insanity, without lending an ear
to the cries of envy, of suffering, and of hatred ... we should not be
able to call its woes in question.

“From what does it suffer? From its internal trouble, from its
illogical and unstable condition, from intestine contradictions,
stirred up by the success even of its unheard-of discoveries and
inventions, piling one on top of the other, the material for contrary
theories, the source of unbridled, egoistic, and antagonistic desires.
Upon this obscure gestation, a great Credo, a great common end awaits;
it is creation before the Fiat Lux. Science multiplies its notions, it
elaborates a high conception of the universe; ... but where is the high
conception of life, of human life, that it is ready to make prevalent?
Industry multiplies its products, but where is the collective work that
it brings to birth? The preëstablished harmony of interests was a dream
of Bastiat, the shadow of a dream of Leibnitz. The citizens of a state
exchange information, scientific and otherwise, through books,
newspapers, or conversation, but to the profit of their contradictory
beliefs; they exchange services, but to the profit of their rival
interests; the more they assist one another, therefore, the more they
nourish their essential contradictions, which may have been as profound
at other times, but were never so conscious, never so painful, and
consequently never so dangerous.” [147]

Suppose, asks the author, there was no more foreign war, how could we
avoid civil war? There have, indeed been historic periods when there
existed a common aim uniting individuals, as the faith did in the
Middle Ages. In our days this aim can be nothing but “art, philosophy,
the higher cultivation of the mind and imagination, the æsthetic life.”

In order to be able to answer the question whether civilization (the
collective name for education, religion, science, arts, manufacturing,
wealth, public order, etc.) causes a diminution of criminality, it is
necessary to discriminate between two stages of civilization. In the
first there is an afflux of inventions; this is the stage at which
Europe is at the present time. In the second this afflux decreases and
it forms itself into a coherent whole. A civilization may be very rich,
then, and but little coherent, or very coherent and not very rich, like
that of the commune in the Middle Ages.

“But is it by its wealth or by its cohesion that civilization makes
crime recede? By its cohesion without any doubt. This cohesion of
religion, of science, of all forms of work and of power, of all kinds
of different innovations, mutually confirming one another, in reality
or in appearance, is a true implicit coalition against crime, and even
when each of these fruitful branches of the social tree combats but
feebly the gourmand branch, their agreement will suffice to divert all
the sap from it.” [148]



—This is not the place to criticise the theory of imitation in general,
with which Professor Tarde thinks that we can explain every social
phenomenon. In my opinion, this theory, in so far as it is new is not
correct, and in so far as it is correct is not new. It is true as
explaining how a social phenomenon, having taken its rise in a
locality, has been rapidly propagated, or why it still persists when
the original causes have ceased to operate.

However, it is plain that by means of imitation one can give but a
partial explanation of the phenomena mentioned. Other factors must be
pointed out to explain, for example, why something spreads everywhere
in consequence of imitation, at a certain moment, while before it
passed unperceived, etc.

I agree, then, that the significance of imitation and tradition is very
important in explaining social phenomena, but I am of the opinion that
imitation and tradition represent the conservative element, and give us
no information with regard to the birth of new social phenomena. [149]

In the domain of criminality also imitation plays a great part.
Children brought up in a vicious environment, easily contract bad
habits by imitation; the harmful influence of prison is proverbial; a
sensational crime often leads to analogous crimes. It is also by
imitation that we can explain, in part at least, the existence of the
Mafia and the Camorra, of which Professor Lombroso says, among other
things: “The long persistence and obstinacy of such associations as the
Mafia, the Camorra, and brigandage, seem to proceed in the first place
from the antiquity of their existence, for the long repetition of the
same acts transforms them into a habit, and consequently into a law.
History teaches us that ethnic phenomena of long duration are not to be
eradicated easily at a stroke.” [150]

Since the phenomena named remain permanent, there must be other
important social factors which have nothing to do with imitation. Thus,
for example, faith, whose prevalence is based to a great extent upon
tradition, would have disappeared long since, notwithstanding
tradition, if there had been no factors in the present society to make
it persist.

Admitting what has gone before, there is no reason to see in most of
the examples cited by the author in support of his theory, anything
else than his great knowledge of historic details of little or no
importance for the question of criminality. Where, for example, is the
connection between the minstrels of the Middle Ages and the vagrants of
our own days? There is certainly none but this, that both went from
place to place. But even if there had never been wandering minstrels,
the social phenomenon called “vagrancy” would have existed all the
same. It has nothing to do with imitation, but on the contrary has
everything to do with the existing social organization. It could thus
be proved by many examples that Professor Tarde exaggerates the extent
of the influence of imitation. We must not lose sight of the fact that
imitation teaches us nothing of the essential causes of a social
phenomenon. When we seek the causes of a disease that some one has, we
frequently see that it is the result of a contagion; we know, then,
that the disease is contagious, and this knowledge will point out
precautions to be taken to limit or prevent the spread of the disease;
but as to the causes of the disease itself we still know nothing.

It is the same way with regard to crime. It is certain that immoral
ideas and customs are easily contracted by children. The removal of
children from a harmful environment is therefore a preventive of the
extension of crime. But we are still ignorant of everything that
concerns the rise of these immoral ideas and customs, which is,
however, the essential thing.

With regard to the remarks of the author upon the influence of labor,
wealth, poverty, and civilization, I simply observe that these very
important and very complicated questions occupy but a few pages in his
work. It will be, then, quite superfluous to note in detail how the
whole has been treated in a very incomplete manner, although very true
remarks are found there (for example, those upon the bad distribution
of labor, upon the desire for wealth as a cause of crime, etc.).—



Beside an article that appeared in the “Revue Philosophique” (1890),
entitled “Misère et criminalité”, Professor Tarde has taken up his
subject again in a report: “La criminalité et les phénomènes
économiques” (Fifth Congress of Criminal Anthropology at Amsterdam). Of
this report we give a synopsis.

According to Professor Tarde, since it has been recognized that the
social factors of criminality are the most important, there has been a
manifest tendency to exaggerate the importance of economic factors.
Their high importance, which is incontestable, does not at all justify
our forgetting the stronger and more decisive action of the beliefs and
feelings in the aberrations of the will. Which of the two sources of
criminality is the more important, the economic or the religious (or
intellectual)? That cannot be decided. But it is much more important to
know in what phases, from what sides the economic life is
criminogenous.

Each economic phase, as, for example, domestic economy or urban
economy, has its special form of criminality. But political and
religious changes, whether they correspond or not to the
transformations in the mode of production, have, perhaps, a much
greater part in criminality than have the economic transformations. The
domestic economy, for example, gives rise to different crimes in which
no economic factor comes into play; as uxoricide, for example.

Neither poverty alone nor wealth alone is an obstacle to honesty. Poor
peoples or classes, accustomed to poverty, are often very honest, nor
is there any more need that great differences of wealth should lead to
crime. But it is the abrupt passing from wealth to poverty and from
poverty to wealth that is dangerous to morality.

“In short, criminality and morality are less dependent upon the
economic state of a country, than upon its economic transformations. It
is not capitalism as such that is demoralizing, it is the moral crisis
that accompanies the passage from artisan production to capitalistic
production, or from some particular mode of the latter to some other
mode.

“Economic phenomena may be regarded from three points of view: first,
from the point of view of their repetition, which has to do chiefly
with the propagation of habits of consumption, called needs, and of the
corresponding habits of labor; second, from the point of view of their
opposition, which includes principally the contests of producers among
themselves by acute or chronic competition, during strikes, or crises
of overproduction,—or contests of consumers among themselves, through
sumptuary laws, aristocratic or democratic, or monopolies of
consumption over which they dispute in a thousand ways, in time of
famine, or scarcity, or any form of underproduction,—or contests of
producers with consumers, through their attempts to exploit one
another, monopolize prices, or laws regulating the maximum price,
municipal tariffs, or protectionist rights, etc.; third, finally from
the point of view of their adaptation, always being renewed and always
incomplete, which embraces the series of successful inventions,
fortunate associations of ideas from which proceed all fruitful
associations of men, from the division of labor and of commerce, an
association spontaneous and implicit, to industrial, commercial,
financial, and syndical societies, etc.” [151]

It is through the second aspect that the economic life can give a
direct explanation of crime; that which is given by the other two is
only an indirect explanation. That is to say, each invention gives rise
to a contest among producers, and the progress of manufacturing creates
the possibility of satisfying needs, but at the same time makes those
who for want of the means cannot satisfy them, feel their needs all the
more strongly.

Every individual must satisfy a certain number of needs which have
their marked recurrences. A peaceful and honest society will be one in
which the great majority of the persons who compose it have, in
measure, the means of satisfying these needs. “Regular habits of
consumption and production form the first condition for good moral
health whether individual or collective, just as regular digestion is
the foundation of good physical health. Those who are irregular become
easily the ‘déclassés.’ Nothing is more contagious than disorder.”
[152]

Hence, then, comes the importance for criminality of social crises,
since during these production and consumption are deranged.

According to Professor Tarde, the social contradictions, which are the
chronic crises of societies, can be the sole causes of criminality. If
a society succeeds in avoiding every internal contradiction there can
hardly be any further question of crime.

Our opinions can always harmonize with those of the people around us,
while we are foreign to them in desire and feeling. “The criminal is he
who, undergoing conformity to the ideas of the community in which he
lives, yet escapes from conforming to the feelings and acts of the
community. He acts contrary to his own principles, which are those of
society.” “It is, then, not to a social crisis that we must mount, but
to a psychological crisis that we must descend, to explain crime.”
[153]

Social crises are of two kinds: politico-religious, and economic. In
opposition to divers statisticians, who are of the opinion that the
former class cause a diminution in criminality, the author thinks that
this diminution is only apparent, and that in reality the number of
crimes increases at these times; which is shown, for example, for
France by the addition of cases not prosecuted to those prosecuted.

As to the effect of economic crises, statisticians, Professor Tarde
claims, have not yet examined it. It seems to him that there is no
parallelism between economic crises and criminality.

The struggle of classes, which springs up and grows during the periods
of crisis, is a great danger to public morals, since it gives rise to a
class spirit, and consequently increases the contempt for the rights of
individuals of another class. However, the class struggle does not
increase the number of individual crimes, but only the number of
collective crimes.

To sum up, Professor Tarde is of the opinion, then, that social crises
in general, and economic crises in particular, are not the only source
nor a continual source of crime. The question of what is the cause of
economic crises remains unexplained. To solve this we must call in all
political economy. The causes of these economic crises are in brief:
first, unlimited competition; second, unforeseen disasters. “We may add
that these acute conflicts lead to suicide more than to crime; they are
a factor of crime much less important than the sullen conflicts, the
low but continuous fevers of troubled epochs in quest of a stable
state. And these are then less the conflicts of production with itself,
or of production with consumption, than the conflicts of consumption
with itself, i.e. the conflicts of needs that have grown but cannot be
satisfied at the time, within the limits of the always insufficient
wages or profits, a fertile source of criminal suggestions. When labor
no longer suffices to satisfy the legitimate needs in accordance with
the prevailing standards, the desire of gain without labor invades the
heart and becomes general. The only remedy for this danger would be the
advancement of manufacturing and its reorganization upon a vaster and
better conceived plan than the present one, if, at the same time that
any industrial progress gave more wealth for less labor, it did not
give rise to still more new wants. The individual organization of
wants, their hierarchization, by virtue of a certain unanimity of
fundamental principles, must precede the social organization of labor,
if we wish this latter really to make for peace and morals.” [154]



—Professor Tarde’s report is characterized by many very true
observations (as, for example, that every economic phase has its own
form of criminality; that sudden transitions from wealth to poverty,
and vice versa, are morally more dangerous than slow changes; etc.,
etc.), but at the same time is still more marked by a certain
elasticity and lack of close reasoning. Hence it is almost impossible
to frame a criticism of the report that will follow it step by step.

However there are some things to be noted. According to the author
there are two sources of criminality, the one economic, the other
intellectual. I consider that this distinction is not correct. Every
crime has an intellectual source, in this sense, that it is an act
conceived by the intellect. It is impossible, therefore, to see beside
this source an economic cause. But the intellect considered by itself
is empty; it is from the environment that it must draw the material
which it will transform into ideas. Consequently the question becomes
this: how far is the economic environment the cause of the formation of
criminal thoughts. Intellect and economic conditions do not stand side
by side but the one follows upon the other. It is only making use of a
commonplace to say that crime has an intellectual source; that explains
nothing.

In reading the first pages of the report one expects, after the
historical exposition which says that every economic phase has its own
form of criminality, to find an exposition of the present economic
system, and an inquiry into how far the criminality of our own day is
bound up with it. This would have been, I think, most important, and
would have advanced the subject. The most serious criticism that I have
to make is that nothing of the kind is attempted. What follows is only
a series of isolated remarks, which are correct only in part, and in
which the whole question is reduced to a matter of economic crises,
although the title speaks of economic conditions.

It is incorrect to say that the statisticians have not investigated the
influence of economic crises, as the second chapter of this work
proves. In it I have analyzed the works of the different authors who
have especially treated of this subject. Finally, I would call
attention to the fact that he furnishes no proof of his assertion that
the class struggle takes its rise in times of crisis—and would find it
difficult to do so.

What Professor Tarde means in speaking of “the advancement of
manufacturing and its reorganization upon a vaster and better conceived
plan”, is not clear. But it is certain that the final observation that
there must be “an individual organization of wants”, is purely Utopian.
For it is one of the characteristic phenomena of our present society
that it has strongly excited the cupidity of men, and that this will
disappear only when its cause has ceased to exist.

All Professor Tarde’s works upon criminality convince us of the great
knowledge of their author. The report of which I have been speaking
contains also ideas that are often very original, but this does not
prevent the necessity of confessing that it does not contribute much to
the solution of the problem that it treats.—




III.

A. CORRE.

In the third book of his “Crime et suicide” the author treats of the
influence of economic conditions upon criminality, beginning with
“labor, wages, and needs.”

Dr. Corre notes first the true condition of the free workman. No one is
obliged to give him work or bread, and it is forbidden to beg or even
to be idle. “There is no opinion more monstrous, more revolting, and
more cowardly. It is a social crime as well as the most dangerous of
follies. For it is necessary to be logical. If you oblige a man under
all circumstances to live by his own means, in the midst of a limited
circle, where the places are distributed in advance, the land divided
to the smallest fragments, if you refuse him the right to alms after
having refused him work ... you drive him to suicide or crime.” [155]
We must give work to everyone who wants to work, in order that he may
support himself and his family, and help must be given to those to whom
work cannot be given, as in the case of workmen not longer able to work
because of sickness or old age. On the other hand idleness must be
punished as well as professional crime. Wages must be so high that they
are sufficient not only for the strict necessities, but for others as
well; for example, for a progressive education, without, however,
arousing in the laboring class the desire for luxury that always
corrupts morals. Though naming a single exception, Dr. Corre is of the
opinion that wages are in general very insufficient, especially if we
take into account the fact that there are times of unemployment,
sickness, etc., during which nothing is earned. The question of wages
is one of great importance, then, for the etiology of criminality.
Nevertheless all the improvement of the material condition of the
working class will accomplish nothing unless there is at the same time
a moral improvement.

As other authors have already proved, the price of bread also has an
influence upon the course of criminality.

Under the heading “economic conditions”, he calls attention, in the
second place to “assistance, savings, property.” When we study the
effect of charity upon criminality in the departments of France, we see
that mendicity and vagrancy decrease, and that crimes are only of
moderate frequency, in places where the official assistance given is
the smallest, while criminality is pretty prevalent and even on the
increase where the greatest amount of official assistance is given.
“Thus very limited assistance will do less harm than if it were more
extensive. Such is the interpretation the mind gathers from a
comparison of the economic and judicial statistics. Excess in
alms-giving, with difficulty separable from a bad distribution of
wealth, will therefore have a demoralizing influence; it enervates and
sterilizes, and its fruits would appear more bitter if it were possible
to unveil the little secrets of assistance under the thousand forms
that it wears.” [156]

“Saving enlarges the field of the needs of the laborer, gives him
security for the future, strengthens his independence with regard to
the state, and his dignity in his relations with other citizens; it
permits him to surround his family with a greater degree of comfort,
and through education to raise his children into the professional
hierarchy. It is therefore useful, and has a moralizing influence.”
[157]

However, exaggerated saving is very prejudicial to morality for it
degenerates into avarice and thus becomes the cause of crime. We often
find the average number of depositors in savings-banks in the
departments that gave the lowest figure for crime. The departments with
a number of depositors above or below this average are apt to have high
figures for crime.

“It is possible to criticise academically the famous saying of
Proudhon, ‘property is theft.’ To refute it will be at times difficult.
I do not mean to say that all property is theft, but I maintain that
property in a measure that can be fixed is nothing else. As it is
organized with use, it is often immoral and one of the most active
factors in anti-social crime, latent or actual.” [158] According to the
author, one who owns property is a supporter of the state. For this
reason the number of small proprietors ought to be increased, even if
this is possible only by dividing great estates, which, however, have
almost always been gotten together by immoral means, by pillaging, by
paying very small wages in manufacturing, by gambling, etc. “They are
all, in the first instance, the fruit of a skill and a want of scruple
which would never obtain the sanction of a really equitable society; at
their blaze, which scorns poverty, the passion for gain is kindled, and
dull rage begins to develop the germ of reprisals. How shall we make
men who have nothing, and exhaust themselves to gain the bare
necessaries of life, satisfied that the persons who do no work and only
amuse themselves possess everything? You may talk of legal limitations
as much as you like, but conscience will revolt against a doctrine that
makes stolen property sacred after a certain period of impunity, and
leads to the cynical conclusion that any article or piece of land,
acquired by crime, is the legitimate possession of the bandit if during
5, 10, 20, 30 years he succeeds in warding off the attacks of the law.”
[159] Not only has property often been acquired in an illegal manner,
but the transmission of it is also immoral. For it is by this means
that persons have acquired great fortunes which they would never have
earned by their labor. It would be preferable to make private fortunes
accrue to the state, after provision had been made for the widow and
children “to provide for the needs of persons who are useful but made
unproductive by poverty, and to reënforce the collective labor.” In
this way a general prosperity would replace great fortunes; this would
increase the feeling of solidarity, while great fortunes only awaken
cupidity and lead to the commission of crimes. The richest departments
give the highest figures for criminality. By the suppression or
limitation of inheritance we should suppress also the numerous crimes
against life resulting from it.

In the sixth chapter, in which Dr. Corre examines the relative
importance of the principal sociological factors, he sums up his
opinion as to the influence of economic conditions upon criminality.
Too great wealth and too great poverty are both causes of crime. “The
first corrupts and the second degrades; both lead to crime through
lessening the resistance to temptation that promises the satisfaction
of wants fictitious or real, and when they both appear in the same
environment, they give more energy to bad impulses, more violence to
conflicts.” [160] This is why the agricultural class, in which moderate
prosperity prevails, is the least criminal. The means by which this
condition of things is to be improved is complex: “it is not altogether
to be found in the solution of the question of wages; it is chiefly to
be found in a better system for making the masses moral, in the
reduction of the influences which tempt them to improvidence and
idleness, lead them to drunkenness and alcoholism.” [161]



—The second part of this work will show sufficiently why, in my
opinion, the treatment of Dr. Corre is confused and incomplete,
notwithstanding the truth of some observations made by him with regard
to the subject which concerns us. The criticism of the author upon the
organization of society at present is that of the petty bourgeoisie; he
expects salvation only from the multiplication of small holdings, and
hopes that this will make mankind happier. However, the development of
large industries makes me believe that this hope will never be
realized.—




IV.

L. MANOUVRIER.

Of all the adherents of the “hypothesis of the environment,” Professor
Manouvrier is undoubtedly the one who has set forth this doctrine in
the clearest manner. Being an anthropologist it is evident that he has
not given his attention more especially to economic conditions. But it
seems to me that what he says in opposition to the theory of Professor
Lombroso, and in support of that of the environment, is of the greatest
importance. I will give a résumé, therefore, of his “Genèse normale du
crime”, [162] and in doing so will quote his own words as far as
possible, in order to give their full value. Although there is no
connection between the doctrine of Professor Lombroso and his
adherents, and this work, I shall be forced to follow his whole
demonstration, because of the interlacing of the theories of the
Italian school and the detailed exposition of the doctrine of the
“environment.”

The doctrine of the innate character of crime and the phrenology of
Gall and Spurzheim are closely connected. Gall thought that he had
discovered in the brain the organs of homicide and theft, without,
however, denying the importance of surroundings, so that he explained a
case of theft by means of circumstances when the bump of theft was
wanting in the thief.

This doctrine has been entirely supplanted by the theories of Lamarck
and Darwin. “In the place of attributing to the environment the rôle of
a simple player of a hand-organ, Lamarck sees in it a true musician
playing upon his instrument any airs suited to its complexity and
qualities. Further, the quality and characteristics of the instrument
can be modified, transformed under the influence of this marvelous
musician and that of the music executed. This was the ruin of
craniomancy. The diagnostics of phrenology found themselves limited at
once and for always to the faculties, the elementary dispositions that
Gall and Spurzheim had tried in vain to discover, and which are
consistent with the execution of acts indefinitely variable.

“The phrenologists are right in connecting the ‘properties of the soul
and mind’ with organization, but they are wrong in connecting such acts
as theft and homicide with organic causes, as if these acts had the
value of real, irreducible functions.” [163]

Notwithstanding the bond between phrenology and the positivist school,
this school does not rely upon the theory in question, but upon the
transformist theory, i.e. upon the theory that gives its attention to
environment. The cause of this is that the fundamental error that forms
the point of departure is still universally prevalent. “This error
consists in believing that acts sociologically defined, like crimes,
can be connected with the anatomical conformation, without being first
referred by a psychological analysis to their psychological elements,
the only ones, whether normal or pathological, that depend directly
upon anatomy. The same error consists in confusing the combinations of
aptitudes formed under the influence of environment, with the
elementary aptitudes resulting from the native organization or its
successive modifications. It also leads to a misunderstanding of the
primary fact that two individuals similarly constituted can be led, in
consequence of the influence of dissimilar environments to which they
have been subjected since their birth, to conduct themselves in
different, and even quite opposite, ways, without their acts ceasing to
be, on that account, conformed to their anatomical constitution.” [164]

It is a fact well known to biologists that in all living beings
qualities often occur that did not appear in their immediate forebears
but in more remote generations. This reappearance of qualities is
called atavism. Its importance has been too much exaggerated, however,
and it has been made into a magic word with which, it has been thought,
everything could be explained, including crime. The line of reasoning
has been as follows: crime is one of the ordinary phenomena among
savage peoples, and must therefore have been so among the ancestors of
the civilized peoples. It is observed that among the criminals of our
day there are more of the anatomical stigmata indicating atavism than
among non-criminals; consequently crime is a phenomenon of atavism!
There are numerous errors in this reasoning. “Since we are treating the
question of crime, we must first of all know what is understood by
crime, must give a definition of it indicating what crime corresponds
to physiologically, and to what order of anatomical characteristics the
physiological tendency to crime corresponds. Considered in themselves,
these acts suppose only the existence of a conformation permitting, and
of needs demanding, their accomplishment. If such a conformation and
such needs no longer exist in the normal state among civilized peoples,
where nevertheless the acts are frequent, it would be proper to examine
the authors of them for abnormal characteristics; not merely any
abnormal characteristics, but characteristics, anatomical or
physiological, that it would be possible to connect with these
aptitudes and needs that have become abnormal.” [165]

Among the anatomical stigmata observed in criminals in prison there are
several which, considered by themselves, have nothing abnormal about
them; none of them would serve to characterize criminals. We often
find, for example, that murderers have relatively large jaws, which are
ordinarily thus an index of a conformation disposed to brutality; “but
this brutality is absolutely of the same order as that of men compared
with women; it is a masculine characteristic, and the masculine
conformation is indubitably favorable to crimes of violence much more
than the feminine; but happily it happens that most men, in civilized
countries, live under conditions in which their natural brutality does
not prevent their being very peaceable citizens, though it would be
imprudent to molest them. Very vigorous men are ordinarily endowed with
square and very solid jaws; they are men for attack or defense, who may
be very useful to society or very harmful, as the case may be. Given to
acting vigorously and brutally, this they may be, but inclined to crime
they are not, any more than the men with small jaws, whose mildness is
often the effect of muscular weakness, and who, though little given to
striking and breaking down doors, nevertheless know how to be brutal
and violent in their own way.” [166]

However, it might be thought that these anatomical characteristics,
though not dangerous in themselves, are nevertheless an indication of a
tendency on their part to act like savages. But this is not the case;
these characteristics “are morphological accidents that are purely
local and are compatible with the most fortunate conformation.” But
this is not saying that every peculiarity must remain unutilized. Thus,
for example, there are persons who are able to move their ears. “If
murder and theft were acts as little complicated, and of as little
importance as moving the ears, and if these acts, having become
criminal, did not suppose very complex anatomical and psychological
coördinations; if there were, in other words, as Gall supposed,
cerebral organs specially and innately fitted for murder and theft, we
could believe that the mere atavistic presence of these organs would
constitute a tendency to commit these crimes; but neither
anatomo-physiological analysis, nor psychology will justify today so
simple a conception.” [167]

And then it has not been proved that murder and theft were habitual
with our ancestors; they had recourse to them only under stress of
circumstances, quite like any normal man of today. Considered from an
anatomical point of view our means of injuring our fellows have
decreased; on the other hand we have now other means at our disposal
(firearms, etc.). “As to the need of pleasure and of life, this can
only have increased, and never can cupidity have been more aroused than
in our civilized society. Never have the temptations to appropriate the
goods of others been stronger and more frequent. Civilization tends to
develop wants and appetites, whence there comes this colossal extension
of the means of repression and of coercion employed to make criminal
attempts dangerous, in order that crime may not be too easy a means of
acquiring fortune. Except for purely pathological cases, the criminal
is moved by his wants, by wants that have nothing extraordinary about
them; when a man has an interest, or thinks he has an interest in
committing a crime, he brings into play muscular and cerebral aptitudes
which every normal man possesses, the same elementary aptitudes as
those he might have made use of, under other circumstances, to pursue
and punish a criminal.” [168]

Some biological facts are to be explained by atavism; their explanation
nevertheless remains mysterious. But atavism loses all its importance
as a means of explanation as soon as we know how to explain a fact by
actually existing causes, as is the case with crime. “We should
understand that it would be a question of atavistic tendencies if
assassins killed for the sole pleasure of killing, if thieves stole for
the pleasure of stealing. Now we know well that theft and murder are
only means, and that their use is called ‘work’ by professional
criminals. If they prefer this kind of work it is because it is quicker
and less painful than regular work.” [169]

It might be objected here that the horror of blood being natural to
most men it would be necessary just the same to have recourse to
atavism to explain murder. This horror of blood is assuredly found in
most men, but only so far as their interest requires. Not a single
surgeon or butcher pursues his bloody trade through atavism, but only
because forced to it by his interests. More than one born-bourgeois
thinks that he would never eat meat rather than have to kill cattle
himself, but this is only pure illusion or an unconscious hypocrisy.
For he would do it without any doubt if he could not gain his
livelihood in any other way. Do not the bourgeoisie shoot their
inoffensive fellow citizens who revolt against a social condition that
no one would dare to call ideal? Do they not mow down savages with
machine guns in order to divide up their country? Or do they not make
war against other states in order to protect their own commercial
interests? It will be objected that these things are not crimes; this
is a question of definition, but assuredly they are similar to crime.

“It is not only in the prisons that we find born-criminals; but we are
all such, if we understand by this abusive expression the possession of
hereditary tendencies to enjoy things ourselves, in case of need, to
the detriment of our fellows. The human crimes to which I have just
alluded indicate chiefly the cruelty and ferocity of the species, and
of ethnic collectivities, social or otherwise. As to the individual
equivalents of crime, I will recall further that they are not difficult
to discover in the conduct of honest men, most of whom do not trouble
themselves to make use of means as harmful and immoral as those which
criminals do. The equivalents of crime among honest men present, it is
true, the great advantage of remaining more or less unperceived by the
penal code, by the police at least, and the psychologists of the New
School; but they are nevertheless recognized as immoral and harmful by
those who have recourse to them, and they suffice to show in what way
honest men would conduct themselves if the conditions in which they
live and have lived had not driven them away from crime, legally
so-called, with as much force as the opposite environmental conditions
have driven others to it.” [170]

Having made fuller remarks to the effect that the cruel and repugnant
professions referred to above are not practiced because of atavistic
tendencies, but solely from necessity, the author ends this part of his
article as follows: “There nevertheless remains a tremendous difference
between the killing of an animal and the killing of a man, from a moral
point of view, of course, but also from the point of view of the
motives generally fitted to prevent the killing. But it must be
remarked that these motives are connected with environmental influences
which are exceedingly variable, and which, for too many persons, are
considerably diminished and at the same time replaced by influences of
the opposite environment. Most assassins have received a certain
culture appropriate to the conception of murder and to its realization,
and this is simply facilitated by their conformation, which is in no
wise exceptional. If we had only to twirl our thumb to get rid of an
enemy we should have to put forth all our efforts to harm no one.
Already too many respectable men can order murders that they would not
be courageous enough to execute. Let us congratulate ourselves that
self-interest more often deters men from murder than drives them to it,
for every normal man possesses the cerebral and muscular qualities
necessary to conceive, prepare, and execute the crime. It is not
necessary to call in the return to animal instincts through atavism.
The continuity of man and the animals is much more perfect than the
atavistic school pretends. Man is always an animal; the most dangerous
of all because he is the most intelligent and because he can utilize
his faculties in all sorts of ways, harmful or useful to his fellows
according to his own interest. The formula to be applied is to arrange
things so that every man will find more advantage in being useful to
his fellows than in injuring them. Progress in this regard would be
more rapid without this unfortunate predilection for occult causes,
which leads so many excellent minds to seek in the clouds for
explanations that lie under their noses, but which have to be found
just where they are.

“Those ferocious instincts which seem the return of another world, in
brawls or in times of revolution, are not returning at all, because
they have never disappeared. During a certain time they do not manifest
themselves in the individual or the family, because there is no need
that they should; or possibly they manifest themselves in ways less
dangerous, in connection with ordinary circumstances and relatively
favorable to tranquillity. But let there arise any need, no matter
what, of a “mobilization of the offensive and defensive forces”, then
the mobilization takes place, and the most civilized man appears under
the form of the dangerous animal he has never ceased to be, happily for
himself and his species. This man whom you take for an atavistic
throw-back, appears such to you only because you have failed to
recognize in their mild form, in yourself and in others, the
fundamental brutality and egoism of the human species. Notwithstanding
the civilizing influences in the midst of which you have lived,
notwithstanding the peaceable habits that you have contracted, and all
the horror with which you are inspired by the contrary habits of which
you fear to fall the victim, it is enough that you should be worked
upon rather strongly by a combination of annoying circumstances, that
even you should become a dangerous individual. When we wish to study
crime as anthropologists or as psychologists, we must not be afraid to
look the truth in the face, and it is important to clear our minds
beforehand, as far as possible, of the illusions of self-love, and of
deceptive conventions.” [171]

Then Professor Manouvrier criticises in a manner as just as it is
witty, the hypothesis of the “delinquent man.” He demonstrates that,
according to the method of the New School, a work could be written upon
the “hunting man” also, full of scientific observations upon his argot,
his boasting, etc., etc., upon all sorts of signs, in short, which go
to show that a taste for hunting is an atavistic phenomenon. The
explanation of crime by atavism is no more true than this other, for
both can be explained by the environment.

If we hold absolutely to the expression: “born-criminal”, every man is
one, just as every dog is a born-swimmer. Every dog knows how to swim
very well, but this does not prevent a number of dogs from never
swimming, since ordinarily there are more convenient ways of crossing
the water. In the same way every man is a born-criminal, but most men
refrain from becoming actual criminals, since that course is more
advantageous to them than the other.

“No one is ignorant that the educational influences to which one is
subjected during his whole life and especially during infancy, and the
solicitations of self-interest, are exceedingly variable under
different circumstances and for different individuals; and that the
educational influences and the solicitations of self-interest unite
very generally to furnish the motive for criminal conduct and for
honest conduct as well. And it is this that governs every man’s manner
of acting in his relations with others; and it must not be forgotten in
treating of anthropology, whether anatomical, physio-psychological, or
sociological. It is never forgotten in practical life.

“We all know that, whatever our fundamental character may be and the
honest habits that we have been able to form, our manner of conducting
ourselves may vary considerably under the influence of changes in our
environment, and in proportion to those changes. It is a temptation to
which the most austere man would greatly dread to be exposed, and to
which he would never voluntarily expose himself, because he knows that
the tendencies imputed to criminals (said to be atavistic, but all
simply human) are not lacking in himself. These tendencies, when they
have found abundant and honorable means of satisfaction during long
years, become so much the more to be dreaded on this account, and run
great danger of becoming criminal as soon the legal means of
satisfaction disappear. The man who comes to lack these means finds
himself in a much more dangerous situation as far as the likelihood of
his becoming a criminal is concerned, than one who had become
accustomed to privations.” [172]

Professor Manouvrier begins the last section of his study by asking
what is the significance of the anatomical peculiarities observed in
the so-called born-criminals. “The truth probably is that we do find in
a number of criminals in prison more of the lower or abnormal
characteristics than in a like number of persons chosen at random. But
this in no wise proves that those among the criminals who have such
characteristics, have been predestined to crime from their physical
make-up. Those among them who are not so constituted are nevertheless
criminals, and honest men who bear the criminal marks have nevertheless
remained honest.

“The truth is that the ‘new school’ consider as criminals only the
refuse of this class, the prisoners; just as, when they wanted to
depict prostitutes, they took poor syphilitic girls who had been at
least three years in brothels, that is to say, the refuse of refuse.
Under what family and social conditions these criminals and prostitutes
lived during childhood and afterward, it is easy for anyone to imagine
who has caught but a glimpse of the slums of manufacturing towns. In
order to escape crime and prostitution or mendicity when one has grown
up in such an environment, it is necessary to have virtues that are
extremely rare among respectable people, so much the more so since, to
the temptations that come from poverty in the midst of luxury, is
ordinarily added the effect of example, and even of education of the
particular kind that is called criminal education. All this may be
resisted for some time, but it is only the first step that costs. The
good qualities themselves that one possesses become the causes of
crime. It may even be maintained that physical excellencies themselves
drive men to crime more strongly than defects, when once the external
conditions become favorable for crime.” [173]

The fact that we generally find more inferior individuals among the
criminals imprisoned than among other men must be attributed to the two
following circumstances: first, that criminals who have not been
arrested, owe their liberty generally to the fact that they are better
endowed; and second, that in all social classes a selection goes on by
which those best constituted are always in possession of the most
desirable and least painful means of existence, while to those less
privileged fall the lowest professions, and they “end sooner or later
by falling into the ditch where the influences that drive men to crime
reach their maximum frequency and power, while the contrary motives are
proportionately weak.” Those who have known better days sometimes
prefer suicide to crime; but those who are born in the ditch, know no
other life, and are consequently led into crime.

What is much more astonishing than crime is the fact that workmen labor
courageously and patiently for ten or twelve hours a day, and
notwithstanding this lead only a miserable life. The reason is that
they have known nothing but labor since infancy and have always had to
be content with very simple amusements. It goes without saying that one
man is more moved to commit crimes than another, although the
conditions under which they are living are the same, just as an athlete
will use violence quicker than a weakling. But this is no reason to
declare strength a factor of crime, since it serves for useful acts as
well. Acts which are contrary to the proper working of society are,
therefore, called abnormal and those are called normal that are in
harmony with it. But it is not therefore permissible to transfer this
distinction to the field of biology, and call the criminal abnormal.
“Aptitudes that are very normal physiologically, may be employed for
acts that are equally normal physiologically, but which, from a social
point of view are classed as abnormal, because contrary to the social
prosperity. Yet this is an abuse of the word ‘abnormal’, because
society as at present constituted is, in its normal functioning,
consistent with innumerable causes of conflict between its own
interests and those of individuals. And just as the annoying
consequences of our mistakes often make us recognize the truth, so
crimes very often serve to indicate to societies the reforms they ought
to bring about in order to perfect themselves.

“Every individual has wants to satisfy, wants primordial or secondary,
that may become infinitely complicated and clothed in forms as much
more various as the environment becomes more complex. Now it happens in
every society, and especially in very civilized societies, that the
different individuals do not find the same facilities, and further, do
not possess the same means of action. There is an evident disproportion
between the existing needs and the milder means of satisfying them;
whence the struggle for existence and well-being.

“In our estimating the intrinsic worth of criminals, we must not fail
to take account of this fact, that most honest men do not deprive
themselves of any of the pleasures which are the aim of criminals, and
that most criminals, in order to escape crime would have had to have
rare virtue. Among the legal means of satisfaction offered by society
there are those that are easy and agreeable, among others that of
drawing the income from capital amassed by one’s parents. There are
also difficult and painful ones, which are the lot of those whom
pecuniary heredity has not secured against the so-called criminal
heredity. In order to share legally in the pleasures of which they are
witnesses, those whom we may call disinherited by fortune, must make
efforts of which those born to wealth have no idea. This is why, if the
disinherited seek a short-cut, we must ask ourselves, before we
consider them as monstrous beings, whether under the same circumstances
we should be able to keep to the legal path.

“The struggle for existence and well-being is regulated by social laws.
If these were perfect, each individual could satisfy his wants in an
equitable measure, that is to say in the measure of his faculties, his
labor, and the service he renders to the community. Crimes would then
be diminished in an enormous proportion, but they would not be
suppressed, for there would still be inevitable competitions, and the
time will probably never come when, on the one hand, each individual
will have just the wants that his social worth will permit him to
satisfy legally, and, on the other, will have sufficient virtue to
renounce the satisfaction of wants, even factitious ones, which he has
once contracted without being able to comply with the conditions which
the most just law imposes for this satisfaction.” [174]

The penal law is one of the means the object of which is combating the
illegal satisfaction of wants. Everyone knows, however, that this means
does not always attain the end sought. The penal law will, in fact,
produce a diminution of criminality only when it shall have brought
about profound penal changes,—when punishment shall be no more than the
useful and necessary reaction against acts that are harmful to the
well-being of the community and to the development of society.

It is to be proved that there is, besides the normal, or ordinary,
origin of crime, a pathological, or extraordinary, origin. “It is quite
superfluous to bring in tendencies atavistically recalled by
pathological degeneracy, in order to explain the harmful effects of
this degeneracy, and of mental diseases, upon the way in which the
degenerate and mentally diseased act. The least functional trouble is
enough to alter our sensations, our judgment, our imagination, our
deliberations, and consequently, to make us act wrongly.” [175]

The theory of the innate character of crime through atavism is
consequently quite erroneous. “It would be unseemly on my part to refer
it, through atavism, to original sin or to the call of the blood of the
ancient melodramas. I will not even say that it is derived through
tradition, which is an environmental influence, from the old
phrenological doctrine, although that is an error of the same kind.
Errors, in fact, are like crimes; they have no need of atavism nor of
immediate heredity, nor even of tradition, in order to repeat
themselves. Causes of error or causes of crime, the springs are far
from being dried up. They always flow abundantly. It is necessary in
science to react against errors, and in society to react against
crimes. But it must never be forgotten that every man is normally
exposed to commit both errors and crimes.” [176]



—I shall make only a few observations upon Professor Manouvrier’s
study, a work which, in my opinion, is one of the best, not to say the
best, upon the origin of crime, and in about fifty pages says more than
many a bulky volume.

In the first place Professor Manouvrier shows that in our days wants
have increased greatly, and he believes that civilization is the cause
of it. I am of the opinion that this last assertion is not correct and
that civilization has nothing to do with it. Many writers commit this
error of confusing civilization and the present mode of production, and
it is just for this reason that it is useful and necessary to correct
it. All the evils that have been brought upon the peoples of Africa and
of China, war, alcohol, etc., etc., have been called by the collective
name of “civilization.” In reality it is those who have brought all
these calamities upon these countries, and have tried to destroy a
veritable, age-long civilization like that of China, who are the
barbarians. It is not a civilizing instinct that has driven European
states to a policy of expansion, but rather cupidity, eagerness for
gain on the part of the owning class, who are seeking a new outlet for
their merchandise; in short, it is the present mode of production,
capitalism.

The same is true with regard to the constant increase of wants; it is
the present system which creates wants. New methods of procuring profit
are invented, and it is only with this in view that many inventions are
made, most of them useless, often even harmful. And on the other hand
there is a class of persons who grasp at any means, even the most
absurd, of passing the time, and have the money to procure these means.
And these wants spring up in other persons also, and the impossibility
of satisfying them makes men the more eager. Consequently it is not
civilization, but capitalism, which must be designated as the cause of
this phenomenon.

In the second place, Professor Manouvrier thinks that criminality would
diminish enormously, but without disappearing entirely, if the social
laws were perfected so that each individual could satisfy his wants
according to his capacities, his labor, and his services to the
community. This is, in my opinion, entirely correct; but the maxim of
Saint-Simon, “to every man according to his capacities, to each
capacity according to its works”, which, in Professor Manouvrier’s
opinion, is perfect, by many others is not thought to be so, though
superior to the present distribution of commodities. We can set over
against this the rule, “that each shall work according to his faculties
and his strength, and receive according to his needs.” If this were
realized, crime would become almost unimaginable. Many persons are of
the opinion that such a thing could never be realized. But they forget
that it is exclusively from the environment that the enormous
differences in wants arise (the wife of the millionaire has perhaps a
thousand times as many needs as the wife of the proletarian). If these
two persons had been born and brought up in the same environment, the
wants of the one would have been to those of the other perhaps as 1 to
3, or even less, but certainly not more. And then those who believe in
a future distribution according to needs, are of the opinion (and think
they can prove it) that, if in the present organization of society
egoism is omnipotent, the feeling of solidarity will be so strengthened
in the future social organization, that the man endowed with great
abilities and much energy, will not begrudge his fellow less highly
endowed, the satisfaction of all his wants.



I would, at the same time, make a remark concerning the environmental
school in general, a remark not to be considered as a criticism, for I
agree perfectly that it is the environment that makes the criminal. It
is this: it is not enough for the treatment of the question of
criminality, to furnish proof of the assertion that the cause of crime
is not inherent in man; it is also necessary to show in what respects
the environment is criminogenous, and in what way it can be improved.
Now the French School has given but little attention to this.—




V.

A. BAER.

The work of Dr. Baer, “Der Verbrecher in anthropologischer Beziehung”,
has only an indirect importance for our subject, as the title
indicates. Since his medical and anthropological studies lead him to
the conclusion that the social atmosphere is the fundamental cause of
crime, it is worth while to note his opinion. For this it will be
sufficient to quote the following: “For us crime is, as Prins
excellently expresses it, not an individual phenomenon, but a social
one. ‘Criminality is made up of the elements of human society itself,
it is not transcendent but immanent. We can see in it a kind of
degeneration of the social organism.... The criminal and the honest man
are each dependent upon their environment. There are social conditions
that are favorable to moral health, where there is no tendency, no
inclination toward crime; there is a social environment where the
atmosphere is corrupt, where unwholesome elements have accumulated,
where crime settles as soot does in a flue, where the tendency toward
crime bears fruit.’ Though Ferri has recently advocated the opinion
that the criminal is the result of three factors, operative at the same
time, and that these three causes are individual (i.e.
anthropological), physical, [177] and social; in our opinion, on the
other hand, these three causes are actually to be reduced to a single
one, if, as he himself points out, we take into consideration the fact
that the first two are both dependent upon social conditions. The
anthropological and physical stigmata of criminals are, as we have
endeavored to show above, in most cases wholly conditioned by the
influences and circumstances of their environment.

“Crime, we will close this work by saying, is not the consequence of a
special organization of the criminal, an organization which is peculiar
to the criminal alone, and which forces him to the commission of
criminal acts. The criminal, such by habit and apparently born as such,
bears many marks of bodily and mental deformity, which have, however,
neither in their totality nor singly, so marked and peculiar a
character as to differentiate the criminal from his fellows as a
distinct type. The criminal bears the traces of degeneracy that are to
be found in abundance among the lower classes from which he mostly
takes his rise. These traces, acquired through social conditions and
transmitted, in his case at times emerge in stronger form. Whoever
would do away with crime must do away with the social wrongs in which
crime takes root and grows, and, in establishing and applying forms of
punishment, must give more weight to the individuality of the criminal
than to the category under which the crime falls.” [178]








CHAPTER V.

THE BIO-SOCIOLOGISTS.


I.

AD. PRINS.

I cannot better give Professor Prins’s opinion upon the subject of my
work than by quoting what he says in his book, “Criminalité et
répression”, and especially in his first chapter entitled “De la
criminalité en général. Des classes criminelles. Des délinquants
d’accident et des délinquants de profession.” There we read: “There
exists no abstract type of a moral man, nor of a guilty man; crime is
not an individual phenomenon, but a social phenomenon. Criminality
proceeds from the very elements of humanity itself; it is not
transcendent, but immanent; we can see in it a sort of degeneration of
the social organism.” [179]

There is an environment favorable to moral health, where the tendency
to crime is almost wholly lacking; there is a social environment where
the atmosphere is corrupt, where unwholesome elements are heaped up,
where the most vigorous perish, where criminality spreads like the
mould in the dunghill; the tendency toward crime there is formidable,
and we can say in this sense that it is a social fact with a social
cause, and that it is in intimate connection with a given social
organization.

Let us consider our own epoch for a moment. A century of progress and
refinement is a century of vices; the increasing complexity of our
mechanism creates, with new temptations, new occasions of falling. The
car of civilization, like that of Juggernaut, destroys many of those
who throw themselves under its wheels. The world has enormous appetites
that it cannot satisfy: sensuality, greed of gain, a taste for and
facility in speculation; the contrast between great wealth and extreme
poverty; the brutal necessities of the struggle for existence in the
face of the concentration of property and of capital; the defects of
the industrial organization, which abandons the proletariat to chance,
keeps no watch over apprenticeship, and leaves the child of the
working-man to the excitations of the streets and the promiscuity of
the workshop, and finally sharpens everywhere the obscure instincts of
animalism; all this recoils upon criminality with deplorable certainty.
How far wrong we should be in such an environment simply to contrast
the delinquent with the honest man! It is two social states that are
contrasted; the one is based upon comfortable means, sociability,
mutual protection, useful work, and thrift; the other upon poverty,
isolation, egoism, and unproductive labor. And in the great urban
agglomerations, pauperism, mendicity and vagrancy, idleness, the spirit
of adventure, prostitution, the dissipation of strength, everything, in
short, naturally concurs in developing social anemia.

“Take any district whatsoever, however poor, uncivilized, and wild, and
you will always find in the great cities, London or Paris, New York or
San Francisco, a worse environment and greater depravity. It is here,
in the lowest slums, where never a glimmer of physical or moral
well-being penetrates, that the disinherited live. They get a glimpse
of the splendor of luxury only to hate it; they respect neither
property nor life, because neither property nor life has any real value
for them; they are born, grow pale, struggle, and die, without
suspecting that for certain persons existence is good fortune, property
a right, virtue a habit, and calm a constant state. Such is the natural
and fatal home of criminality.

“In a quarter subjected to detestable hygiene, built upon marshy soil,
devoid of drainage and potable water, furrowed with narrow and filthy
streets, covered with hovels without life or air, where an atrophied
population vegetates, epidemics are inevitable and propagate themselves
with great intensity. In the same way, crime finds an easy and certain
prey in the environment of the poor of a great city. The illegitimate
and abandoned children, the children of convicts and prostitutes, the
vagrants, etc. are so many designated recruits. Without family, without
traditions, without fixed home or settled occupation, without relations
with the ruling classes, what wonder that they have no other motive
than complete egoism, no other activity than selfish and transitory
efforts for the immediate satisfaction of their material appetites? The
emigration from the country to the city still further increases this
army and multiplies the chances of crime. When the sons of peasants
leave the plow for the workshop and come to seek fortune in the furnace
of great cities, they follow the spirit of adventure; they must have,
at any price, a means of subsistence, and as competition is great and
temptations arise at every step, the prisons profit by this overplus
that the country gives to the city. Another consequence of the
immigration from the country is that the population becomes excessive,
places are lacking, and wages fall below the living expenses.
Ducpetiaux showed, in 1856, that the budget of the working-man in the
great cities is lower than the sum representing the budget of the
working-man in prison. This situation has not changed, and the laboring
class, badly lodged, badly nourished, vegetate at the mercy of economic
crises. The working-man is always on the verge of vagrancy, the vagrant
always on the verge of crime. The whole proletariat is thus exposed in
the front rank, and whether it is a question of sickness or crime, it
is the first to fall.” [180]

“Such are the conditions of the development of the criminal classes,
that is to say of the classes where we meet the tendency to crime. And
it is of importance to remark that we can determine their legal
character; they are the vagrants and delinquents by profession. They
are clearly differentiated from the vagabonds and delinquents by
accident. This distinction, which modern statistics has brought into
relief, is now the basis of penal science, and the judge can no longer
overlook it.

“The occasional delinquents constitute the minority, their life is
regular, their instincts are right; a sudden passion, an unpremeditated
outburst, a passing depression of the will, leads them into crime; a
sort of fever dominates them and, the fit once past, their normal life
takes up its course again.

“On the other hand, the professional delinquents, who make up the
largest part of the population of the prisons, are really the criminal
class. They are the hardened, the incorrigible, the recidivists. They
form, by the side of regular society, the great rebel tribe, where
gather and mingle poverty, ignorance, vice, idleness, and prostitution.
The soldiers of this army obey, not a momentary desire, but a permanent
tendency. They do not always commit crime for crime’s sake, but the
most trivial incident drives them to it; they profit by every
opportunity, and we can say that, as in certain circles virtue is a
reflex act, so crime is a reflex act with them. Further, they have,
quite like the civilized world, a public opinion which supports them,
arouses them, gives them their own kind of popularity, and constitutes,
in a word, an incentive for the heroes of vice, just as the other
public opinion encourages the soldiers of duty.

“What is true of criminal society as a whole, is equally true of the
individual as such. In each infraction of the law, besides the
accidental factor, i.e. age, character, temperament, in a word, the
personal disposition, there is the collective or social factor, i.e.
the environment, the permanent conditions, the general laws. With the
occasional delinquent the individual factor predominates, it is
especially the man that appears. With the habitual delinquent, it is
the social factor, the collectivity that comes upon the scene.

“In the well-to-do, polished, educated classes, who have lacked nothing
and have had the benefit of civilizing influences from the cradle, the
fault is chiefly personal, and it is the exception. In the lower
strata, where everything is lacking, where, to combat evil, men have
neither in the present, social protection, nor in the past, the
generations of ancestors who have enjoyed power, wealth, and education,
it is chiefly collective. In this sense, then, the collective forces
have a dominant action in criminality; in order to combat it these must
be attacked, and the legislator finds in the law only a blunted weapon
if he does not understand this supreme truth, the social character of
criminality.” [181]




II.

W. D. MORRISON.

The preface to “Crime and its Causes” contains an abridgment of the
opinion of the author upon the influence of economic conditions. He
says there:

“Economic prosperity, however widely diffused, will not extinguish
crime. Many people imagine that all the evils afflicting society spring
from want, but this is only partially true. A small number of crimes
are probably due to sheer lack of food, but it has to be borne in mind
that crime would still remain an evil of enormous magnitude even if
there were no such calamities as destitution and distress. As a matter
of fact easy circumstances have less influence on conduct than is
generally believed; prosperity generates criminal inclinations as well
as adversity, and on the whole the rich are just as much addicted to
crime as the poor.” [182]

The chapter “Climate and Crime” contains some observations that are of
interest in connection with our subject. In speaking of the great
number of crimes against persons in Italy, the author says:

“Nor can it be said to be entirely due to economic distress. A
condition of social misery has undoubtedly something to do with the
production of crime. In countries where there is much wealth side by
side with much misery, as in France and England, adverse social
circumstances drive a certain portion of the community into criminal
courses. But where this great inequality of social conditions does not
exist—where all are poor as in Ireland or Italy—poverty alone is not a
weighty factor in ordinary crime. In Ireland, for example, there is
almost as much poverty as exists in Italy, and if the amount of crime
were determined by economic circumstances alone, Ireland ought to have
as black a record as her southern sister. Instead of that she is on the
whole as free from crime as the most prosperous countries of Europe.”
[183]

—This quotation is one of the best samples of Morrison’s logic and
knowledge of facts! Italy is poor; Ireland is poor; the former has many
crimes, the latter few. Hence, economic conditions are not an important
factor. To say nothing of the care necessary in comparing two countries
where the penal law, police, courts, etc. are very different, there is
an error of logic in the quotation. For poverty may be in one of these
countries a determinant that leads to a certain phenomenon, while in
another country it does not lead to it, because neutralized by a
counter-determinant. And then, the knowledge of facts that Morrison
gives evidence of here, is not great. It is not at all true that in
Italy every one is poor. On the contrary, there is plenty of wealth in
that country, while Ireland, on the other hand, is drained by landlords
who live elsewhere. [184]—

The chapter that interests us next is that entitled “Destitution and
Crime.” “A ‘destitute person’ is a person who is without house or home,
who has no work, who is able and willing to work but can get none, and
has nothing but starvation staring him in the face.” [185]

According to Morrison there are two kinds of crime of which a destitute
person may be guilty, namely theft and mendicity. Two questions must be
answered, then, first, what percentage is there of these crimes?
second, how far can one attribute theft and mendicity to destitution?

During the years 1887–1888 the number of cases tried in England and
Wales was 726,698, of which 8% were crimes against property and 7%
offenses against the “Vagrancy Acts.” Consequently 15% of all the
crimes might have been committed because of destitution. From
investigations made by himself, half the thieves had work and were
earning something at the time they committed their crimes.

Now we still have to explain the other half of the cases of theft.
Those who committed these thefts were without work, then; but there
were among them habitual criminals, and these could probably have found
work, but did not want to work. Therefore they were not “destitute
persons.” This leaves still 25% of the thieves. Among these destitution
is now truly the direct cause. However lack of work is not the sole
cause, but the fact that children of proletarians are left to
themselves when their parents are sick or dead, enters in. And then
many aged working-men become criminals because they are too old to work
and no one supports them. Drunkards also at times come to commit crimes
because of poverty, since they find it difficult to work. The estimate
is, then, as follows:


    Proportion of criminals earning at the time of arrest        4%
        ,,     ,,    ,,     habitual thieves                     2%
        ,,     ,,    ,,     adults without shelter and old men   1%
        ,,     ,, drunkards, vagrants                            1%
        ,,     ,, crimes against property compared with total
                                              number of crimes   8%


Then come the infractions of the “Vagrancy Acts.” The offenses that are
punished under these laws are chiefly prostitution, presence in public
places with criminal intentions, presence in a particular house with
criminal intentions, and carrying burglars’ implements. Prostitution
aside, destitution ought not to be considered as the cause of these
infractions, according to the author, because the guilty persons are
those who ordinarily will not work and would not change their lot for
anyone else’s. The class of vagrants is no more unhappy than any other;
it has even its own philosophy. (—Who could be unhappy, then? This
statement of the case gives one a great desire to ask the author how it
happens that no people of means have adopted this enviable career.—)
The same reasoning applies to most of the mendicants (45% of those who
break the vagrancy laws), they do not want to work. Another fraction is
made up of those who cannot find work; their number is difficult to
determine; according to Morrison’s opinion it is not very high (he
estimates it at 2% for mendicants). It is especially aged persons who
belong to this class. There are two principal reasons for this.

First, the increasing use of machines, which throw workmen out of
employment, while increasing the possibility of utilizing the labor of
women and children.

—However true this observation, it is nevertheless very incomplete. It
is not the machine that is the cause, but the system of free labor,
which throws everyone on his own resources when he can work no longer,
whether this is from lack of work or from the disability of the
worker.—

A second cause of vagrancy and mendicity is to be found in the Trades
Unions. For these Unions have been able to obtain a uniform wage, and
aged workmen must, in accordance with their rules, earn as much as the
young ones although not able to do as much work. The employers, not
being able to afford to give them the whole amount, discharge them.

The circumstance that there are more male than female beggars is a
proof to the author that economic conditions are not the cause of
mendicity, etc., for women ordinarily live under worse conditions than
men.

“The only possible explanation of this state of thing is that vagrancy
is, to a very large extent, entirely unconnected with economic
conditions; the position of trade either for good or evil is a very
secondary factor in producing this disease in the body politic; its
extirpation would not be effected by the advent of an economic
millennium; its roots are, as a rule, in the disposition of the
individual and not to any serious degree in the industrial constitution
of society.” [186]

After having stated that, in his opinion, prostitution also has little
to do with economic conditions, Morrison arrives at the conclusion that
14% of the delinquents under the Vagrancy Acts have been made so by
destitution; as such delinquents constitute 7% of the total of the
criminal population, these destitute persons form 2% of the whole.
[187] Adding these 2% to the 2% of destitute persons among the thieves,
we get a total of 4%. Further, the author estimates the destitute
persons among the other criminals (those not punished for theft or
infractions of the Vagrancy Acts) at 1%. Of all criminals, then, 5%
have become such from destitution, according to Morrison.

—I shall not insist upon proving that these calculations have little
value. In the first place all the figures are only estimates, without
any indication of what they are based on. In the second place Morrison
has only proved, supposing his estimates are correct, that 5% of the
criminals belong to a category defined by the author himself. All this
gives him absolutely no right to conclude that economic conditions are
not a powerful factor in crime. Just where the writer believes that the
question has been solved the difficulties properly commence. If we wish
to treat the question of vagrancy in a scientific manner we must ask:
how does it happen that with the present mode of production there are
found persons who prefer vagrancy to work? This is one of the questions
that must be answered, yet for Morrison it does not exist. The causes
of professional theft, alcoholism, etc. seem, according to the author,
to have nothing to do with economic conditions. I shall show in the
second part of this work how far wrong he is.—

The following chapter treats of “poverty and crime.” To prove the
slightness of the causal connection between the two, Morrison gives the
following table:


Italy      1880–84   New cases of theft per an. to 100,000 inh.   221
France     1879–83   ,,   ,,   ,,  ,,   ,,  ,,  ,,   ,,     ,,    121
Belgium    1876–80   ,,   ,,   ,,  ,,   ,,  ,,  ,,   ,,     ,,    143
Germany    1882–83   ,,   ,,   ,,  ,,   ,,  ,,  ,,   ,,     ,,    262
England    1880–84   ,,   ,,   ,,  ,,   ,,  ,,  ,,   ,,     ,,    228
Scotland   1880–84   ,,   ,,   ,,  ,,   ,,  ,,  ,,   ,,     ,,    289
Ireland    1880–84   ,,   ,,   ,,  ,,   ,,  ,,  ,,   ,,     ,,    101
Hungary    1876–80   ,,   ,,   ,,  ,,   ,,  ,,  ,,   ,,     ,,     82
Spain      1883–84   ,,   ,,   ,,  ,,   ,,  ,,  ,,   ,,     ,,     74


England is six times as rich as Italy, and the figure for theft is
greater; hence, economic conditions are not causes, etc. etc. [188]

—It has been some years since Quetelet pointed out (see Chap. II, Sec.
II, of this work) that absolute wealth throws no light on the criminal
question, because the total wealth of a country gives no idea of its
distribution. Yet Morrison thinks that the preceding table proves the
correctness of his statement!—

The author sees a second proof in support of his reasoning in the fact
that during the prosperous period of 1870–74 criminality in England was
greater than during the period of economic depression from 1884 to
1888. (—See our summaries of the works of Tugan-Baranowsky and of
Müller, where it is shown that the economic conditions of that period
do have a relation to criminality. There is perhaps no country where
the connection between crime and the course of economic events is so
close as in England; and it is surprising that there are authors like
Morrison who are so little in touch with the situation, and who yet
express themselves so decidedly.—)

In America the immigrants commit fewer crimes on the average than those
who are born in the country; the position of these last being better,
economic conditions are not causes of crime. (—As if assertions as
vague as this: “the American has a better position than the immigrant”,
could have any value!—)

Morrison sees another proof in the fact that the criminality in the
English colony of Victoria, where prosperity is fairly general, differs
little from that of other countries where the prosperity is less. (—See
A. Sutherland, “Résultats de la déportation en Australie”, Compte Rendu
du Ve Congr. d’Anthr. Crim., p. 270, where it is shown that criminality
in Australia on account of the deportation of English criminals is
great, but has fallen continually since 1850, and now is not so high as
in Italy, Sweden, Saxony, and Prussia. So this proof given by the
author is not convincing.—)

Then the author draws attention to the fact that, according to him, the
number of criminals in the different classes of society in England is
proportional to the respective numbers of individuals in each of these
classes. Finally he also thinks that his thesis is supported by the
fact that during the summer months the prisons in England are more
populated than in winter.

—The author deceives himself, for to find out that more crimes are
committed in winter than in summer one has only to consult, not the
statistics of the prisons, but those of the courts; the former give no
information as to the time when the offense was committed; it is even
probable that a part of the prisoners incarcerated in summer committed
their offenses in winter. Many writers who have not fallen into this
error have come to the conclusion that crimes and misdemeanors against
property, which are those chiefly in question, increase in winter and
decrease in summer.

If one wished to make a complete criticism of Morrison’s work it would
be necessary to write a whole book, so great is the number of his
errors and omissions, which is why I refer to the second part of my
work.

The fundamental error of the author is that he believes that the
question of how far economic conditions lead to crime is exhausted when
the effect of poverty has been investigated. This is only a part
(though an important one) of the question, which though apparently
simple is in reality very complicated.

Finally, I must protest against the unmerited reproach that the English
Trades Unions are the cause of criminality among aged working-men. We
live in a society in which a great proportion of the men wear
themselves out for a small wage in order to enrich others, and where
aged working-men who can now do little or no work are tossed aside like
oranges from which the juice has been squeezed. When they commit
crimes, therefore, it is society that is the cause of it, and not the
unions, which, after years of struggle, have succeeded in getting
higher wages for their members than those of non-union labor. [189]—




III.

F. VON LISZT.

The following quotation, taken from “Die gesellschaftlichen Ursachen
des Verbrechens”, [190] gives the opinion of this author in a few
words:

“Crime is the necessary result of the joint action of two groups of
conditions. The first group is due, partly to the innate, partly to the
acquired character of the agent; the other to the environment
surrounding him. The microbe of crime flourishes only in the culture
medium of society. This sentence, which has gradually become a
commonplace, indicates the significance of social conditions for the
origination and development of criminality.” [191]

“It is obvious that a diminution in the number of certain crimes may be
brought about by an improvement in the social order. The impulse toward
crime is undoubtedly quickly strengthened by social conditions, and
also quickly made weaker. Political and religious offenses become so
much the more numerous, the more definitely and relentlessly the
dominant opinion takes its stand against diverse persuasions. If today
a certain tendency in art were to attain state recognition and the
protection of the criminal law, tomorrow the aesthetic heretic would be
persecuted as the religious heretics were persecuted in earlier
centuries. The sexual instinct will constantly long for satisfaction
and take it where it finds it. If you prohibit the possibility of such
satisfaction within the bounds of legality, the instinct will break the
bonds and lead to crime. And whoever finds neither bread nor work will,
in the great majority of cases, be able to discover ways and means of
securing the one without the other at the expense of society.... ‘The
beast in man’ is in all circles, in all strata of our society.... But
the beast, with all its wild passions, with rage and hate, with
covetousness and envy, with thirst for blood and insatiable vanity, is
it not derived from father or mother, who have drained the pleasures of
life or the woes of life to the dregs, who were corrupted in blood
through their own fault, or without their own fault, before they gave
life to the germ to which they imparted the curse of their forefathers
as a heritage?

“A reorganization of our social order will materially lessen the
impulsion to crime in the men who are living today, but infinitely more
important and infinitely more permanent will be its effect upon coming
generations. While diminishing the number of those tainted by heredity
it will tame the beast in man. This is no Utopia. It will be easier,
perhaps, to underestimate the effect of such a transformation, than to
appreciate its full value.

“But which transformation? That is the question that we must answer, if
we are not to be pushed aside as harmless visionaries.

“Our entire education, in school as in life, rests upon suggestion.
What keeps us from crime is the inhibitory ideas, which are instilled
into us until they permeate our flesh and blood and control our
actions, without our being conscious of it. ‘Thou shalt’, ‘thou shalt
not’, these general prescriptions of right and morality, of religion
and philanthropy, or whatever you choose to call it, must determine our
conduct, unless we stop to consider, hesitate, and delay....

“The inhibitory ideas, however, retain their force only if we live in
the community of our fellows, the enclosed circle held together by like
views and a community of interests. Put upon his own resources, the
true man makes himself known. But the men who can do this are rare. The
great majority of us need outside support. Who has not seen in his own
experience how the judgment and prejudice, the beliefs and
superstitions of his associates have a determining effect upon him; how
he supports others and is supported by them? Break up the enclosed
circle and you weaken or annihilate the inhibitory ideas; shatter
society to atoms, so that each stands by himself in the war of all
against all, and you set loose whatever evil instincts have their roots
in us; ‘declass’ man and you have driven him into the arms of crime.

“And this declassing has been most abundantly provided for by our
present economic system. It has unshackled egoism without setting any
bounds to it. It reaps what it sows. In the proletariat it has created
the very medium in which the microbe of crime flourishes. Next to the
wealth of individuals lies the misery of the masses. Do we still
wonder, then, that the criminal-statistician laments an increasing
number of cases. Every society has the criminals that it deserves.”
[192]

—The opinion of Professor von Liszt and of other bio-sociologists with
regard to crime is a union of the doctrine of the Italian and French
schools. Having already given a criticism of these schools I will limit
myself to a few remarks.

The formula, “every crime is the product of an individual factor on the
one side, and of social factors on the other”, is of little value for
the question, being applicable to every act, even the most laudable,
and explains very little of what is peculiar to crime. A more special
examination of the so-called individual factor of crime shows that it
is formed, for example, of great needs, of highly developed muscular
strength—in short, of things which do not belong to crime alone; or it
may be a lack of moral conceptions (the result of an unfavorable
environment, of bad education, etc.). A veritable individual factor is
to be found only in some special cases, where crime is the result of a
predisposition, resulting from a morbid mental condition, combined with
unfavorable circumstances. At times, then, crime is the resultant of an
individual factor with a social factor; in most cases this is not so.
In maintaining that it is always these two together which give birth to
crime, one makes use of a commonplace, since by individual factors are
understood conditions necessary to every act; or else the statement is
quite inaccurate.

Finally it may be said also that most of the bio-sociologists, while
recognizing the great influence exercised by environment do not give
any description of this environment. It is not enough to name social
imperfections existing in our days, and to demand their reform, one
after another; we must first of all find out whether these
imperfections are connected with the present economic system, and can
be removed without attacking the system itself. [193]—




IV.

P. NÄCKE. [194]

In his work, “Verbrechen und Wahnsinn beim Weibe”, Dr. Näcke treats the
criminal question from the medico-anthropological point of view.
However, his remarks upon the connection which exists between economic
conditions and crime are very important. In the fifth chapter,
entitled, “Die anthropologisch-biologischen Beziehungen zum Verbrechen
und Wahnsinn beim Weibe”, he puts the question: can one fix the idea of
“crime” anatomically?

According to him the answer must be an absolute negative. “Semal is
right when he says: ‘The moral sense is a slow and gradual acquisition
of the ages.... The conscience of peoples like that of the individual,
calls every act moral that is useful to the agent himself or to
others....’ Every people, then, fixes the concept ‘crime’ according to
the moral code prevailing among them at the time; it is consequently
not rooted in man physiologically, but is as Manouvrier brilliantly
demonstrates, purely sociological. It is therefore really nonsense to
seek for anthropological stigmata for a sociological concept.

“But another consideration also leads us to the same result. The
stability of a people demands the establishing of certain boundaries,
called ‘laws’, the transgression of which might disturb the social
order, and therefore must be punished. But the laws form only single
boundary marks, not a tight enclosure, so that between them many,
consciously or not, pass through without being caught or punished.
Besides, the laws of a higher morality do not always correspond with
the prevailing legal system, so that many things are offenses in the
eyes of the moral code that are not such in the eyes of the law, a fact
which, as is well known, the conscienceless take advantage of. It is
plain, therefore, that there are innumerable transgressions that are
not punished, innumerable criminals who pass as honest men, so that we
cannot really speak of criminals and honest men, but simply of the
punished and the unpunished.

“Punishment is, however, as we have already seen, a poor criterion.
Habitual criminals are often not nearly so depraved as many persons of
good reputation, especially in certain districts whose moral concepts
are of a very elastic kind; or as others who have, to be sure, been
punished but once, but who, in all their actions, have always been
crafty criminals.” [195]

“As there is to be found no such thing as absolute bodily and mental
soundness, so there is no such thing as an absolutely ‘honest’ man. ‘We
are altogether sinners’, say the Scriptures with entire truth—and not
in thought only—none of us is proof against becoming a criminal, and
under certain circumstances, even a great one.” [196]

“There is an unbroken gradation from the purest to the worst man. When
we speak simply of ‘criminals’ we mean only those standing on the
farthest step, who are not always, however, the worst. It is a
question, then, of the refuse of the world, and not of real crime. In
every environment there are always individuals who become evil-doers
exclusively or chiefly through circumstances—this possibility no mortal
can escape—and on the other hand there are those who owe this in part
(seldom, however, exclusively) to their inferior psychic personality,
which allows them to run counter to the prevailing morality and drives
them to breach of the law; these last constitute the criminals in the
narrow sense.” [197]

In chapter VI, “Zusammenhang von Verbrechen und Wahnsinn”, the author
explains that in case an individual factor exists, it is not ordinarily
this alone that leads to crime, but it must be coupled with a social
factor.

This is what Dr. Näcke says of the causes of this individual factor:
“Indeed it is even probable that in the last analysis the individual
factor is dependent upon the environment, since this so influenced the
parents, grandparents, etc. that the germ of the next generation must
have been injured directly or later through corrupted blood or narrow
pelvis on the part of the mother (both again dependent upon the
environment).” [198]

Further along he makes this idea more specific, when he is examining
the different causes of crime. Among these causes the author cites the
following:


    1. Lesion of the germ (favored especially by the marriage of
       degenerates).
    2. Alcoholism.
    3. Syphilis.
    4. Malnutrition and unhealthy mode of life.
    5. Excessive labor of women and children.
    6. Bad domestic life.
    7. Desertion in which children under age are left.


The author sums up in the following terms: “In what has gone before we
have attempted to pick out and follow up some threads of the complex
social fabric, in the firm persuasion that only an improvement of the
environment in its thousand-fold ramifications will be able effectively
to combat crime, and gradually to exert a favorable influence upon the
individual factors, which are certainly not to be undervalued.

“If we survey the whole matter, everything comes in the end to the
stomach-question; only so long as this is not solved—and perhaps it
never can be satisfactorily solved—must we keep the point of view given
above practically before us, which, upon the solution of the matter,
becomes in large measure no longer necessary.” [199]




V.

HAVELOCK ELLIS. [200]

The work of Dr. Havelock Ellis, entitled “The Criminal”, contains only
one passage which is of importance for the question of criminality
considered from the economic point of view. Like most bio-sociologists
he considers the social factors as the most important. This is the
passage in question:

“The problem of criminality is not an isolated one that can be dealt
with by fixing our attention on that and that alone. It is a problem
that on closer view is found to merge itself very largely into all
those problems of our social life that are now pressing for solution,
and in settling them we shall to a great extent settle it. The rising
flood of criminality is not an argument for pessimism or despair. It is
merely an additional spur to that great task of social organization to
which during the coming century we are called.

“It is useless, or worse than useless, to occupy ourselves with methods
for improving the treatment of criminals, so long as the conditions of
life render the prison a welcome and desired shelter. So long as we
foster the growth of reckless classes we foster the growth of
criminality. So long as there are a large body of women in the East of
London, and in other large centers, who are prepared to say, ‘It’s Jack
the Ripper or the bridge with me. What’s the odds?’ there will be a
still larger number of persons who will willingly accept the risks of
prison. ‘What’s the odds?’ Liberty is dear to every man who is fed and
clothed and housed, and he will not usually enter a career of crime
unless he has carefully calculated the risks of losing his liberty, and
found them small; but food and shelter are even more precious than
liberty, and these may be secured in prison. As things are, the asylum
and the workhouse, against which there is a deep prejudice, ingrained
and irrational, would have a greater deterring effect than the prison.
There are every morning in Paris 50,000 persons who do not know how
they will eat or where they will sleep. It is the same in every great
city; for such the prison can be nothing but a home. It is well known
that the life of the convict, miserable as it is, with its dull routine
and perpetual surveillance, is yet easier, less laborious, and far more
healthy than that to which thousands of honest working-men are
condemned throughout Great Britain.” [201]




VI.

CARROLL D. WRIGHT.

The author of the brochure, “The Relation of Economic Conditions to the
Causes of Crime”, begins by declaring that there are two kinds of
criminals; persons who have become such from their psycho-physical
constitution, and others who have become such from circumstances.

“I believe the criminal is an undeveloped man in all his elements,
whether you think of him as a worker or as a moral and intellectual
being. His faculties are all undeveloped, not only those which enable
him to labor honestly and faithfully for the care and support of
himself and his family, but also all his moral and intellectual
faculties. He is not a fallen being: he is an undeveloped individual.”
[202]

The author then continues by saying that since there is a relation more
or less close between all the important social questions and the labor
question, it is necessary to take that up also in studying the criminal
question.

We know that there are three great systems of labor: the system resting
upon slavery, the feudal system, and the system now in force, i.e. that
of free labor. In the first two, which intrinsically do not differ
much, crime had a totally different character from what it has under
the last. Under the feudal system the peasants lived in the most
deplorable condition, without hope of betterment. In many countries
conditions were so bad that great bands of thieves and brigands overran
them. During the reign of Henry VIII, which lasted 38 years, 72,000
criminals were executed. “Pauperism, therefore, did not attract
legislation, and crime, the offspring of pauperism and idleness, was
brutally treated; and these conditions, betokening an unsound social
condition, existed until progress made pauperism, and crime as well,
the disgrace of the nation, and it was then that pauperism began to be
recognized as a condition that might be relieved through legislation.”
[203]

In the end the feudal system was overthrown and that of free labor, the
present system, became general. Since then the differences between
poverty and wealth have appeared more distinctly.

“Carry industry to a country not given to mechanical production or to
any systematic form of labor, employ three-fourths of its inhabitants,
give them a taste of education, of civilization, make them feel the
power of moral forces even in a slight degree, and the misery of the
other fourth can be gauged by the progress of the three-fourths, and a
class of paupers and resultant criminals will be observed. We have in
our own day a most emphatic illustration of this in the emancipation of
slaves in this country (America). Under the old system the negro slave
was physically comfortable, as a rule. He was cared for, he was nursed
in sickness, fed and clothed, and in old age his physical comforts were
continued. He had no responsibility, and, indeed, exercised no skill
beyond what was taught him. To eat, to work and to sleep were all that
was expected of him, and, unless he had a cruel master, he lived the
life that belongs to the animal. Since his emancipation and his
endowment with citizenship he has been obliged to support himself and
his family, and to contend with all obstacles belonging to a person in
a state of freedom. Under the system of villeinage in the old country
it could not be said that there were any general poor, for the master
and the lord of the manor took care of the laborers their whole lives;
and in our Southern towns, during slavery, this was true, so that in
the South there were few, if any, poorhouses, and few, if any, inmates
of penal institutions. The South today knows what pauperism is, as
England learned when the system of villeinage departed. Southern
prisons have become active, and all that belongs to the defective, the
dependent, and the delinquent classes has come to be familiar to the
South....” “But so far as the modern industrial order superinduces
idleness or unemployment, in so far it must be considered as having a
direct relation to the causes of crime.” [204]

After having tried to show, by the aid of some historical examples,
that the conditions in the system which preceded ours were of a nature
much more serious than those of our own day, he continues as follows:

“In the study of economic conditions, and whatever bearing they may
have upon crime, I can do no better than to repeat, as a general idea,
a statement made some years ago by Mr. Ira Steward, of Massachusetts,
one of the leading labor reformers in that state in his day. He said:
‘Starting in the labor problem from whatever point we may, we reach, as
the ultimate cause of our industrial, social, moral, and material
difficulties, the terrible fact of poverty. By poverty we mean
something more than pauperism. The latter is a condition of entire
dependence upon charity, while the former is a condition of want, of
lack, of being without, though not necessarily a condition of complete
dependence.’

“It is in this view that the proper understanding of the subject given
me, in its comprehensiveness and the development of the principles
which underlie it, means the consideration of the abolition of
pauperism and the eradication of crime; and the definitions given by
Mr. Steward carry with them all the elements of those great special
inquiries embodied in the very existence of our vast charitable, penal,
and reformatory institutions, ‘How shall poverty be abolished, and
crime be eradicated?’” [205]

Let the circumstances be favorable or unfavorable, let the governments
be liberal or despotic, let the religion and commercial systems be what
they may, crime has always existed. This is why it would exist even if
there were no longer any unemployment, if everyone had received an
education, if the efforts of temperance societies and social reformers
had been realized, and Christianity were universal. But all these good
influences together would certainly reduce crime to the minimum.

Criminality will decrease but little if the improvements have to do
simply with the physical condition and not at the same time with moral
and intellectual conditions. It is, on the other hand, not to be
disputed, according to the author, that a development of these last
qualities will have a favorable influence upon criminality. For the man
who has received an education will betake himself to crime less quickly
than the ignorant man, while on account of his education he will
generally be able to find work to protect him against poverty and
crime. The lack of work is an important cause of crime; for example,
among the convicts of Massachusetts there were 68% who had been without
work, and in the whole United States in 1890, 74% of the murderers had
been without work. This lack of employment may have been because of an
antipathy to work or of a lack of opportunity. And it is this last case
especially that occurs only too often in the present social
organization.

Great improvements are urgently demanded; living conditions must become
better and more sanitary, and work must be better paid. The fundamental
complaint of the writer against political economy is that it has not
considered moral forces as one of its elements. As soon as it shall
have considered them as such it will have entered upon the way that
leads to real improvements.

After having indicated what these improvements ought to be, the author
goes on in these terms: “In a state in which labor had all its rights
there would be, of course, little pauperism and little crime. On the
other hand, the undue subjection of the laboring man must tend to make
paupers and criminals, and entail a financial burden upon wealth which
it would have been easier to prevent than to endure; and this
prevention must come in a large degree through educated labor.

“Do not understand me as desiring to give the impression that I believe
crime to be a necessary accompaniment of our industrial system. I have
labored in other places and at other times to prove the reverse, and I
believe the reverse to be true. Our sober, industrious working men and
women are as free from vicious and criminal courses as any other class.
What I am contending for, relates entirely to conditions affecting the
few. The great volume of crime is found outside the real ranks of
industry.” [206]

It might still be asked whether civilization favors crime. The answer
would have to be at once affirmative and negative. Affirmative in
exceptional times, otherwise negative. The more civilization advances,
the better the condition of the working people will become, the more
equitable will be the division of profits, and the more crime will
diminish. The attempts of Robert Owen and many others prove the truth
of this.

The author closes his study with these words: “Trade instruction,
technical education, manual training—all these are efficient elements
in the reduction of crime, because they all help to better and truer
economic conditions. I think, from what I have said, the elements of
solution are clearly discernible. Justice to labor, equitable
distribution of profits under some system which I feel sure will
supersede the present, and without resorting to socialism, instruction
in trades by which a man can earn his living outside a penal
institution, the practical application of the great moral law in all
business relations—all these elements, with the more enlightened
treatment of the criminal when apprehended, will lead to a reduction in
the volume of crime, but not to the millennium; for ‘human experience
from time immemorial tells us that the earth neither was, nor is, nor
ever will be, a heaven, nor yet a hell’, (Dr. A. Schäffle) but the
endeavor of right-minded men and women, the endeavor of every
government, should be to make it less a hell and more a heaven.” [207]

—The study of Carroll D. Wright contains some very true observations
upon the relation between crime and economic conditions (for example,
upon the difference between the slave and the free laborer, whose
liberty consists chiefly in this, that he can die of hunger if he
cannot find work or is no longer able to work). But in general the work
gives the impression of vagueness and hesitation proper to the school
of economists and sociologists to which the writer belongs. They
condemn certain manifestations of capitalism, but wish to maintain the
“causa causarum”, the system itself. This is not the place to speak of
this more fully and I will confine myself to pointing out some
historical errors of the author.

In the first place, a classification of economic systems into only
three is incomplete. It is very surprising that this error should have
been made by an American. For the North American Indians neither lived
under the feudal system nor under that of free labor, and for the most
part never knew slavery; the author has forgotten to mention the
primitive-communistic mode of production.

In the second place, it is incorrect to call all those who lived under
the feudal system “poor.”

In the third place it was not to the feudal system that the famous
executions under Henry VIII belong, but rather to incipient capitalism
which, by dispossessing a great number of peasants, made them poor.
(Compare More, “Utopia”, and Marx, “Capital.”)—



Among the partisans of the bio-sociological doctrine, I think that
certain other authors should also be classed, for example: L. Gordon
Rylands, “Crime, Its Causes and Remedy”; Dallemagne (see p. 224 of the
“Actes du IIIme Congrès d’Anthrop. Crimin.”); Drill (see “Des principes
fondamentaux de l’école d’anthropologie criminelle” and “Les fondements
et le but de la responsabilité pénale”); Kovalewsky, “La psychologie
criminelle”; Orchanski, “Les criminels russes.” With regard to Russian
criminologists see Frassati, “Die neue positive Schule des Strafrechts
in Russland.”

The Dutch criminologists must be reckoned as among the
bio-sociologists.

G. A. v. Hamel, “De tegenwoordige beweging op het gebied van het
strafrecht”, and “L’anarchisme et le combat contre l’anarchisme au
point de vue de l’anthropologie criminelle”; G. Jelgersma, “De geboren
misdadiger”; A. Aletrino, “Twee opstellen over crimineele
anthropologie”, and “Handleiding bij de studie der crimineele
anthropologie”; S. R. Steinmetz, “De ziekten der maatschappij.” Dr. C.
Winkler inclines, as it seems to me, rather toward the opinion of the
Italian criminologists. See: “Iets over crimineele anthropologie.”

[Note to the American Edition: Of the recent literature there should be
mentioned: in Germany, especially Aschaffenburg, “Das Verbrechen und
seine Bekämpfung”, and Wulffen, “Psychologie des Verbrechens.” In
Holland the authors already named, van Kan, and de Roos are to be
classed among the bio-sociologists. For Russia there should be added
von Bechterew, “Das Verbrechertum im Lichte der objektiven
Psychologie.” In America it seems to me more reliance is placed upon
the Italian theory than in Europe; see, for example, Henderson,
“Introduction into the Study of the Dependent, Defective, and
Delinquent Classes.” Upon the recent development of criminology in
Holland, England, Sweden, Denmark, Russia, Greece, and Servia see the
study already cited of von Thót, “Die positive Strafrechtsschule in
einigen europäischen Ländern.”]








CHAPTER VI.

THE SPIRITUALISTS. [208]


I.

H. JOLY.

It is in the second chapter of his “France criminelle”, bearing the
title of “Richesse et misère”, that the author gives his opinion of the
connection between criminality and economic conditions. [209]

According to Joly, the opinion expressed by many persons that poverty
is the great factor in criminality, appears to be true, at least at
first sight; for the problem is, in fact, very complex and difficult.

In the first place a distinction must be made between voluntary and
involuntary poverty. “With vagrants by profession, beggars from choice
and speculation, drunkards, those who have made up their minds to live
no matter how, gamblers who have systematically used up their capital
and that of their family, workmen who have given up work only from
rebellion against society, yes, with all these poverty leads to crime.”
[210] The second kind of poverty springs from disease, accidents, etc.,
i.e. from causes independent of the will of man.

“There are, then, evidently innocent poor people; and there are others
so much the more pardonable as the consequences have been aggravated by
the fault of others. Is it then in the intermediate region that we must
seek for the influences that lead to evil? It may be. This region is
not unknown to us. Let us seek here, without taking sides in any way,
and examine the facts as well as we can.” [211]

In opposition to the continual increase of criminality the author shows
that the national wealth has increased, although—and this should not be
forgotten—real property, with the exception of small holdings, has
decreased; the condition of the rural workers, on the contrary, has
improved.

In the second place Joly calls attention to the condition of
working-men in the cities. According to him the question of whether it
has grown worse must be answered in the negative, for the emigration
from the country to the city always keeps up. Notwithstanding their
higher wages men are no better off there, since they spend upon
amusements their additional earnings. If criminality increases among
them it is not, then, in involuntary poverty that the cause is to be
found.

At the same time with the increase of wages the price of food must be
noted. In most of the departments of France these prices have risen in
the same proportion as wages. Consequently the working-man has not
become better off. He has new needs, but when he has met these he has
not enough left for the primary necessities. It is not economic
factors, but moral factors, that come into play here.

The proportional increase of wages and the price of food, of which
mention has been made above, in the different departments of France, is
not met with in the departments of Morbihan, Vendée, Bouches-du-Rhône,
and Hérault. In the first two, prices have risen much more than wages,
while the contrary appears in the last two. As regards criminality, the
first two take their place among those that show the lowest figures,
the last two among those that show the highest. Joly draws from this
the conclusion that social life is too complicated for us to be able to
learn the morality of persons merely from the rise or fall of wages. In
any case it is certain, according to him, that the increase of
criminality that has been shown is not due to poverty, and that
consequently we have not the right to say that poverty in general is
one of the primary causes of crime.

However, it must not be lost sight of that in speaking of the increase
of wealth and the rise in wages, we are speaking only of average
figures, and that there are many individuals whose wages remain below
this average. “Now, where do we see the greatest differences, and where
are they most felt? Exactly in wealthy epochs and in wealthy
surroundings. So it is in the poor departments that crimes against
property develop the least. There are two reasons for this,
psychological and social. What any man feels the most is not being or
having absolutely; it is being or having more or less than those who
surround him. What must drive men to crime chiefly, then, is the
comparison of wealth with poverty.” [212]

Joly thinks he can produce further data upon the connection between
crime and poverty by checking up the kind of articles that are most
frequently stolen. Out of 1000 cases of theft (assizes, 1830–1860)
there were 395 cases of theft of money, next came thefts of personal
property, then clothing, etc., then successively, different kinds of
merchandise, jewelry and table-ware, food, grain, etc., and living
domestic animals. This information does not teach us much about the
relationship in question. For the articles stolen can be sold, which
prevents our discovering the motives of the crime.

The analysis of the value of the objects stolen also gives us little
information. During a period of 25 years the cases of theft of 10 to 50
francs were the most numerous (about 30%), next those of 100 to 1000
francs, then those of less than 10 francs. Ten years later the most
numerous were those of 100 to 1000 francs (33%).

However, on the strength of the statements of an old police officer,
Joly thinks he can draw the conclusion that poverty enters only to a
small extent into the etiology of crime. Nevertheless the established
fact that a rise in the price of grain is associated with an increase
of criminality, contradicts this. But according to Joly the
contradiction is only apparent. “Famines are exceptional; theft is
constant and while famines are always decreasing, theft is always
increasing. Suppose that in ordinary years people did not steal or
stole very little; the difficult moments would find them more patient,
more resolute to have recourse to legal and permissible means; we
should not see them so prompt to extricate themselves from their
difficulties by simply taking the property of others. But what
resistance can we count on from those who have long had the habit of
stealing from fancy, cupidity, or a desire to gormandize? What
resistance can be hoped for, especially when the habit has begun in
youth? Now, we have seen that a third of the thefts are committed by
minor children.” [213]

The weakness of the influence of economic conditions upon criminality
is, according to Joly, further proved by the fact that times of
prosperity are not accompanied by a decrease in the number but by a
change in the kind of crime committed (as Prins and Garofalo have
shown). Cheap wine makes most crimes against persons increase. But the
low price of grain has the same effect, since the working-man, when his
condition has improved even a little, spends his additional earnings in
all kinds of amusements, which, in their turn, may be the source of
crime. This is proved, for example, by the fact that in Marseilles
suicides are most numerous on Sunday and Monday, and fewest on Friday
and Saturday, a fact explained by the pay-days of the working people.
This is also applicable to crimes against persons.

To prove his thesis the author reminds us of the fact that domestics,
although not subject to privations, furnish a large percentage of the
thefts; that the percentage of thefts committed by unmarried persons
continually increases; and finally, that the investigation (of 107
cases tried in 10 years before the assizes at Rheims), made by a
magistrate (Ch. Vuébat), has proved that economic factors have little
importance for criminality, and moral factors much. “To sum up, it is
not the increase of poverty that is the cause of the increase of crime;
it is not property in general that leads to crime against property.
This is not saying that poverty, and innocent poverty, does not exist,
nor that it is not a bad counselor, nor that it is not the duty of the
upper classes and of the government to concern themselves with the lot
of the poor. It does mean that a man is less led into evil-doing by the
faults of others or by the fault of destiny than by his personal
faults.” [214]



—If one considers the study of the question by Joly from a critical
point of view, the thing that most strikes the attention is this; that
he puts economic causes by the side of the moral causes of criminality.
As I have already more than once remarked, this is not sound. Every
crime finds its origin in moral causes, or better, in the lack of moral
ideas dominant at a certain period. But one of the principal questions
to be answered is this; how far do these moral ideas find their origin
in definite economic conditions? Joly, being a spiritualist, has not
succeeded in formulating this problem well, still less in solving it.

His entire treatment of the relation between criminality and economic
conditions is characterized by a striking narrowness. He speaks of
poverty and wealth as if they were the most natural things in the
world, and had no need to be explained. Then he makes a distinction
between voluntary and involuntary poverty, and excludes the former from
the discussion as having nothing to do with the problem in question.
This manner of reasoning has rather the air of a penitential sermon
than of a scientific investigation. “Voluntary poverty” [215] is a
contradiction in terms. For a man tries as far as possible to spare
himself suffering and to gain happiness. There can never be any such
thing then as voluntary poverty.

Though his terms are unhappily chosen, Joly only wishes to point out
that poverty may originate in circumstances or in the person himself.
But in treating this problem he should not have been silent on a very
important, and very difficult point, namely how far these individual
causes of poverty are based upon the present economic system.

If the question treated by Joly is incomplete, what he says neither has
any great value, nor does it prove at all his statement that the
influence of economic conditions is small. He gives but a few pages to
the very difficult question of whether the standard of living of the
working class has been raised. He brings out the universally observed
fact that the wants of all classes have increased, but he seems not to
have noted that this is intimately bound up with the present mode of
production. He cites the testimony of an old police officer, and the
investigations of a magistrate (investigations, it may be said in
passing, that reached the colossal number of 107 cases) in order to
prove that most crimes are not committed as a consequence of immediate
privations—as if this were enough to solve the question of how far
economic conditions enter into the causes of crime.— [216]




II.

L. PROAL. [217]

In his ninth chapter, entitled “Le crime et la misère,” this author
gives some pages to our subject. It is incontestable, according to him,
that poverty exerts an influence upon criminality. The number of crimes
increases in the years of poor crops, or when there is a lack of work
owing to industrial or agricultural crises. Thus, criminality reached
high figures in 1840, 1847, and 1854, when the price of grain was high.

In consequence of this and of his personal experience (the author is a
magistrate) he thinks the opinion of Garofalo is incorrect, that
poverty only gives crime its form and is not a cause of it. For
indigence not only puts morality in danger by depriving some persons of
the bare necessities, but it also causes the children of the poor in
the great cities to be brought up in a pitiable manner.

Although the author is of this opinion, however, he does not subscribe
to the view that “the poor man is dedicated to crime.” On the contrary,
a great proportion of the poor are as honest as possible, and have
honorable toil as their only means of support. Judicial statistics show
that the rich are as guilty of crime as the poor.

“We see, then, that even if all the citizens had means and education,
there would always be criminals; the number of them would be a little
less, but not much. There would always be traders practising deception
with regard to the quantity and quality of their goods, merchants
adulterating food, employes abusing the confidence of their employers,
notaries embezzling the funds entrusted to them; there would always be
wives poisoning their husbands, and husbands killing their wives, and
teachers of lay and denominational schools committing sexual crimes.”
[218]

Most crimes are not committed to escape from want, but rather to
procure luxury and pleasure. Hence the rich as well as the poor commit
them. “To sum up, I do not believe that the rich are less tempted to
take the property of others than the poor. The more wealth one has the
more he wants; further, the more wealth increases, the more factitious
wants increase, and if one’s wealth becomes insufficient to satisfy
these wants, the thought of increasing it by any means is not slow in
coming. Admitting that some day all men may be rich and educated,
though that seems to me to be an impossible dream, cupidity will always
make thieves, rogues, and forgers; hatred and revenge will always
inspire homicide, murder, and arson; debauchery will always lead to
sexual crimes. Material and intellectual progress will never suppress
the passions and will not free men from the struggle that must be
maintained against them. It will always be necessary to repress anger
and sensuality, to put a bridle upon cupidity, and, in a word, to set
the soul free from its passions. The increase of well-being and
education will never make the police and the penal code unnecessary.”
[219]

—It will be superfluous to give a criticism of this discussion. We have
already met several authors who took this point of view. Proal is like
the others who do not even know how to put the question of the
influence of economic conditions clearly, who do not comprehend that
poverty and riches are both the inevitable consequences of the same
system.—




III.

M. DE BAETS. [220]

“It is an incontestable fact that the influence of poverty upon
criminality is immense.” It is thus that the author expresses himself
in the introduction to his work. I shall set forth his manner of
defending this thesis in the following lines.

The most disastrous consequence of poverty is the temptation to procure
illicitly what is needed for one’s well-being. We can see this in the
crimes of crowds as well as in individual crimes. At the 3d Congress of
Criminal Anthropology, Professor H. Denis gave certain facts with
regard to the correlation between crime and the economic status. [221]
During the years from 1845 to 1849 the curve of criminality coincides
exactly with that of the price of wheat. But at the close of 1850 the
two curves diverge, when the curve of wheat is replaced by that of
staple foods in general. If we follow the trend of wages attentively we
shall note that they also are higher in the last years. The increase of
criminality is no longer to be explained, therefore, by this rise. To
what, then, is it due?

In the author’s opinion we must note, first, that forced unemployment
is increasing; second, that poverty and wealth have force only by
comparison.

The well-being of the working man has increased, but that of men in
general much more so. This explains only a part of the phenomena given
above. The rest of his explanation is as follows: “There are, in fact,
other elements, which may neutralize the influence of the environment.
To all the solicitations of vice and crime man can offer resistance,
finding his refuge and support in moral force.

“Now, go to the poor and unhappy, and ask them what prevents them from
quickly slipping downhill into crime, and you will find in their mouths
the expression, naïve, but strong, of the idea of duty; and this idea
of duty you will find precisely and clearly only in that of submission
to an absolute, incontestable, unconditioned authority, that of God. A
man whom no one would suspect of any extraordinary good-will toward
religion, M. Jules Simon, said a few months ago, ‘The peoples must be
brought to God if we want justice and order to reign.’

“Must not even those who do not themselves believe, recognize in this
idea of duty, of law imposed by a God, the creator, an ‘idée-force,’ a
source in itself of energy and activity against evil and for good?

“It is in the diminution of this energy, in the efforts that have been
made to tear out of the hearts of the poor this root, whose flower is
hope, and whose fruit is virtue, that I am inclined to see one of the
causes of the frightful increase of crime, which all concede, some with
surprise and all with dismay.” [222]

In the second part of his discussion the author brings up the
degenerating influence of poverty. Although a man has a free will at
his disposal, it is necessary that he should also have an organism
capable of putting the will into action. Hence it is that degeneracy
makes its effect felt upon man.

“Now, misery is just the totality of the most imperious desires
remaining unsatisfied; it is the love of life, the love of well-being
left without gratification; it is the suffering of the wife one would
like to see happy, the hunger of the children to whom one would like to
give bread. And if crime can give this bread that one cannot find, if
crime can satisfy all these appetites, all these desires, it will
present itself with the most powerful attractions, with the charm of
fascination. Will the unfortunate man have the supreme energy to prefer
duty to enjoyment?” [223]

Poverty is a bad preparatory school for this contest; a weakened
organism will succumb more easily to temptation. And generally this is
accompanied by a lack of education and of the development of the higher
faculties.

In following the course of life of a proletarian we see that the child
of the proletariat carries, often from his birth, the signs of
degeneracy, since his mother was forced to work hard during her
pregnancy. From his childhood he is ill nourished, and grows up in an
unhealthful environment. There can hardly be any question of education,
for his father and mother work in the shop, which prevents any family
life. The child is not attached to the dwelling of his parents and
wanders in the street, where he picks up bad habits. Arrived at
adolescence, he enters the factory to pass the greater part of his time
in monotonous occupations. And once full grown, life for him consists
only in routine labor, monotonous and without end. “However, this man
has a soul, he has a mind! But it slumbers in a perpetual inertia.
Nothing in his life has awakened what is grand, noble, and divine in
this reasonable being. How can we hope to have the moral energy and the
sublime ambition for good survive in him?” [224]

However unhappy this manner of life may be, there is still lacking the
greatest misfortune that can befall the proletarian; forced inaction.
This is one of the chief causes that can drive him to commit crime! And
then there is another scourge of the working class, alcoholism. “Source
of poverty without any doubt, but fruit of poverty incontestably.”
Finally, of all the proletarians the most unhappy are the women. Low
wages and the monotony of tiresome work too often make prostitutes of
them.

To all these criminogenous causes the Christian must oppose the moral
sentiments which are drawn from his religion. His motto must be,
“rather death than dishonor.” But for that he must have heroic courage,
which most people lack. Perhaps before God these sinners will find
grace.

But all this cannot be a reason for society to allow to exist these
scandalous conditions, which, in a few words, are as follows:
“Insufficiency of the means of subsistence; work too long continued, as
measured by the exhaustion resulting from it; work demanded of mothers
of families; excessive and unsuitable labor expected of children;
improper conditions in certain industries.” [225]

This must be changed, and it is possible to do so. Not, however, with
the aid of the state, for then industry would lose the elasticity so
necessary to it. But the change must be brought about by association of
the proletarians. “In the forced individualism of the laborers is to be
found the cause of their ruin; the salvation must be found in
association.” The author closes by referring to the encyclical, “Rerum
novarum”, in which it is said that Christian workmen must band
together, and by encouraging the rich to help their less privileged
brothers. [226]




IV.

CRITICISM.

The authors of whom I have just been speaking, together with others,
like von Oettingen and Stursberg, of whom I have spoken in Chap. II,
have this idea in common, that the continually growing irreligion is a
cause of the increase in criminality; in other words, that irreligion
is a powerful factor of crime and that the irreligious are predisposed
to crime.

What proofs have been given by these authors in support of their
thesis, their very serious accusation against those who are no longer
religious? Most of them have not even tried to prove it. It is a dogma,
with which, therefore, we have nothing to do. An increase of irreligion
had been shown, also an increase in criminality, therefore there is a
causal connection. Protest must be made against any such methods of
reasoning. If there is a parallelism upon the chart between two curves
that do not undulate, we must be very careful about drawing the
conclusion that there is a connection, much more a causal one. That
irreligion has increased is certain; is the same thing true of
criminality? Certainly not. The trend of criminality as a whole is very
rarely uniform, there is almost always a divergence; for example,
economic criminality and violent criminality very rarely keep pace with
each other. If we wish to give a general idea of the trend of
criminality, we can only say that it is decreasing rather than
increasing. The spiritualist authors often cite Germany in support of
their thesis. This is no longer possible, for, after an increase in the
total figures up to the end of the nineteenth century, there is now a
fluctuating decrease.

In the Netherlands we can estimate the increase of irreligion; [227]
according to the censuses of 1879 and 1909, the percentage of those who
are not members of any church has increased enormously, from 0.31 to
4.97, an increase of 1500% in 30 years! What an increase of crime must
we look for! The reality is very different. The curve of crime has
fallen without any doubt. [228] The facts and the thesis do not agree.

Another way of examining the question is to be found in “criminal
geography.” Since irreligion shows enormous differences in the
different parts of a country, we ought to find considerable criminality
in the provinces where the lack of religion is most in evidence. For
the Netherlands, in my study already referred to, I have given detailed
tables with the result that there is no connection between the
phenomena in question. In general we have even the right to say that
the provinces with the lowest figures for irreligion show a high
criminality, and vice versa!

The best means of settling the question is by a direct statistical
study. I have made calculations, based upon the criminal statistics, of
more than 126,000 individuals sentenced during the period from 1901 to
1909, in the Netherlands. Here are the results:


Netherlands, 1901–1909.

====================================+===========================================================
                                    |     Number Sentenced to 100,000 of the Population
                                    |                   Over 10 Years Old.
                                    +-------------+-----------+-------+-----------+-------------
                                    |             |           |       |    Not    |
            Offenses.               |             |           |       |  Members  |   Total
                                    | Protestant. | Catholic. | Jew.  |  of Any   |Population.
                                    |             |           |       | Religion. |
------------------------------------+-------------+-----------+-------+-----------+-------------
All offenses                        |   308.6     |   416.5   | 212.7 |   84.2    |   337.3
Theft                               |    40.0     |    54.8   |  25.5 |    9.6    |    43.9
Aggravated theft                    |    19.9     |    24.0   |  12.7 |    5.2    |    20.7
Receiving stolen goods              |     2.6     |     3.5   |   9.2 |    0.7    |     3.0
Embezzlement                        |     8.6     |     9.3   |  13.1 |    1.9    |     8.7
Fraud                               |     2.4     |     2.5   |   3.9 |    0.4    |     2.4
Offenses against public decency     |     1.9     |     3.4   |   2.0 |    0.5    |     2.4
Minor sexual offenses               |     1.2     |     1.0   |   0.3 |    0.2    |     1.0
Rape                                |     1.5     |     2.2   |   1.5 |    0.7    |     1.8
Sexual crimes with persons under 16 |     0.3     |     0.3   |   0.1 |    0.0    |     0.3
All sexual crimes                   |     5.1     |     7.1   |   4.1 |    1.6    |     5.7
Rebellion                           |    25.9     |    37.0   |  13.2 |   12.2    |    29.0
Assaults                            |    74.4     |    98.2   |  43.2 |   20.1    |    80.1
Serious assaults                    |     8.5     |    11.0   |   3.9 |    1.9    |     9.1
Homicide and murder                 |     0.4     |     0.6   |   0.5 |    0.1    |     0.5
====================================+=============+===========+=======+===========+=============


The results are the following, then: the first place is almost always
occupied by the Catholics, the second by the Protestants, and then come
the Jews (except in cases of receiving stolen goods, embezzlement, and
fraud), and the minimum of criminality (in all crimes without
exception) is shown by the irreligious!

Here we have not the task of explaining this fact, we only bring it
out; and we have the right to declare that the thesis: “irreligion
leads to crime”, is not correct.








CHAPTER VII.

THE THIRD SCHOOL [229] AND THE SOCIALISTS.


I.

F. TURATI.

In the first chapter of his “Il delitto e la questione sociale”, the
author shows that among the numerous misfortunes from which the
proletariat suffers, this must be reckoned, that it is almost
exclusively from its ranks that criminals are recruited. “The criminal
tribute is the almost exclusive privilege of one social class. And as
the bourgeoisie has so far thought out no better plan than to oppose
the degradation of crime with another degradation called punishment, it
has come about that to the monopoly of the criminal tribute is added,
for the poor, the monopoly of the penal tribute.” [230]

After having spoken, in the following chapter, of “free will”, Dr.
Turati gives his attention to an opinion of Dr. Lelorrain, who says
that we must modify man if we wish to make criminality disappear or
decrease. Dr. Turati objects that it is exceedingly difficult to change
man, and that there is an easier and more effective way, namely to
change society. In a society where everything is bad, where the
exploitation of one by the other is the rule, where the enjoyment of
some goes on at the detriment of others, and this under the protection
of the law—in such a society there is a perpetual incitement to crime.
It is the ideal of socialism to create a society in which crime shall
be neither necessary nor advantageous. However short its duration, the
colony of New Lanark founded by Owen, is one of the best proofs of the
correctness of this idea. In a society formed in accordance with this
socialistic ideal, crime would appear only exceptionally, by atavism,
for example, and would cease to be a general and always threatening
danger.

“The social penal question is a question above all of social
transformation.” Many objections have been made to this statement. The
school of Lombroso and Ferri sets up in opposition its theory of the
triplex character of the factors of crime; cosmic, individual, and
social. When society is so modified that the interests of the
individual are identical with those of the community, it would be only
one part of crime that would disappear; one could not, for example,
prevent an extraordinary heat from causing crimes against morals.

According to Dr. Turati it is not impossible to refute this objection,
though it may be difficult to do so. In the first place Ferri
recognizes the social causes as more important than the other two put
together. He estimates that the number of persons driven to crime by
social reasons (passion and occasion) is more than 60%; the others
(insane or half-insane criminals, born-incorrigibles, and habituals)
form a minority, then. But among these there are many criminals by
habit, who were not born as such, but have become such from force of
circumstances. Dr. Turati estimates that from 70% to 75% of criminals
have come to commit their crimes from social causes. When we take
account further of the fact that about 18% of the prisoners are insane,
the number of real criminals who have become such from other than
social causes is reduced to 10% at the most.

According to Dr. Turati the physical and anthropological factors exert
an influence upon the form, but not upon the nature, of the crime.
Further, these three causes are present in every crime, but almost no
crime would be committed without the social cause. It is this last that
is always the predominant factor. When it is removed, then, the other
two are reduced to zero. The facts have proved this. Owen’s colony was
not made up of peculiar material, and the physical surroundings were
neither better nor “more honest” than any other. Nevertheless, crime
was unknown there. But the author furnishes still further proofs in
support of his thesis that physical and anthropological causes amount
to nothing in comparison with social causes, which in turn are
dependent upon economic conditions. With the exception of crimes
committed by the propertied class, which are in general the result of
excessive cupidity, or a commercial uneasiness, and which will “ipso
facto” disappear without any doubt when once society is otherwise
organized, the greatest contingent of criminals is furnished by the
class of non-possessors. Now all the physical influences, such as
climate, act upon the two classes in the same way, nor are there
anthropological differences between the two classes, yet the difference
between them as regards criminal tendencies is great. It is the social
factors, then, that explain the difference.

However, another observation must be made here. Ferri cites in a mass,
as social factors, the increase of population, emigration, public
opinion, customs, etc. But when we examine and classify these factors
minutely, it becomes clear that in reality they are based upon economic
conditions alone.

However, this observation is not applicable to “criminals by passion”,
since in their case the influence of the environment appears to be but
weak. Lombroso estimates that they form 5% of all criminals, and Ferri
is of the opinion that it is only 5% of those who commit crimes against
persons who are criminals by passion.

One of the anthropological causes of crime is “man”, and one of the
cosmic causes is “the universe.” But neither has anything to do with
crime as such. Otherwise the air we breathe and the food that we eat
would be causes of crime. On the contrary, it is the organization of
society that is the cause of crime, and physical and anthropological
influences are only conditions. (Speaking scientifically we do not
separate causes and conditions, but this is the common usage.) If the
causes ceased to exist the conditions would have no further importance.

Next, Dr. Turati treats of certain kinds of crime. First, crimes
against property. As almost every criminologist will admit, these
crimes are intimately connected with the unequal division of property.
“But,” an opponent will object, “it is not possible, by means of social
institutions, to change cosmic influences, such as a low temperature,
or the failure of the crops, both of which cause an increase of the
crimes against property.” Those who are of this opinion forget,
however, that a man does not become criminal because he is cold, but he
who is cold becomes criminal only if society neglects to provide for
the needs born of the cold.

The influence of society is not seen so distinctly when crimes against
persons are in question. Nevertheless it is very great; the economic
conditions of our day work in two ways, through poverty on the one
side, and injustice on the other. Poverty injures not only the physique
but also the morals of a man, since it leaves him in ignorance and
grossness, and does not develop his moral sentiments. And then it is
harder to bear the evils caused by society than those caused by nature.
In the second place, economic inequality stifles the sense of justice
in man, since it accustoms him to this inequality. “The law is equal
for all”, is only a phrase, for all are not socially equal.

One of the most wide-spread objections to the proposition that crimes
spring from social conditions is that if an improvement in these
conditions leads to a decrease of the crimes against property, the
crimes against persons increase. This is urged by Ferri, among others,
as one of the most effective arguments against Turati and his
partisans. But against this may be urged another fact brought out by
Ferri, namely that while crime is increasing, it is becoming less
intense and less brutal. We see clearly, then, that it is possible to
have a powerful counter-determinant to the tendency to commit crimes
against persons, i.e. education.

As to sexual crimes, they increase when the food supply increases. This
is the cause: sexual needs have a direct relation to nutrition. An
increase of the sexual needs, however, has nothing to do with
criminality. It is only the social organization that changes these
needs that have become more intense, into crimes, by subordinating the
satisfaction of them to economic considerations. There are, besides,
other social causes, like bad housing etc., that lead the proletariat
to commit the crimes in question.

The author then points out the enormous influence of the abuse of
alcohol upon criminality, the causes of this abuse being also found in
the social organization.

Another argument of Ferri’s must be refuted, i.e. that Turati and his
followers attach too much weight to education. Notwithstanding the
equality in the education of two brothers, says Ferri, one becomes a
scamp and the other a hero. To which the author replies that we can say
with just as good right, thanks to education the brother of a scamp
becomes a hero.

But in speaking of education Ferri has in mind that of the bourgeoisie,
which is in opposition to morality, and can consequently have but
little influence. From the day when the state of society shall have
become sound, and the interests of all taken to heart, morality can be
in harmony with reality.

“The true, all-inclusive penal substitute is the equal diffusion, so
far as is socially possible, of well-being and education, of the joys
of love and thought.”




II.

B. BATTAGLIA.

Before speaking of the influence of economic factors upon criminality,
I feel obliged to point out, by the following quotation, what the
author of “La dinamica del delitto” understands by crime: “Primarily it
must be noted that crime is not, in itself, a phenomenon that assumes
the criminal character from its own nature; but the criminal character
is affirmed or denied according to certain purely accessory
circumstances that accompany the act; and in all cases the crime is
such with reference to social relations.” [231]

“From the human point of view a crime represents the satisfaction of a
need of the criminal, like the satisfaction of any other need, and
comes under the law of the struggle for existence. In fact, a need not
satisfied constitutes a pain, and pain, whatever its nature be, first
excites and then depresses and exhausts the functional power of the
organism. The organism, under the influence of pain, loses a quantity
of phosphates proportional to the intensity of the pain; the
physiological equilibrium is broken, and some functions important for
the internal economy are neutralized. The organism, because of the law
of conservation, is called upon to relieve the pain. Often it can do
this without injury to others; at other times it comes into collision
with social interests, and in such a case falls into crime.” [232]

After having spoken of the anatomical and physiological characteristics
that have been observed in criminals, Dr. Battaglia comes to the
investigation into the causes that produce crime. In examining the
factors of crime we see, according to the author, that they consist of
two great groups, first, criminogenous factors, and second, occasional
factors. These last are important only when they are present with the
first. Among the occasional factors are to be classed in the first
place, age, meteorological occurrences, etc., in short, the influences
to which the whole population are subjected. In the second place, sex,
economic conditions, education, etc. i.e. influences which have a less
universal sphere. However, none of the occasional factors can, by
itself, cause a crime to arise. Otherwise a whole population would be
criminal in the same way, since some factors, climate for instance,
exercise their influence upon the whole population. In order to lead to
crime these factors must exert their influence upon intellectual
faculties especially disposed toward crime.

The factors really criminogenous, are those which create certain
physico-psychical conditions, from the complexus of which results the
personal capacity for crime, such as the diseases and defects of
development and nutrition, cranial and intracranial; improper
education; psychical heredity; and atavistic reversions.

“When these factors have prepared the mental condition, by making it
different from that of all others, any opportunity whatever is a
sufficient psychical factor, and a crime is committed. Therefore the
criminogenous factors are those that have the real social importance,
because they prepare inevitably for delinquency.

“It is true, on the other hand, that any of the occasional factors,
acting in a certain way, and with a certain intensity and persistency,
can produce criminogenous factors, like education or alimentation.”
[233]

The author then treats some of the so-called “occasional factors”, such
as age, sex, and religion. I shall speak only of what Dr. Battaglia
says upon the influence of alcoholism and poverty upon criminality,
since this is pertinent to my work.

Alcoholism is a cause of crime in two ways, first, direct, i.e. when
crimes are committed under the actual influence of intoxication;
second, indirect, since chronic alcoholism causes demoralization and
degeneracy. As evidence in support of this the author cites the
opinions of Baer, Virgilio, and others.

As to poverty, Dr. Battaglia remarks that the opinion of Professor
Lombroso on this subject cannot be correct. The latter believes that
the importance of the fact that crimes against property decrease when
prices fall, is weakened by the circumstance that, according to Guerry,
the theft of food holds only the hundredth place in the table of
articles stolen. According to Dr. Battaglia this has no weight in a
critical examination of the influence of poverty. For anyone who is
driven to crime by hunger tries by preference to seize articles that
are of great value and little volume, since he can at once exchange
them for other articles that are directly consumable. Further it must
not be forgotten that alcoholism and bad education are intimately
connected with poverty, and lead in their turn to crime. Not only does
acute hunger incite to theft indirectly, it may lead to it directly,
for it may (according to Professor Follet) bring on a delirium. Chronic
hunger and malnutrition may cause pellagra, rachitis, tuberculosis,
scrofula, etc., or predispose to these diseases, which may cause crime
in their turn.

In the second part of “La dinamica del delitto” the author makes an
examination of what he has called the “criminogenous factors.” Crime is
a phenomenon that develops itself in society in accordance with certain
constant laws. Consequently the criminogenous factors must be found in
society. To discover them, then, it is necessary to examine the
different social institutions.

The family. In nature and in primitive society there rules a natural
selection by which the weak and sickly are prevented from reproducing
themselves, or from reproducing themselves as freely as those who are
stronger. But at present this selection is no longer felt; even the
most wretched, the most diseased can procreate, since it happens
constantly that marriages take place with a secondary object. Hence
transmission of degeneracy may go on from one generation to another,
and consequently, the indirect propagation of crime.

The social position of woman. The inferior position in which woman
finds herself in general (the cause of this is in social conditions,
since the position of woman varies among different people) occasions
crimes in different ways. First, since woman takes no part in the
public life, she is circumscribed in intellect, and consequently, vain,
egoistic, and ignorant. It follows that her influence upon her children
is often very bad. Then, because of her inferior position she easily
becomes the victim of unscrupulous men, who seduce her, so that she is
often driven to prostitution. In consequence of her ignorance she often
marries a man who has asked for her in marriage with an interested
motive. Further, her manner of living (lack of healthful work, etc.)
may bring on neuroses that are transmissible to her children.

Human reproduction. As an animal, man must satisfy two predominant
necessities, that of feeding himself, and that of procreating. Though
this last is not as strong as the other, it must nevertheless be
satisfied, and without this the human organism would experience very
painful consequences. Celibacy is very harmful to morality; it leads to
prostitution (with its consequences, like syphilis), to misconduct, and
hence to the abuse of alcohol, etc.—in short, it favors the birth of
anti-social sentiments.

The present laws governing the relations between man and woman are also
harmful to morality. The author here refers to the indissolubility of
marriage. When the motive for a marriage has ceased to exist, namely
when mutual love no longer exists, the marriage ought to be dissolved.
The harmful consequences of this indissolubility are numerous. Adultery
and many homicides flow from it; the education of children suffers from
it enormously; and finally if the mother expects a child, the vexation
consequent upon discord may exercise an unfavorable influence upon the
newly born.

Education. The development of the intellect and especially of the
feelings is of the highest importance to morality. For example, where a
disagreement will be settled in an amicable manner among persons who
are well brought up, the same disagreement among persons ill-trained
will often lead to brawls. Education is a very complex and difficult
task, requiring much tact and knowledge. It is not astonishing that as
practised it leaves much to be desired. And the consequences of this
absence of a good education are exceedingly favorable to the
development of criminality. However, it must not be forgotten that some
persons, in consequence of qualities transmitted by heredity, become
immoral despite the best imaginable education. The answer to the
question “should education be left to the parents, i.e. to private
persons, who can consequently corrupt their pupils entirely, and not be
under public control?” must, according to Dr. Battaglia, be absolutely
negative. In order that education may be effective in the family it
must be supplemented by the moral influence of the environment, which
also plays an important part in the education of the child. The great
congestion of persons in the cities, for example, should disappear,
because of its bad influence.

Instruction. The double end of instruction is in the first place to
strengthen the intellect by exercising it, from which it will result
that it will have a greater power over the feelings; and in the second
place to furnish a certain amount of positive knowledge, by which the
individual is put into a position to adapt himself to his environment
and to foresee the consequences of his acts. From this it follows that
instruction is of great importance in dealing with criminality. Those
who deny this mean by the “instructed man” one who has learned to read
and write; but it is evident that such instruction is not enough to
exercise an influence of any real importance. It is undeniable that
persons well reared may also become criminals, but in every case their
crimes have a less ferocious character than those of persons without
education.

Religion and State. Religion is opposed to progress, to the development
of the faculties, and to the general dissemination of knowledge that
improves men and increases solidarity; and it incites to intolerance.
Further, the confessional instruction is harmful to the intellectual
faculties of children. The state puts obstacles in the way of the free
movements of individuals; maintains civil marriage; prevents free
discussion, one of the primary requirements for progress; it sets up
compulsory education, but does not prevent the population’s being
brought up in error; by drafting great armies, it withdraws the best
forces from agriculture and manufacturing, so that the vigorous
individuals marry late, and prostitution is thereby encouraged; it
tolerates stock exchanges and lotteries; it favors crowding into great
cities, something that is very favorable, directly and indirectly, to
crime (bad housing conditions, alcoholism, etc.).



In the chapter that follows, Professor Battaglia reduces the factors
that he has just named “criminogenous”, to economic elements. “All the
inconveniences, the anomalies, the errors, the disorders, found in the
family, in the state, in social and religious relationships, etc., are
provoked by the economic situation in which society finds itself....”
[234]

Civil Status. In the communistic villages of Russia it is advantageous
for the father of a family to have many children, for the work in the
common fields is then performed more easily. Hence the marriages of
persons less than 20 years old are numerous. In the rest of Europe the
situation is entirely different. By marrying, a man makes himself worse
off, and at the birth of each child his cares increase. Hence marriages
are put off (especially among professional men) when the man cannot
provide for the needs of his family. For analogous reasons some deny
their sexual desires and contract a marriage to better their position.
In both cases economic conditions exercise an unfavorable influence.
When his income is not sufficient to support himself and his family
properly, the workman is obliged to labor longer than his strength
permits; he and his family are not well enough fed, their dwelling is
bad; consequently their physical condition deteriorates. The effects
are not only diseases, like scrofula, pellagra, phthisis, anemia, etc.,
but also a great predisposition to contract them. Poverty undermines
the organism and exhausts its strength.

In consequence of present economic conditions it is possible to amass
enormous wealth; but wants are still further increased relatively,
which brings it about that frauds, embezzlements, etc., are often
committed by persons of means, especially since the moral sentiments
are lost when one thinks only of gaining money. But wealth is
inconstant; he who has plenty today may be very poor tomorrow. This is
what causes the disquiet and agitation that characterizes the
bourgeoisie, and the neuroses that often follow. Finally the author
dwells upon the work of women and children, so harmful to morality and
to health.

Alcoholism. The inevitable consequence of poverty is the abuse of
alcoholic drinks. One who works too much and eats too little, who is
badly housed and ill-clad, and has no intellectual occupation, finds in
alcohol a means of forgetting his poverty. The life led by a great part
of the bourgeoisie leads also to alcoholism. The harmful consequences
of alcoholism are numerous, especially as regards criminality, because,
first, it leads directly to violent crimes, and, secondly, it
indirectly favors degeneracy.

Fatherhood. It is only for economic reasons that legal marriage, its
indissolubility, and all that belongs to it, are maintained. If each of
the parents kept his or her economic independence, there would be no
reason to take up the matter of legal regulation, and thus the question
of whether the father of the child is or is not the legal husband of
the mother would no longer concern the State.

Prostitution. Most prostitutes come from the lower strata of society.
Like the criminals they present signs of degeneracy, and from the sole
fact of degeneracy have taken on larger proportions in the proletariat
than in the other classes, though the chance that these women will
recruit themselves in this class is already greater. The other causes
of prostitution are of an economic nature, such as exploitation by
parents, bad housing, etc. In consequence of prostitution syphilis
spreads and in its turn favors degeneracy. Further, from the weakening
of their moral sentiments prostitutes are more easily led to commit
crimes.

Ignorance. The cause of the great ignorance of the working-people—an
important factor in criminality—is of an economic nature. The workers
have to exhaust their strength, and have neither the leisure nor the
means, for mental development.

Laxity of morals. In indigent families all the members sleep in one
room, often even in one bed. Hence it comes that sexual morality is
lacking. The parents, often absent on account of their work, leave
their children to their fate. These latter do not know how to look
after themselves, and easily learn bad habits from other children. The
education of the children of the bourgeoisie is no more favorable.
Often they learn only that they must make money, or acquire a social
position, or make a “good” marriage, a thing which leads them to all
sorts of deceits and intrigues to arrive at their end.

Plutocracy. The great armaments and wars of European powers are the
consequence of the present system of competition, which obliges the
constant search for new outlets for commerce.

Plutocracy of the Church. It is only upon its economic resources that
the great power of the Church rests.

Corollary. Poverty alone causes many moral situations from which crime
must logically result. The majority of criminals are in fact recruited
among the less privileged classes.

But the bourgeoisie is not happy simply because the proletariat is
unhappy. The cause of the unhappiness of both is in the present
economic conditions, by which the great majority of the population
vegetate in the blackest misery, while the others are immersed in idle
luxury. There is only one remedy for this injustice; it is to divide
the total product of labor among the workers, and not among the
capitalists.




III.

N. COLAJANNI.

The whole of the first volume and the first chapters of the second
volume of “La sociologia criminale” [235] contain a criticism of the
theses of the Italian school. The author denies the correctness of
these, since he believes that we must consider the anthropological and
physical causes as having little or no importance. This he demonstrates
in detail. In his last chapters Dr. Colajanni treats of social and
economic factors.

While admitting that economic conditions are of the highest importance
in the development of the whole social life, and consequently in the
matter of criminality, the author does not agree with Marx and Loria,
who consider every social occurrence, whether political, or religious,
or æsthetic, or moral, as the unique and direct product of an economic
phenomenon. [236]

According to the author, this assertion is carried too far, since the
feelings and passions of superior people, who do not think of material
profits, influence the masses at certain moments.

A great number of philosophers, moralists, poets, statisticians, and
economists have seen in economic conditions the “causa causarum” of
morality, and consequently also of crime. Pietro Ellero, among others,
says very decisively: “From private property are derived all crimes, or
almost all. Property engenders cupidity and haughtiness on the one side
and depravity on the other, even when it does not produce the perfect
tyranny of the one class and the degradation of the other. It is the
cause of most of the evil passions, faults, and crimes that are
committed, of the troubles, anxieties, sadness, and rancor from which
both rich and poor suffer alike. The immoral influence of property is
continued afterwards, and that terribly, in the present organization of
the family, constructed, as it is, almost always upon the basis of
calculation!” [237]

It is incontestable that economic conditions have a direct influence
upon the origin of crime. The lack of the means of satisfying the
numerous wants of a man is already a goad to incite him to procure
these means in any way whatever, honest or dishonest. And it is the
dishonest way that one will choose by preference when society makes it
difficult or impossible to act otherwise. A London pickpocket gets
$1500 a year on the average; on the other hand, the misery of those who
wish to earn their living honestly is indescribable. Further, the
honest man’s chance of being killed or becoming incapable of working is
greater than the thief’s chance of being punished. Honest work results
in fewer advantages and more dangers than dishonest work.

The indirect influence is not less important than the direct. War, our
present industry, the family, marriage, political institutions,
revolutions, vagrancy, prostitution, education, etc. are important
causes of crime, but they can all be reduced to economic causes.
According to many persons education is the one means of preventing
moral evils, but John Stuart Mill has already said: in our present
society the poor have no education, and that of the rich is bad. There
is no possibility of a good education if a certain material well-being
is lacking. Hence those who expect everything from education under the
present conditions are wrong.

But where does well-being cease and poverty begin? Both are only
relative conceptions; consequently we cannot fix their limits. In order
to attain the minimum of criminality in any given society there must be
the certainty of the means of subsistence, stability of economic
conditions, and equality in the distribution of wealth.

Some authors deny that political revolutions have their causes in
economic conditions. Lombroso and Laschi, for example, attempt to
explain them chiefly by physical influences; which is the more
astonishing, because in the general opinion it is from economic causes
that they are derived. They adduce, among other things, to support
their opinion, the fact that out of 147 revolts that took place in
Europe between 1793 and 1880, only a third were attributable to
economic conditions. It goes without saying that this does not at all
prove the correctness of their thesis, since in all these cases the
authors are speaking only of direct causes, while most military
revolutions, revolts against the royal power, etc., spring from
economic conditions, even if indirectly. It is true that in the 19th
century the direct revolutionary influence of crises and famines has
decreased, because of the measures taken by the governments. This does
not however prevent there having been revolts occasioned by such
conditions (Lyons in 1831, etc.). The frequent revolts in Belgium and
France, rich countries, do not furnish any proof against the thesis of
Dr. Colajanni; for notwithstanding the great wealth of these countries,
nothing proves that it is equally divided. As soon as the poverty of a
people has passed certain limits, we see in that country neither
crimes, revolutions, nor suicides, since all energy is then extinct.

Another question is this: how far is there a correlation between the
progress made by socialism and the increase of criminality. [238]
Several authors, like Garofalo, are of the opinion that there is an
intimate connection between the two. But they do not furnish any facts
as proofs in support of their assertion, to which, on the contrary, the
facts give the lie.

The countries where socialism is most widely spread do not show the
greatest criminality; rather the contrary. The German and Italian
districts where there are the most socialists are no longer the most
criminal. How could it be otherwise? While socialism is the conscious
and collective reaction against the existing order, crime is the
unconscious and individual reaction against that order.

Next, Dr. Colajanni turns his attention to idleness and vagrancy, which
are both causes of crime. Out of 32,943 thefts in Paris in 1882, 57%
were committed by vagrants.

But are idleness and vagrancy considered in themselves also offenses?
Any man is harmful to his species, says Féré, when he does not
collaborate, either materially or intellectually, in production.
According to Dr. Colajanni, idleness and vagrancy, viewed from such a
high social point of view, are really offenses. But then the idle rich
are also guilty of these offenses. Finally, what are the causes of
these crimes? Spencer, Féré, and Sergi say: the vagrants are the weak,
the degenerate, the parasites of society. The question is this, then:
do these phenomena find their origin inside or outside of the human
organism? Romagnosi says that vagrancy and idleness ought to be
punished only when they are not excusable. To make them inexcusable it
would be necessary to procure employment for every man who was willing
to work. Spencer, Sergi, and Garofalo, on the contrary, are of the
opinion that these crimes are almost always to be imputed to the same
persons. However, Spencer should not have forgotten that in his own
country, aside from industrial crises, numerous occurrences have forced
a great number of persons to become idlers and vagrants through no
fault of their own, as for example, the Irish and Scotch farmers driven
from their lands by the landlords.

And Garofalo should have known that it is capitalism that has made the
work of men superfluous by employing women and children, and that the
cause does not rest with those who suffer from it; on the contrary, the
cause of economic crises is not in their victims, but in the system
that is in force.

An examination of the causes of these two phenomena obliges us to
distinguish between habitual and accidental, or forced, vagrancy.
However—and this is too often forgotten—the latter transforms itself
into the former, for the taste for work is, like morality, an acquired
social product. This is why this quality is lost when one is long
without work.

One of the most important causes of the possible transformation of a
worker into a vagrant is a long illness. Having lost the habit of work,
and being enfeebled, a man will find great difficulty in going to work
again. If he does not succeed he descends step by step until he comes
finally to mendicity. But it is chiefly the economic transformations,
inventions, overproduction, that must be called the “causa causarum” of
the phenomena cited above. [239]

Prostitution, which occupies so important a place in the etiology of
crime, in almost every case finds its origin in poverty, in a bad
education, in a corrupting environment, as is proved by the official
investigations and the writings of specialists, like Parent-Duchatelet,
Fiaux, Augagneur, and many others. [240]

The correlation that exists between crimes against property and
economic conditions is very evident, and is direct. This causality
appears also with regard to crimes against persons. Only it is then
indirect. The influence of poverty upon criminality is especially great
when it has been of long duration. Proudhon is quite right when he
says: “Hunger that is every instant present, during the whole year,
during the whole life, hunger which does not kill in a day, but is
composed of all deprivations and all griefs, and unceasingly consumes
the body, ruins the spirit, demoralizes the conscience, corrupts the
race, generates all vices and diseases (drunkenness, among others), and
an aversion towards work and thrift, baseness of spirit, callousness of
conscience, laziness, and prostitution together with theft.” [241]

The fact that the number of thefts of provisions is relatively small
has little importance, since the thief always tries to steal some
article of small bulk and great value. Also it must not be forgotten
that little thefts of food often pass unnoticed, or without complaint
being made, because the party injured does not consider the act a
crime, since committed from necessity.

Another convincing proof of the influence of economic conditions is the
incontestable fact that it continually happens that a person will
declare himself guilty of a crime that has not been committed, with the
sole purpose of obtaining a lodging in jail. The great percentage made
up of crimes committed from cupidity, as well as the fact that the
number of recidivists is greater for crimes against property than for
others, shows the great influence of economic conditions.

The study of the morality of primitive peoples shows us that the crimes
of abortion, for example, of infanticide, and homicide upon the aged,
have their origin in economic conditions exclusively, the means of
subsistence not being sufficient to support a large population. When
these crimes occur among civilized peoples they have the same causes.
For example, cases of infanticide are very common in Trevise, one of
the poorest provinces in Italy. The lack of education or the influence
of other factors opposed to education are the reason why the corrupting
influence of which we have been speaking often rages in the lower
classes with all its force.

To prove the assertion that economic conditions have little influence
upon criminality, some authors cite the fact that England, with its
great wealth, shows a greater number of crimes against property than
Italy, which is much poorer. He who reasons in this way forgets that
the absolute wealth of a country may be very great, but the
distribution of that wealth not proportional. England gives us the
proof of this; in no other country is the difference between rich and
poor more pronounced, and without the presence of other important and
opposing factors, the criminality would be much greater than it is now.

One might also bring up the difference between the criminality of
Ireland, which is smaller despite the proverbial poverty there, and the
great criminality of Italy. However, when we study conditions in the
two countries we find that those in Italy are still more undesirable
than those in Ireland, which explains the greater criminality against
property in Italy. The mysterious assassinations of large landholders
and their agents in Ireland have also their cause in the bad
distribution of the land. In Belgium criminality is greatest where
well-being is least (in Flanders). According to the researches of Liszt
and Starcke, the poorest districts of Germany are also those that are
most criminal, etc.

Upon the economic condition of criminals the author gives the following
data: In 1870–71 there were among the prisoners at Neufchâtel 10% who
had some property, and 89% who had only their work for their support
(in the non-criminal population the percentage of these is much
smaller). According to the data of Stevens the prisoners in Belgium
were divided as follows: 1% of well-to-do persons, 11% of persons with
some income, and 88% of indigent persons.

The statistics of recidivists in Sweden from 1870 to 1872 give the
following information:


          Well-to-do                              0.64 %
          With sufficient   means of subsistence 10.08 ,,
           ,,  insufficient  ,,   ,,     ,,      43.54 ,,
           ,,  miserable     ,,   ,,     ,,      45.63 ,,


Marro, in his “I caratteri dei delinquenti”, gives us the following:


=====================================+============+================
                                     | Criminals. | Non-criminals.
-------------------------------------+------------+----------------
Without property                     |   79.6 %   |     43.4 %
Minor children of well-to-do parents |    4.1 ,,  |     10.5 ,,
With a little property               |    6.7 ,,  |     18.4 ,,
With considerable property           |    9.4 ,,  |     27.6 ,,
=====================================+============+================


At the time that they committed their crimes 43% of these criminals in
general, and more than 50% of the criminals against property were
without work.



All that has been given above has to do with statics; what follows has
to do with dynamics. The rule universally observed is this:
modifications in economic conditions are followed by modifications in
criminality. When the former grow worse, the number of crimes (and
especially of those against property) increases, and vice versa. It is
especially the proletariat, who have no means of resisting the
unfavorable influence of crises, a rise in the price of food, etc., who
are hardest hit in these cases.

The author gives some data. In Italy in 1880 a great increase of crime
coincided with a lack of work and with a rise in the price of
provisions. The gradual diminution in criminality must be attributed to
the good harvest and the large emigration. In Belgium the number of
prisoners rose during the crisis of 1846 from 6750 to 9884. In Norway,
in consequence of the depression of 1869, crimes against property
reached the maximum. The number of prisoners in Sweden rose from 1835
to 1839, chiefly because of poverty, from 12,799 to 18,357. A great
increase in crime took place in England in consequence of the crises of
1826, 1830, 1847, and others. In the United States there were in 1884
not less than 400,000 working-men without work, which explains the
following figures:


            ===================+=========+=========
                               |  1883   |  1884
            -------------------+---------+---------
            Homicides          |  1,494  |  3,377
            Cases of lynching  |     92  |    219
            Suicides           |    910  |  1,897
            ===================+=========+=========


In consequence of the economic crises of 1839, 1840, 1843, 1847, 1867,
1876, and 1881, the number of murders increased in France. [242]

The maximum stability and the minimum lack of proportion in the
distribution of wealth is the best preservative against crime. The
correctness of this rule is proved by the facts. The small number of
crimes among the Irish is explained by their altruistic sentiments,
which are the consequence of their social institutions from before the
conquest of their country by the English. Among Mohammedans crime is
rare. Also there may be remarked among them a true democracy, based
upon equality and fraternity. The Yorubas (in Eastern Africa) have a
mild character, and they are benevolent and true to their word; with
them the land is considered as common property, etc., etc.

“These are facts which speak clearly: the collectivism of the Javanese
dessa, of the Berber diema, the Russian mir, the Slav zadrouga, and the
village community of the early Aryans and North American Indians,
produces everywhere, with all climates, among all races, identically
the same results—morality and solidarity.

“It is to be noted also, that everywhere and at all times, whether in
the temperate or the frigid zone, in the North, in the South, or at the
equator, laws and institutions which aim to insure certainty of
subsistence and to maintain a certain equality, go far to cut down
crime; and they do it in such a way as to make those who live under
them more moral than those who are subject to different institutions
and laws. We have clear examples of this among the Hebrews, Iroquois,
Peruvians, Chinese, Berbers, etc., although they differ greatly as to
the grade of civilization they have reached.” [243]




IV.

A. BEBEL.

In “Die Frau und der Sozialismus” the author gives the following pages
to the relation between the present social organization and crime: “The
increase of crime of every description is intimately connected with the
social conditions of the community, little as the latter is inclined to
believe it. Society hides its head in the sand, like the ostrich, in
order not to be forced to recognize a state of things that bears
witness against it, and silences its own conscience and others’ with
the lying pretense that laziness and love of pleasure on the part of
the workmen and their want of religion is accountable for everything.
This is hypocrisy of the most revolting kind. The more unfavorable and
depressed the condition of society, the more numerous and grave do
crimes become. The struggle for existence then assumes its most brutal
and violent shape, it throws man back into his primæval state, in which
each regarded the other as his deadly enemy. The ties of solidarity,
not too firm at the best of times, become daily looser.

“The ruling classes, who do not and will not recognize the causes of
things, attempt to effect a change by employing force against the
products of these conditions, and even men whom we should expect to be
enlightened and free from prejudice, are ready to support the system.
Professor Haeckel, for instance, regards the stringent application of
capital punishment as desirable, and harmonizes in this point with the
reactionaries of every shade, who on all other subjects are his
bitterest enemies. According to his theory, hopeless criminals and
ne’er-do-wells must be rooted out like weeds, which deprive the more
valuable plants of light, air, and soil. If Professor Haeckel had
occupied himself even to a slight degree with the study of social
science, instead of limiting himself to natural science, he would have
discovered that all these criminals could be transformed into useful,
valuable members of society, if society offered them more favorable
means of existence. He would have found that the annihilation of the
criminal has just as little effect on crime, i.e. on the development of
fresh crimes, as if on a number of farms the ground were superficially
cleared of weeds while the roots and seeds remained undestroyed. Man
will never be able absolutely to prevent the development of noxious
organisms in nature, but it is unquestionably within his power so to
improve the social organism created by himself, that it may afford
equally favorable conditions of existence and an equal freedom of
growth to all; that no one may be forced to gratify his hunger or his
desire of possession or his ambition at the expense of someone else.
People only need to investigate the causes of crime and to remove them,
and they will abolish crime itself.

“Naturally those who seek to abolish crime by abolishing its causes
cannot take kindly to measures of brutal suppression. They cannot
prevent society from protecting itself against crime in its own way,
but they demand all the more urgently the radical reformation of
society, i.e. the removal of causes.” [244]

“The relationship between social conditions and crime has often been
pointed out by statisticians and sociologists. One of the offenses that
comes closest to us—for our society, in spite of all the Christian
teaching about charity, regards it as a crime—in times of business
depression, is mendicity. We learn from the statistics of the kingdom
of Saxony, that in measure as the last great commercial crisis grew
worse, beginning in Germany in 1890 with the end not yet in sight, the
number of persons sentenced for mendicity also increased. In 1889, in
the Kingdom of Saxony 8566 persons were punished for this offense, 8815
in 1890, 10,075 in 1891, and in 1892 as many as 13,120, a very great
increase. The impoverishment of the masses on the one hand, with
increasing wealth on the other, is the chief mark of our period. In
1874 there was one poor man to 724 persons, while in 1882 the number
had reached 1 to 622. [245] Crimes and misdemeanors show a similar
tendency. In 1874, there were 308,605 persons sentenced in
Austria-Hungary, and 600,000 in 1892. In the German Empire in 1882
there were 329,968 persons sentenced for crimes and misdemeanors
against the laws, i.e. 103.2 persons to 10,000 of the population over
12 years old; in 1892 the number of those sentenced reached 422,327, or
143.3 to the 10,000, an increase of 39%. Those convicted of crimes and
misdemeanors against property were:


        1882   169,334 persons, or 53.0 to the 10,000 over 12
        1891   196,437    ,,    or 55.8 ,, ,,    ,,    ,,  ,,


“We think that these figures speak volumes, that they show how the
deterioration of social conditions increases and multiplies poverty,
need, misdemeanors and crimes.” [246]




V.

P. LAFARGUE.

The first part of the study, “Die Kriminalität in Frankreich von
1840–1886”, is taken up with an examination of the trend of criminality
during these years. The author comes to the conclusion that during this
period crime has increased, and that the line that shows this increase
is made up of a succession of curves, alternately concave and convex.

In the second part, he treats of the causes of crime. He first points
out that the belief that the proclamation of liberty, equality, and
fraternity in the French Revolution would be speedily followed by a
diminution in crime, was not borne out by the facts. Then he takes up
the idea, so widespread in the first half of the 19th century, that one
of the most important causes of criminality is the lack of education.
This hypothesis has been generally recognized as false, in consequence
of an examination of the facts. According to Lafargue, who is entirely
in agreement with Quetelet on this point, it is necessary not only to
examine the qualities of the individual, but also especially to analyze
society, and to try thus to discover the sources of crime. Next the
author shows the results of the researches of Quetelet with regard to
the influence of the season, age, and sex upon criminality, and sets
forth and criticises briefly the theories of Lombroso and his partisans
with regard to the criminal man. We should run to too great length if
we gave more fully his refutation which is as brilliant as it is
accurate.

Some statisticians connect the returns of the harvests and vintages
with criminality. An investigation upon this point as regards France,
gives the following results: the years 1847, 1854, 1868, and 1874,
which are characterized by a great increase of crime, were preceded by
years of bad harvests.

The average of the crops of grain was:


            from 1840 to 1853 about 80 million hectolitres
             ,,  1856 ,, 1885  ,,   100   ,,        ,,


the crop rose:


            in 1846 to 61 million hectolitres
             ,,  1853 ,, 63   ,,        ,,
             ,,  1867 ,, 83   ,,        ,,
             ,,  1873 ,, 84   ,,        ,,


However, the bad harvests of 1855, 1861, and 1879 did not have these
results, and with the good crops of 1847 to 1852 crime increased. Here
there were, therefore, other factors. Consequently, although the price
of grain can partially explain the fluctuations of criminality, it does
not account for the general increase from 1840 to 1886.

The author combats further the opinion of Professor Lacassagne that
crimes against persons are especially under the influence of the
production and consumption of wine. If this were the case the
wine-growing departments ought to furnish the highest figure for crimes
against persons, which is not the case. On the contrary, Lafargue is of
the opinion that in this respect, the consumption of brandy is of more
importance. The continually increasing abuse of alcohol (i.e. of
spirituous drinks like brandy) which in its turn is due to the
miserable condition of the proletariat, is one of the causes of the
increasing criminality.

Quantity of alcohol consumed:


    =======+======================+======================
     Year. | Total (Hectolitres). | Per Capita (Litres).
    -------+----------------------+----------------------
     1850  |        585,200       |         1.46
     1855  |        714,813       |         2.00
     1860  |        851,825       |         2.27
     1865  |        873,007       |         2.34
     1875  |      1,010,052       |         2.82
     1880  |      1,313,849       |         3.64
     1885  |      1,444,342       |         3.86
    =======+======================+======================


In the third part Lafargue makes special investigations with regard to
the correlation between economic conditions and criminality. If the
theory of Lombroso were correct, criminality ought to decrease; bad
harvests no longer explain the increase, and the climate has not
changed. However, the increase of criminality coincided with the
enormous increase in the productive forces in France.


=======================================+===========+=============+=============+============
                                       |   1840    |    1860     |    1880     |    1884
---------------------------------------+-----------+-------------+-------------+------------
Horse-power of steam engines used      |           |             |             |
  in manufacturing and agriculture     |    34,350 |     177,652 |     544,152 |    683,090
Consumption of coal (in tons)          | 4,256,000 |  14,270,000 |  28,846,000 | 30,941,000
Production of iron (in tons)           |   585,000 |   1,430,000 |   2,790,000 |  2,747,000
Production of steel (in tons)          |     8,262 |      30,000 |     389,000 |    503,000
Exports and imports (in millions       |           |             |             |
  of francs)                           |     1,442 |       4,174 |       8,501 |      7,575
Increase of inheritances (in millions  |           |             |             |
  of francs)                           |     1,608 |       2,724 |       5,265 |      5,244
National wealth (in millions of        |           |             |             |
  francs)                              |    64,320 |     108,960 |     210,600 |    209,760
=======================================+===========+=============+=============+============


There is a close correspondence, then, between the development of the
economic forces and the increase of criminality. Must we regard this as
simply chance, or is there causality between the two? Quetelet has
already pointed out that the poorest districts, i.e. those in which the
absolute wealth is not great, but where the contrasts are not very
marked, furnish fewer criminals than the wealthier provinces. According
to Lafargue this has become still more striking with the development of
capitalism.

“The colossal development of the productive forces and the national
wealth does not lead to the increase of the well-being of all the
members of society, but to enormous fortunes on the one hand, and on
the other to misery and need, for the great majority of the
population.” [247] If the multiplying, grading, and perfecting of
punishments have been incapable of checking the upward progress of
crime, this proves that crimes and misdemeanors against the common law
are the necessary products of conditions, and are closely bound up with
the form and fashion of the creation of social wealth in capitalistic
society.

“The development of the capitalistic mode of production is not uniform;
at times it is over-rapid, and then slows up again and undergoes crises
that destroy the living of thousands and millions of individuals. If it
is correct that modern criminality is a necessary consequence of the
method of the production of wealth in capitalistic society, then the
fluctuations of crime must correspond with the variations in
production. The number of offenses must increase in times of crisis,
and decrease when economic conditions improve; in other words,
criminality is determined by the flourishing or depression of the
capitalistic mode of production.” [248]

As a means of measuring comparative economic conditions, Lafargue has
taken the annual number of failures. He has also traced a curve for the
price of flour. [249]

Examining the first plate we see that lines I and II, although not
entirely parallel with V, follow it in general. According to Lafargue
there are three counter-determinants that caused the deviations: first,
changes in the price of flour; second, political events; third,
extraordinary industrial activity. Thus, for example, it was the
political events of 1848–52 that prevented the decrease of crime during
those years, though the failures and the price of flour went down; and
at the close of 1854 a feverish economic development recommenced,
which, with the fall of the price of flour in 1856–59, caused a
decrease of criminality during those years. At the same time the
failures rose a little; but the line would doubtless show a different
course if it were drawn with reference to the ratio of failures to the
total number of commercial and industrial enterprises in this period.
The low price of flour in 1869 neutralized the increase of failures and
even diminished the criminality. From 1874 to 1878 a new industrial
revival kept crime stationary or reduced it. Since 1876 the failures
have increased greatly and crime follows at a little interval; the
falling price of grain (1881–1885) certainly exerted an influence.


[PLATE I.

I. Crimes against Persons and Property, tried at the Assizes. II.
General Criminality (Crimes and Misdemeanors). III. Offenses against
the Common Law, tried by the Correctional Tribunals. IV. Price of a
Sack of Flour in the Markets of Paris. V. Number of Failures.]


[PLATE II.

I. Thefts with Aggravating Circumstances, tried by the Assizes, and
Simple Thefts, tried by the Correctional Tribunals. II. Theft, Fraud,
Embezzlement, tried by the Correctional Tribunals. III. Number of
Failures and the Price of Flour Combined.]


The curves are almost constantly parallel; the deviations are caused by
political events and by the industrial revival. [250]

Vagrancy and mendicity take the same course as failures; they increase,
however, from 1848 to 1852 in consequence of the political troubles of
those years. From 1878 on, failures, and vagrancy and mendicity
increase and are parallel. In the periods of industrial revival
(1854–59 and 1874–76) vagrancy and mendicity decline sharply. In
examining the curve of recidivism it must be remembered that since 1884
many recidivists have been transported.


[PLATE III.

I. Vagrancy and Mendicity. II. Failures. III. Recidivists sentenced by
the Assizes or the Correctional Tribunals.]


Here we see a result contrary to that on the preceding charts: If the
failures increase the rapes generally decrease, and vice versa.
According to this plate the consumption of alcohol has no relation to
crimes against morals.


[PLATE IV.

I. Rape. II. Consumption of Alcohol. III. Failures.]


At the end of his study the author comes to the following conclusion:
“The effect of bankruptcy upon criminality and politics is undeniable;
it furnishes one of the most striking proofs of the correctness of the
historical theory of Karl Marx, that the phenomena of literature and
art, of morality and religion, of philosophy and politics, in human
society, lead back to the phenomena of economic development.” [251]




VI.

H. DENIS.

Professor Denis begins his report to the 3d Congress of Criminal
Anthropology, entitled “La criminalité et la crise économique”, by
calling attention to the effect that the crisis of 1846–47 had upon
criminality. The crops of wheat, rye, and especially potatoes had been
bad, and the price of these articles of food had accordingly risen. The
breaking up of household labor and the introduction of machines brought
about a revolution in the linen industry at the same time. So the
figures for crime indicate an enormous increase during these years, and
at the close of the period a continuous decrease.


            =======+===========================
                   |  Numbers of Delinquents
            Years. | to the 10,000 Inhabitants.
            -------+---------------------------
             1845  |            28.8
             1846  |            47.9
             1847  |            65.3
             1848  |            42.4
             1849  |            25.-
             1850  |            19.8
             1851  |            19.8
             1852  |            19.2
             1853  |            19.7
            =======+===========================


Then the author treats of the effect produced upon criminality by the
crises of 1874 and the years following. The price of grain no longer
giving, in consequence of importation, an exact picture of the economic
conditions, he adds to the chart which he uses, the “nombres
indicateurs” (of 28 of the more important articles of commerce). The
curve of these numbers shows a fluctuating rise during the period from
1850 to 1865, and a fluctuating decline during the period following the
years 1874–75. During the first period, in which the economic
conditions were favorable (the years 1870 to 1873 being characterized
by an economic development that was even feverish), criminality
remained fairly stationary. Only during the years 1856–57 and 1861–62
was there an increase, and this is probably to be ascribed to the high
price of grain. The economic depression that commenced after 1874 was
severely felt, and crime continually increased without the low price of
grain being able to prevent it.

Professor Denis closes his report with the following words: “The
solution of the problem of criminality must be in part sought in
economic conditions; and the more regular and constant the social
movement of wealth, the more we approach a normal equilibrium of
collective functions, the more we instil justice into our economic
institutions, the more shall we be able to gain the mastery over
criminality.

“An Italian criminologist, Ferri, studying the evolution of criminality
in France in relation to the income of the most numerous class, has
shown that with a general rise in wages we see a decrease in certain
kinds of crime. The general increase of prosperity is a sure pledge of
a decrease in criminality. But there is another, and that is a decrease
in those more or less marked oscillations, in the economic world, whose
periodic return is certainly one of the gravest aspects of the modern
state.

“In the second place, the economic causes that affect the tendency to
crime reveal an immense solidarity, which continues to extend itself
into space, as heredity plunges its roots into time. The great
fluctuations in prices are common to the whole world, and the
individual whom these perturbations drive to crime by a series of
shocks, comes into conflict with a great number of other individuals,
without being conscious of this infinite solidarity. But science must
endeavor to collect the evidence of it. Finally these great economic
influences tend, on the one hand, to reduce the field of the individual
responsibility, and on the other, to give a precise character to the
responsibility of society in this connection. It is responsible, in
fact, within the limits within which it might have restrained the
economic fluctuations and corrected their effects, but has not done so.
Here the terrible saying of Quetelet is still true: society herself has
put the weapon into the hand of the criminal.” [252]




VII.

H. LUX. [253]

In the chapter, “Die degenerirenden Einwirkungen des Kapitalismus”,
this author treats of the question of criminality and its relation with
present economic conditions.

“The property-holders, those who enjoy the benefits of all the
political and social institutions, alone have the right to exist. Those
without possessions do not have this right, despite the fiction of the
Prussian code with regard to the matter. The simple instinct of
self-preservation causes them to engage in a continual attack upon a
legal system that protects only the stronger. It is this attack which
those who are in possession of power, those who have drawn up the laws
for the purpose of protecting their power, characterize as a breach of
the law, as crime.... This is the simplest relationship between the
form of society and crime. Naturally, complications come in.... The
stronger those without property, the outlawed, themselves become
through some chance, the more do they modify the law that was set up by
those who were formerly stronger, the more do complications arise in
the primitively simple right of property, the right to the protection
of social institutions, and the law of marriage, and the greater and
more complicated becomes the circle of crimes.” [254]

After having next spoken briefly of free will, and having shown that it
is incorrect to connect criminality with a single social phenomenon
alone, since the social mechanism is too complicated, the author begins
to treat of the crimes against property. In the first place he gives
the following tables:


Germany. [255]

========+========================================================++=========================
        |                          Prices.                       ||
        +----------------------------------+---------------------++ To 10,000 Inhabitants
        |    In Marks per 1,000 Kilogr.    | In Pf. per Kilogr.  ||  Over 10 Years Old.
 Years. +-----------+----------+-----------+----------+----------++----------------+--------
        | Of Bread. | Of Peas. |    Of     | Of Beef. | Of Pork. || Crimes Against | Theft.
        |           |          | Potatoes. |          |          ||    Property.   |
--------+-----------+----------+-----------+----------+----------++----------------+--------
 1881   | 198       | 251      | 43.5      | 114      | 128      ||  --            |  --
 1882   | 171       | 236      | 56.5      | 116      | 128      || 52.9           | 32.6
 1883   | 155       | 241      | 45.5      | 120      | 128      || 51.0           | 31.6
 1884   | 145       | 229      | 47.0      | 120      | 120      || 50.7           | 30.1
 1885   | 147       | 212      | 38.0      | 119      | 120      || 48.6           | 27.9
 1886   | 130       | 209      | 39.5      | 117      | 119      || 48.1           | 27.2
 1887   | 135       | 198      | 41.5      | 113      | 115      || 47.1           | 26.0
 1888   | 144       | 219      | 59.0      | 112      | 114      || 45.9           | 25.4
 1889   | 162       | 209      | 42.0      | 117      | 128      || 49.3           | 28.1
========+===========+==========+===========+==========+==========++================+========


Hungary.

============================+======+=======+=======+======+======+======+======+======
                            | 1881 |  1882 | 1883  | 1884 | 1885 | 1886 | 1887 | 1888
----------------------------+------+-------+-------+------+------+------+------+------
Convicted of theft          | 19.  |  26.7 |  25.7 | 23.4 | 32.2 | 22.0 | 21.7 | 22.3
Crop of maize per hectare   | 16.1 |  20.0 |  16.8 | 17.2 | 20.5 | 15.5 | 14.2 | 18.0
 ,,  ,, potatoes per hectare| 81.8 | 110.7 | 109.9 | 80.1 | 92.0 | 77.2 | 79.0 | 85.4
============================+======+=======+=======+======+======+======+======+======


Finally, Dr. Lux cites some statistics from Kolb’s “Handbuch der
vergleichenden Statistik”, which show the close connection between
crimes against property and economic conditions.

Political crimes. “In the case of crimes against the State, public
order, and religion, the dependence upon the form of society is
immediately apparent. The ‘classes’, i.e. the property-owners as a
whole, see in the institutions that they have set up, the strongest
support of the capitalistic system, which must be maintained at any
cost. The property-owners have the power to uphold their unique
position by laws directed against those who would break down that
power. And if the laws are no longer sufficient, their place is taken
by judicial interpretations in the interests of the classes. This is
only the logical consequence of the whole spirit and aim of
legislation. The greater become the rights founded upon property, the
more do those without property feel themselves to be deprived of their
rights,—in the fullest sense of the word—in jeopardy as to their
existence, their full life; the more energetic is the reaction against
the laws, which are felt as despotism; and the more serious is the
attack upon those laws,—a characteristic phenomenon of all periods of
transition as to the form of society.” [256]

The question which presents itself now is this: how far are these
factors connected with existing economic conditions? But before
entering upon this the author calls attention to the environment in
which the children of the proletariat live, and especially of the lower
proletariat, an environment in which misery and vice contend for the
preëminence. There it is nearly out of the question to learn ethical
conceptions. Whence it comes also that in our days criminality among
the young has greatly increased. However, alcoholism must also be named
as one of the most important causes of psychical perturbations.

It is not only the non-possessors, but also the possessors who are
driven to commit crimes as a consequence of existing economic
conditions. “But not only for those without property, for the
proletariat, does capitalism furnish the psychically prerequisite
conditions for crime ... but for the property-holders themselves.
Entirely aside from business practices and tricks of the trade, which
stand upon the hairline between right and wrong, apart from the frauds,
forgeries, etc. that are evoked by too tempting opportunity, there are
more general effects of the capitalistic system. The hurried chase for
gain, the accelerating of commerce by railroad, steamship, telegraph,
and telephone, the multiplication of commercial crises, which earlier
came at intervals, but now are a permanent accompaniment of the social
life, bring about a nervousness running through all circles of society,
that is continually increasing, and is the forerunner of more serious
psychoses. The terrible increase of cases of insanity (in Prussia, to
the 10,000 of the population, in 1871, 5.94 cases; in 1875, 7.28; in
1880, 9.87), appears to be thus directly caused by capitalistic
society.” [257]

However, there act in man as counter-determinants, combating the
factors called criminogenous, the ethical factors (“ethische
Hemmungsvorstellungen”), which are determined by education, character,
the fear of punishment, etc. Those who do not wish to investigate the
deepest causes of criminality, are of the opinion that the best way to
combat crime is by increasing the penalties. The persons who speak thus
forget that the so-called ethical factors have no longer any effect
when the conditions have reached a certain degree of seriousness.

Crimes against persons. It is the industrial workers who form the
greatest contingent of criminals against persons. “The continually
changing conditions of earning a living, the desire for drink, the
slight influence of the family, the being crowded together with persons
of defective education and little training ... these all necessarily
breed crimes of violence; entirely aside from the habitual rowdyism of
the bully [“Zuhälter”], which is to be regarded as the consequence of
prostitution. [258]

Besides the external conditions named above, the person of the criminal
is also to be noticed. We may consider it as proved that in some cases
of crime one of the causes is a mental perturbation (for example, that
caused by drunkenness). These perturbations play a great part in sexual
crimes (perverted instincts). What characterizes most of these mental
anomalies is that they blunt the social instincts. But there is another
cause of psychic degeneracy. “It is a universally valid psycho-physical
law that man, ‘the more he depends upon an agreeable stimulation for
the satisfaction of his senses, demands ever stronger stimuli, even to
secure the same degree of pleasure.’ Pleasures, especially sensual
pleasures, must always become more intense, more titillating, in order
to afford satisfaction, but the more their intensity increases, the
more do the nerves become irritated and exhausted, and the more quickly
is the ground prepared for mental diseases either in the individual
himself or in his descendants.—It must be emphasized, however, that
such an increase in the stimulus is only possible to the rich, and
accordingly it is with reference to them chiefly that these sources of
mental disturbances are to be taken into consideration.” [259]

After having called attention to the great amount of recidivism among
female delinquents, to the great increase of crime in our own day, and
to the great percentage of young people among the criminals, the author
closes with the following words: “Crime belongs in a society founded
upon capitalism just as necessarily as do prostitution, the destruction
of countless human lives through economic exploitation, etc.”




VIII.

P. HIRSCH.

After having shown in the first chapter of his work, “Verbrechen und
Prostitution”, [260] the relation between criminality and prostitution,
and the increase of the two at the same time, the author gives, in his
second chapter, a short exposition of the doctrine of criminal
anthropology, and in the third chapter he takes up the doctrine of the
social environment.

Here he treats first of the encouragement of prostitution and crime by
the marriage restrictions. Marriages increase or decrease as economic
conditions grow better or worse. So, for example, in Prussia there
were, from 1866 to 1870, 1605 marriages to 100,000 of the population;
this number rose to 1896 in the period of prosperity between the years
1870 and 1875, only to fall, in 1888, to 1624. In bad times the number
of illegitimate births makes a consequent increase. It is very
comprehensible that natural children furnish a greater number of
criminals than legitimate children, since they have more difficulty in
enduring the combat of life than the others.

Then he sets forth as a cause of crime the influence of domestic
relations. When the parents belong already to the class of criminals,
it is almost inevitable that their children should fall into the hands
of justice while still young. And the present system of production
brings it about that the education of the children of the proletariat
is almost nil, since it obliges the father, and very often the mother
also, to work away from home during a great part of the day and often
of the night. The situation is still more unfavorable for the children
who have lost their parents when they were still quite young. Starke
says that about 57% of the legitimate children among the juvenile
prisoners in Plötzensee were orphans or had been abandoned by their
parents.

The third part has to do with the housing conditions of the
proletariat. “A lodging fit for a human being is the first requirement
for the bodily and mental welfare of the family; it is the prerequisite
for a well-regulated family life, and for the rearing of the children
to be moral men and women. The improprieties resulting from the
exigencies of insufficient lodgings are innumerable, and this condition
is an inexhaustible source of crime, prostitution, and vice of every
kind.” All the data prove that the proletariat, who, of all classes,
pay the highest rent, are the most miserably housed. In Berlin, for
example, the poorest classes have been shown to spend on an average a
quarter of their income for rent. In Hamburg the part of the income
that had to go for rent among the class whose income was from 600 to
1200 marks, in 1868 was 18.77%, in 1874 20.90%, in 1882 23.51%, and in
1892 24.71%, while the percentage remained the same or decreased for
all other classes. In order to make up the resulting deficit, resort is
often had to night-lodgings. “The disadvantages of subletting are
obvious. ‘Children of both sexes have to sleep with their parents, and
often with strangers, in the same room, often even in the same bed; the
advantages of domesticity are lost; the tavern offers more pleasant
entertainment than being crowded together with wife and children in one
room that must be shared with strangers, and in which the opportunity
for quarreling and fighting, in consequence of the narrow quarters, is
constant. It is the bad housing conditions that are the cause of the
increasing alcoholism, of the break-up of the family life, and of the
lack of education for the youth.’ (Braun).” [261]

The chapter that concerns us next treats of the subsidiary businesses
engaged in by school children. It goes without saying that in the cases
where the wages of the father of the family must be increased by the
labor of the mother, the children also must be put to work at an age at
which they ought to have their leisure time for play. For though
child-labor in factories is a little limited by legislation, it is
still commonly practiced in household industry. Further most of the
children of the proletariat must, in their free hours, do all kinds of
work harmful to their physique and their morals. “It is plain to be
seen how greatly the school-children are injured by engaging in
additional work. Entirely aside from the harm they suffer in the matter
of health, and from the fact that the tired children cannot give
sufficient attention to the words of the teacher and that for many of
them their instruction is as good as lost, is the great fact that their
morals are in the highest degree endangered. Under the pressure of
necessity, these children learn to grasp every advantage, whether
allowable or not, and—not through their own fault, but through that of
society—are precociously familiar with vice.” [262] “Any one who
examines these conditions will not be surprised that according to the
statement of Superintendent Schönberger, out of 100 juvenile prisoners
in the Plötzensee prison near Berlin, 70 had been employed during
school days as breakfast-carriers, newsboys, messengers,
bowling-alley-boys, etc., early in the morning, from half past four on,
and in some cases still earlier, until school time, and in the
afternoon either the whole time, or from four till half past seven or
half past eight at night.” [263]

Next, Hirsch examines the influence of economic crises. He quotes,
among other things, the following from the researches of J. S(chmidt).
During the economic depression from 1875 to 1878 the number of
punishments inflicted by the “Ordnungspolizei” in the country of Baden
rose from 16,218 to 22,264, and that of the penalties inflicted by the
“Sittenpolizei” (having surveillance of prostitution) from 1995 to
4485. There were increases, therefore, of 40% and 125%. In the period
of prosperity from 1882 to 1885 these figures fell from 22,765 to
18,856 (16%), and from 4106 to 4007 (3%). During the critical years
from 1889 to 1892 the number of recidivists convicted of theft rose
18%, and the number of other thieves convicted 6%. In the period from
1875 to 1878 (years of crisis) the number of offenses against property
rose 17.4%, and decreased 13% in the years 1882 to 1885 (a period of
prosperity).

In conclusion the author points out the fact that there are also
criminals who are predisposed to crime by their physical constitution
(mental disorders), and treats of “the repression of crime and
prostitution.” [264]








CHAPTER VIII.

CONCLUSIONS.


Having come to the end of my exposition, I have still to sum up the
different chapters. As we have seen, a very small proportion of the
authors who have taken up the subject, deny the existence of the
relation between criminality and economic conditions, and in my opinion
they have not proved the correctness of their position.

The great majority of authors are of the opinion that economic
conditions occupy a more or less important position, but that other
factors besides these are also at work. I have tried to show that as
far as these factors are of a cosmic or religious nature, this thesis
cannot be correct; that as far as they are of an anthropological
nature, they play a rôle only with regard to a part of criminality.

Finally, we have seen that a small number of authors are of the opinion
that the influence of economic factors is sovereign. I have been able
to find no inaccuracies in the foundations of their theses.

Nearly all the authors—later I shall speak of the exceptions—have this
in common, that they give a very limited meaning to the words “economic
factors”, under which they include only poverty and wealth, and that
they do not inquire whether these phenomena do not themselves need
explanation, and whether economic conditions have not a great influence
upon the whole social organization. They consider them as being
phenomena of the same value as the other sides of the social life. In
other words, most authors have omitted to explain the present mode of
production and its consequences.

However, economic conditions, in my opinion, occupy an entirely
different place; they are the foundation upon which the social
structure rests. To make my thought clear I will once more call
attention to the classic formula of this doctrine, originated by Marx
and Engels, taken from the preface to the work, “Zur Kritik der
politischen Oekonomie”, which I have already quoted in treating of the
theories of Professor Ferri.

“In the social production of their life men enter into fixed, necessary
relationships in production, independent of their will, relationships
which correspond to a definite stage in the development of their
material powers of production. The sum total of these relationships
forms the economic structure of society, the real basis upon which the
juristic and political superstructure is erected, and to which definite
forms of social consciousness correspond. The form of production of the
material life conditions the social, political, and intellectual
life-process in general. It is not the consciousness of mankind that
determines their being, but their social being that determines their
consciousness.” [265]

In the second part of this work I will try to sketch a treatment of the
question according to this theory. As regards economic conditions I
shall limit myself, for different reasons, to the present system, i.e.
modern capitalism.

These reasons are the following:

First. A really scientific examination of the causes of criminality is
only possible since the existence of criminal statistics, i.e. since
the beginning of the 19th century. [266]

Second. Criminality has increased greatly under capitalism, and is of
the greatest importance to the whole social life.

Third. An examination of historic criminality is very interesting; that
of our own day is still more so. However, social science is not simply
a means of solving interesting problems, but also, and chiefly, a means
of pointing out to society the way to protect itself from scourges like
criminality, or if possible, to get rid of them entirely. Here the
saying of Marx applies: “The philosophers have only interpreted the
world differently; the important thing is to alter it.”



Above I have already remarked that some authors have an opinion that
differs from that of the majority, and are in agreement with the theory
cited. Among these must be cited Engels, one of the two founders of
this theory, and most of the authors of whom I spoke in the last
chapter. However, Engels has only made, in passing, some observations
upon the influence of capitalism on crime among the workers in
factories; Hirsch, in his interesting brochure, has pointed out only
certain sides of the economic life; and although the studies concerning
this question published by Lafargue and by Lux are more complete than
those of the first two authors, there are nevertheless important points
which these last have not examined, or to the bottom of which they have
not gone, as it seems to me. And it is quite comprehensible that it
should be so; for the work of Lafargue is only a magazine article, and
that of Dr. Lux is one of the subdivisions of a social-political
manual, in which he treats of crime among other social phenomena. The
works of the other authors noticed in Chapter VII, do not make the
study of the question in the manner noted, useless.

I am of the opinion, then, that while the works quoted have made
considerable progress, there is still much to be done. It therefore
appears to me that it will not be without profit to take up the
subject.



The theory of Marx and Engels results in our having a method of
investigation already marked out. While most authors who have published
studies upon the question, have thought it unnecessary to give an
exposition of the economic system in which we live, or perhaps have
given a little attention to it along with other social conditions, I
shall begin by setting forth the present economic system as that upon
which the other parts of the social life rest. These I shall treat in
their turn, in so far as they are connected with criminality. It is
obvious that this will be only a sketch, for if one wished all the
details, it would be enough to refer to the special literature upon the
subject. Then I shall investigate the question of how far criminality,
under its different forms, is the consequence of the conditions we have
found.



[Note to the American Edition: According to some criticisms of my book
it should have been my task not only to give a sketch of the economic
theory of Marx, but also to prove it “in extenso” and to refute the
criticisms of it, since it is not universally accepted.

It is true that this theory has not been generally accepted—a thing
that would be impossible from the social consequences of such
acceptation—but I claim that of all the economic theories, that of Marx
is the only one that daily wins more adherents, and more and more
interpenetrates all social science—even in the case of authors who are
the bitterest opponents of this theory.

To require that a book like mine should once more set forth and defend
the theory of Marx “in extenso”, is as impossible as to require that a
modern biologist, who proceeds upon the basis of the Darwinian theory,
should prove over again that his basis is sound. That there may be more
or less error in detail in the theory of Marx, as in that of Darwin, is
possible, but in general they have resisted, like a wall of bronze, all
attacks in the most pitiless of contests, that of opinions.

Let the adversaries of Marx’s theory judge without prejudice whether
that theory does not constitute a great step in advance in
criminology!]








PART TWO.


BOOK I.

THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM AND ITS CONSEQUENCES.


CHAPTER I.

THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM. [267]


In order to provide for his needs man has always been obliged to work,
and this work has always depended upon the physical environment and
especially upon the means of production. It is not our province to
enquire how or why the means of production were developed. It is enough
to show that because of their development the products which man had at
his disposal were multiplied. Now when these products become too
abundant for one group of producers, a surplus results, which may be
exchanged for products of a different sort of which the first group of
producers are deprived by reason of their circumstances. These
products, which are not destined for personal use but for exchange are
called commodities. Consequently it is its social qualities and not its
natural qualities that make a commodity of any given product. That an
exchange may be made, then, two conditions must be satisfied:

First, There must have been a division of labor; for there would be no
point in the exchange of identical products. The objects to be
exchanged are those which have no immediate usefulness for the person
who possesses them, while they are useful to those who do not possess
them.

Second, The persons who are exchanging must have full power to dispose
of their products—in other words, they must be the possessors of the
product which they wish to exchange.

In the beginning the relative quantities of the products exchanged for
each other must have varied greatly. But in course of time the exchange
of commodities took place in a ratio fixed for any one place and time;
ten hatchets, for example, being equivalent to five bows, etc. These
commodities must have a common quality which makes a comparison
possible; and it is this common quality which we call their value. The
first problem to be solved, then, is this: “What constitutes the value
of commodities?”

To become a commodity anything must provide for some need of man; it
must have the value of usefulness. Without this value a product can
never be a commodity. However, it is impossible that the quality which
different commodities have in common, and on the basis of which they
are compared, should be their usefulness, that is to say, their natural
qualities. For it is just because of their difference in usefulness [to
their possessors] that goods are exchanged.

“As regards their use-value goods are primarily of different quality;
as regards their exchange-value they can only be of different quantity,
without including a particle of use-value.” [268]

Since usefulness does not count in exchange there is only one quality
of the commodity that remains, that of being the product of labor. And
as we have withdrawn the consideration of usefulness in estimating
exchange-value, we must do the same for different kinds of work, so
that the only quality which remains to a commodity is that of being the
product of the labor of man in general. Any commodity, then, derives
its value only from the circumstance that it represents a certain
amount of labor of man in general.

The value of a commodity is determined by the quantity of labor it
represents, measured by the time required. Naturally by “work” is to be
understood here not individual work, but social work; or as Marx says:
“It is ... the quantity of work socially necessary, or the time
socially necessary for the production of a commodity, which determines
its value.” [269]

In measure as the division of labor is developed, production for
personal use diminishes, and the production of commodities increases,
until it finally becomes the universal form of production, and one
commodity (money) is developed as a universal equivalent. As a
consequence of the development of the production of merchandise, the
purchase and sale of goods becomes a special profession. The merchant
buys for a different reason from that which influences his customers.
While the latter buy for consumption, the former buys to sell again and
make a profit out of the transaction. The commodity which serves for
this purpose is called capital.

Consequently capital comes into existence at the moment when the
production of commodities has attained a certain degree of development.
Private property, the basis of the production of commodities, begins
from that point to show its capitalistic character, at first in an
imperceptible manner, which nevertheless becomes more and more
developed. The income of the artisan depends primarily upon his
personal qualities; that of the capitalist—as such—depends in the first
place upon the amount of his capital. The working power and capacity of
an individual are limited, so that the quantity that he can produce is
also limited; while money can be heaped up without limit. The larger
the sum of money anyone uses as capital, the more the money can
produce. But the reverse of the medal is not so pretty. Side by side
with the possibility of accumulating a fortune there is that of
becoming poor. This fact was not prominent at the entrance of
capitalism into the field, when poverty was not yet a general
phenomenon, but it increased more and more, so that at present we live
in a society in which the greater part of the population is poor.

In the Middle Ages the trades were developed in Europe; the division of
labor increased; tools were perfected; and commerce was developed,
chiefly as a consequence of the improvement of the means of
communication. The maritime route to India was discovered as well as
the American continent. Enormous sums of money, acquired by means of
commerce and pillage, flowed into Europe. With the discovery of these
countries the outlets for trade correspondingly increased. The trades,
however, not being in a position to furnish the great quantity of
commodities required, the merchants determined themselves to undertake
the wholesale production of articles intended exclusively for sale.

There was no lack of money to procure the raw materials and the tools,
to establish workshops and to hire workmen. The only difficulty to be
overcome was that of procuring these last. The workman who has in his
own possession the means of production will not sell his labor. To
attain their end the capitalists had to seek for persons who, having no
means of production, were obliged to sell their productive energy or
die of hunger.

For certain reasons it was possible for the needs of the capitalists to
be satisfied. On account of the development of the market in the cities
the demand for food, and for raw materials of every kind, such as wood,
wool, etc., increased, and agricultural production for the purpose of
sale increased, so that the peasants began to have money. This latter
fact complicated the relation between them and the feudal lords. So
long as the rent was paid in kind the lord demanded only as much as he
could consume; but from the day that the rent began to be paid in money
the landowner began to press the peasant more and more, since money can
always be used, and no one ever has enough. From this fact arose so
severe an exploitation that many peasants left the country to take
refuge in the towns.

The second reason why a large number of workmen were obtainable was
that the lords themselves began to produce commodities for city
markets, especially wool and wood. This took fewer laborers than
agriculture, but required more land, so that many peasants were driven
from their farms and, like the others, went to swell the population of
the cities.

Thus there was no further obstacle to wholesale production, and from
then on raw materials were purchased, workshops established, and the
labor of the proletariat procured. Human labor thus has become a
commodity, corresponding exactly to definition: first, it has no
use-value for the possessor if he has not the means of production, and,
on the other hand, has such a value for the person possessing these
means; second, the possessor of labor has the free disposition of it.

The contract is made; the proletariat on the one side furnishes the
commodity—labor—and the capitalist on the other gives the equivalent of
it. Now how much must be given for this commodity? In other words what
is the value of the labor delivered? The value of a commodity is
determined by the labor-time socially necessary for its production, in
this case necessary for the proletarian and his family to live; for the
workman being mortal, and capital having need of new forces, the wage
must be sufficient to raise a new generation of workers. The standard
of the workman’s needs is subject to variation according to time and
place (the causes of which variation we need not examine here), but it
is fixed for a certain country, time, and category of workers.

Let us suppose now that the process of production has a normal course,
that is to say, that it comes out as the capitalist wishes. He has
begun with a sum, A, and ends by possessing A + a. We must now explain
this surplus a, which, in the terminology of capitalistic production,
is called surplus-value. The surplus obtained from the labor of slaves
is easily explained. The owner leaves the slaves a part of the product
of their own labor to live on. The rest is his. His surplus springs
from the labor of others. The relation of the serf and his lord is, if
possible, even clearer. The serf works part of the week for himself and
on the remaining days for his master. The explanation of the surplus
produced by capital employed at usury or in primitive commerce (the
most ancient forms under which capital was employed) no longer offer
any great difficulties. The usurer appropriated to himself the
possessions of the borrower little by little and so ruined him
completely. The primitive merchant made himself a surplus by selling
dear something that he had bought at a trivial price, a transaction
which involved no increase in value. Now it is just this increase in
value that is to be explained upon the basis of the law that things of
equal value are exchanged, and not, as in the cases cited above, upon
the exceptions to the law.

If we represent the transaction of one who buys, not to make a profit,
but to exchange something which has no use-value for him for something
which has such a value (the simple circulation of commodities), by the
formula C—M—C, in which C stands for commodities and M for money, we
can represent the transaction of the capitalist by M—C—(M + m). In this
formula m stands for the surplus-value accruing to the capitalist at
the end of a successful operation. The latter formula is composed of
the factors M—C, the purchase of the commodity, and C—(M + m), the
sale. According to the law of the circulation of commodities the value
of M ought to be equal to C, but C in turn must be equal to M + m, a
thing which is possible only if C is a commodity which, while it is
being consumed, produces a value greater than what it has. However,
there is no value without labor; consequently the formula cited can
harmonize with reality only if labor is itself a commodity. And, as we
have seen above, it is such from the moment that the economic
development has reached a certain point.

What is now the course of the production of the surplus-value? The
capitalist has fitted up a factory, has procured tools and raw
material, has hired labor, and the process of production commences.
Suppose that the necessaries of life for the workman and his family may
be produced by six hours of work socially necessary; by making him
work, then, six hours the capitalist will have a product equal to that
of the raw material used, increased by that which is given it by the
tools and by the labor which the workman has put upon it. This value,
however, has been entirely paid out by the capitalist; he has no
surplus left; the transaction has failed. But ordinarily the process
succeeds in procuring profits for the capitalist, since in the contract
between him and the laborer it is not stipulated that the latter shall
work only the number of hours necessary to produce enough for his own
needs. On the contrary the workman is compelled to labor as long as his
strength will permit. The value produced by the workman after the time
necessary for the production of the equivalent of his needs falls to
the capitalist, and this it is which constitutes the surplus-value, the
value derived from work not paid for.

The aim of the capitalist is to procure for himself as large a
surplus-value as possible. He can attain his end at once by forcing the
laborer to work as long a time as it is possible for him to work. From
this springs the irreconcilable conflict between the interests of the
proletariat and those of capital, the combat over the length of the
working-day. The day has its natural limits (it is necessary that
certain hours be left to the workman for food and rest), its legal
limits (decreed too late by the state, driven on one side by the
workers themselves, and on the other by the plain certainty that
without this protection the working class would become enfeebled), and
finally its limits fixed by the pressure of the labor unions.

However, there is still one other way in which the surplus-value is
increased, as I shall explain by what follows. Let us suppose the
length of the working day to be twelve hours, and the time necessary
for the production of the equivalent of the workman’s needs to be six
hours. We can then represent the day as follows:


    A----|----|----|----|----|----|----|----|----|----|----|----B
                                  C


CB is consequently the time in which the surplus-value is produced. The
aim of the capitalist, then, is to protract the period CB as much as
possible, and this he can accomplish in two ways: first, that of which
we have just spoken, the prolongation of AB; second, the shortening of
AC in order that CB may be as long as possible, or in other words, the
shortening of the time necessary for the production of the necessaries
of life for the workman and his family. When the productivity of labor
rises, the value of the commodities falls; and when the value of the
commodities which the workman needs for his support falls, the value of
labor falls also. However, the increase of the productivity of labor is
only possible through the improvement of the means of production and
the methods of working, so that capitalism modifies its manner of
production unceasingly. In general the capitalist does not take account
of the fact that the more cheaply commodities are produced for sale,
the more the value of labor falls, and, other things being equal, the
more the surplus-value increases. The capitalist strives constantly to
make improvements in his methods of production in order to surpass his
competitors. Supposing that, by the employment of a new method of
working, he succeeds in producing in half an hour an article up to that
time generally made in an hour, he will then obtain an extra profit as
long as his competitors do not employ this method. But as soon as the
latter have improved their production in the same way, the time
socially necessary falls from an hour to half an hour, and the extra
profit of the man who first introduced the method ceases. The result
that remains is this: the value of labor has decreased, and the
relative surplus-value has consequently increased, in so far as the
commodities whose value has declined are destined to provide for the
needs of the workmen.

Before entering upon the consideration of some of the methods for
shortening the necessary hours of labor, attention must be fixed upon
the fact that, aside from this method, the capitalist tries above all
to lower the price of labor below its value, while the workers, for
their part, oppose this tendency and try to obtain the contrary; whence
there results a new cause for an inexorable struggle between labor and
capital, side by side with that over the length of the working-day.

Let us now examine the methods of abridging the labor-time necessary,
beginning with coöperation. As we have seen above the capitalistic
method of production begins when the capitalist has in his service a
sufficiently large number of workmen. In the days of the guilds the
master had also paid workers, but the surplus-value which he procured
from them was not great, since their number was small, a fact which
obliged him to work with them, since without this his income would have
been too small. The true capitalist is he who is permitted by the
amount of the surplus-value which he receives to live according to his
rank, without working with his laborers, reserving to himself only the
direction of affairs.

The difference, therefore, between capitalistic production and that at
the time of the guilds is in the first place only quantitative, but
there come in qualitative differences as well. In the first place the
differences in the individual capacities of the workmen disappear; the
ability of one neutralizes the smaller ability of the other, so that
the capitalist can count upon an average amount of labor. Next there is
economy in the new arrangement; because a structure to hold twenty-five
workmen working together costs less than twenty-five structures with
one workman in each. Finally, and most important of all, by having a
number of men working together, each doing his own share toward the
common end, we bring about a systematic working together, that is to
say, coöperation, which brings into being a new collective force
greater than the sum of the individual forces. Not only does
coöperation permit the accomplishment of work requiring a greater
expenditure of energy, but it also raises the productivity of labor.
The direction necessary for this joint labor falls to the capitalist as
such. Submission of the workman to the capitalist is, then, an
indispensable condition of the capitalistic method of production.

We come now to another method for increasing the relative amount of the
surplus-value, the manufactory proper, a more developed form of
coöperation, which became general between the middle of the sixteenth
century and the end of the eighteenth. This comes from two causes. On
the one side it is due to the combination of different trades, up to
that point independent of each other. The manufacture of a carriage,
for example, requires the work of a wheelwright, a harness-maker, a
painter, etc., who all exercise their trades independently of each
other. The capitalist unites them all in one trade, that of
carriage-maker, in which the occupation of each becomes more limited,
more specialized. The painter, for example, becomes especially a
painter of carriages. On the other side the manufactory is due to the
bringing together of workmen of the same trade into a single workshop,
and to the division of labor made possible in this way. Thus, for
instance, in the manufacture of pins, each pin is no longer made by a
single workman but by several, each of whom does only a special part of
the work.

It is clear that through the introduction of manufactory methods the
productivity of labor has been enormously increased, so that the time
necessary for the production of the necessaries of life for the workmen
has become shorter, and the surplus-value correspondingly augmented.
The part taken by the workman in the process of production is quite
different from what it was in the time of the guilds. The different
operations that he performed in making the complete product are now
replaced by the monotonous and repeated production of a single one of
the parts. From this point dates the division of workmen into skilled
and unskilled laborers. The latter are those whose work is such as to
require little or no apprenticeship, and they are the cause of a new
lowering of the price of labor.

We have still to take up the question of the introduction of machinery
and of manufacturing on a large scale. Although at the period of the
early manufactories the workman was obliged to perform a monotonous
task, which in so far may be called “mechanical”, yet this task was
performed, though with the aid of tools, by his own hands. But in the
eighteenth century the machine was invented, that is to say, a
mechanism which took the place both of the workman and of his tools.
Machines were introduced because they saved hand-work, and consequently
lowered the price of the product and relatively increased the
surplus-value.

Each developed mechanism is composed of three parts: the motor, the
transmission, and the operating part. It is to the development of this
last that the economic revolution of the eighteenth century is due.
However, there was needed a motive power greater and more regular than
those then available. The steam-engine, invented by James Watt,
provided for this need and, in its turn, led to new developments of
operating machinery. The steam-engine was capable of running many
operating machines at the same time, and thus the modern factory was
established. In branches in which the product requires a series of
different manipulations, a system of machines has been contrived of
which one furnishes the material to the next without the intervention
of hands, so that a system of automatic mechanism has been produced.

The revolution caused by the introduction of machines in one branch of
industry necessitated its introduction into another, etc. The means of
communication and of transportation were extended. The steamboat, the
railroad, and the telegraph were invented. Because of important
inventions in the manufacture of machines it finally became possible to
produce the necessary quantity of machines of all kinds.

What are the most important consequences of the new system of
production? In the first place stands the introduction of the labor of
women and children, since tending machines generally does not require
great muscular strength. The advantages which accrue to the capitalist
from the employment of women and children are obvious. Since the price
of the workman’s labor is determined by the time necessary for the
production of the necessities of life not only for himself, but also
for his family, as soon as the whole family are compelled to sell their
labor, the price of that labor will simply equal that of the labor of
the workman alone. Ordinarily the income of the family will rise a
little under these circumstances, but, because of the absence of the
wife from the household, expenses will increase also. The increase of
the surplus-value, obtained by the labor of women and children, is
therefore important. Besides, the women and children have less power to
resist the capitalist than men have, while the men, in their turn, are
weakened by the competition of women and children.

In the second place the introduction of machines produces in the mind
of the capitalist a desire to prolong the working day as much as
possible, for the following reasons among others. The greater the
number of hours each day in which the machine is in operation, the more
quickly it will return its cost through the product, and, other things
being equal, the shorter will be the time required for the capitalist
to gain the same amount of surplus-value. Suppose A works his machines
for 8 hours a day, and B works as many machines for 16 hours; B’s
machines will return their cost through the product in half the time
needed by A’s. Consequently B will gain double the surplus-value in the
same time, so that A also will be driven to work his machines for 16
hours. And since a machine deteriorates even when it is not in use,
there is, when the machines are stopped, a loss of value which the
capitalist cannot retrieve. Hence the tendency to prolong the
working-day. In the third place every capitalist runs the danger of
seeing his competitors introduce new machines which save still more
work and so diminish the value of his own. The more quickly a machine
returns its cost, the less the danger just mentioned becomes.

Finally, I have still to notice the following cause for the
prolongation of the working-day. The object of the employment of
machines is the increase of the surplus-value through their use. This
increase, however, is possible only through the diminution in the
number of workmen employed by the capitalist. But since the
surplus-value is created only by the workmen, any diminution in their
number is to the disadvantage of the capitalist. In order to overcome
this he attempts to prolong the day.

The more machinery is developed, the more the attention which the
workman must give to his work increases; in other words, the more
intense the labor becomes. The tendency of the capitalist to increase
the intensity of labor reaches its apogee as soon as the working time
is limited, for different reasons. In order that the surplus-value may
be equal to what it was formerly, the workman, for example, must
produce as much in eleven hours as he formerly produced in thirteen
hours. The means by which the intensity of labor is increased (not to
enter into unnecessary details) are; first, the manner of fixing
wages—piece-work, and second, the practice of making the workmen tend
more machines than formerly, and of driving the machines faster, so as
to force the workmen to a greater intensity of labor.

The contest between the large manufacturing establishments and the
small factories and workshops has led gradually but infallibly to the
destruction of the latter. They are forced to maintain the competitive
struggle by incredibly long hours of labor, by an unlimited
exploitation of the labor of women and children, etc. In this way it is
often possible to resist competition for some time, but finally the
large manufactory triumphs all along the line.

Agriculture also, though to a less degree than manufacturing, has been
revolutionized by the introduction of machines. Rural workers who have
become superfluous have betaken themselves to the cities, and there go
to swell the population already enormously increased by industrialism.

The exposition which I have just given of the origin of the
surplus-value is sufficient for this work. It is not necessary for our
subject to stop to consider the fact that a part of the surplus-value
is destined to become capital, while the other part is consumed by
those who have appropriated the whole. As has been shown above, the
employment of machines, etc., has increased in every branch of
industry, and this has brought it about that the capital necessary to
any manufacturing establishment increases continually under the
pressure of competition. Hence it follows that capitalism itself forces
the capitalist to invest as new capital part of the surplus-value
acquired by him. But aside from this, it is capitalism also that
produces the capitalist’s penchant for always investing more capital,
which, in its turn, produces a greater surplus-value than the original
capital, etc. And since the accumulation of capital has no limits, the
greediness of the capitalist has none, and he is driven to increase his
capital incessantly, even when his income is so great that it permits
him to satisfy every possible need.

However, the group of capitalists of which we have been speaking is not
the only one that gains surplus-value. Industrial capital is obliged to
share the total surplus-value with commercial capital, the capital
consisting of money, and that consisting of real estate. In the first
place, a part of the surplus-value is claimed by commercial capital.
For the economic system in force would not be able to operate without
commerce. The development of capitalism has led to an extensive
division of labor in the class of capitalists (banks, insurance
companies, etc.), and the capital invested in these enterprises must
equally have its share of the total surplus-value. Capital in the form
of money plays an increasingly important part in modern capitalism, and
so must have its share of the surplus-value.

The owners of the soil also appropriate a considerable part. The land
is the most indispensable means of production, and is incapable of
being increased at will. As capitalism increases, the demand for
territory becomes greater and greater. This causes the ground rents in
general to rise, which means that the share of the total surplus-value
which the land-owners appropriate becomes greater and greater. It is
especially in the cities, which are highly developed under capitalism,
and in which, consequently, the demand for land is great and the supply
relatively small, that ground rents have risen to an unheard of degree,
and this to the prejudice of the health and happiness of the less
privileged classes.

Up to this point we have been necessarily supposing that the capitalist
succeeds in making a profit. But, as we know, it often happens that he
does not attain his end, that his capital produces no added value, that
he even loses it entirely or in part. This case being important for the
subject in hand we must stop to consider it for a moment. As has been
shown above, the capitalist begins by purchasing labor and the means of
production in order to set in motion the process of production. For him
the difficulty then consists of selling the manufactured product at its
value and of thus realizing the added value which is a part of this. At
times, aided by circumstances, he succeeds in selling the product above
its value, and so makes an extra profit. On the other hand, he runs the
risk of having to sell the product below its value, or of not being
able to sell it at all.

The causes of the poor success of the process are of different kinds.
In the first place, the capitalist may not have the ability necessary
for the direction of the process of production. For example, the
product made under his management may be inferior to that of his
competitor, though the cost of production is the same; the means of
production may be purchased at too high a price; he may not have been
in touch with the tastes of consumers, etc.; reasons all of which
render his product unsalable, or salable at a loss.

In the second place, circumstances independent of his own act may
present themselves which have the same result. Let us look at some of
them. To begin with, the unforeseen cessation of payment on the part of
one of his important debtors may oblige him to sell his goods at a
sacrifice in order to satisfy his creditors. Again, he may lack the
capital necessary to meet competition. For the amount of capital
necessary in every branch of industry or commerce becomes greater and
greater, and the man who cannot procure this capital is forced little
by little to give ground to his competitors and finally to give up
business altogether.

In the third place, it very often happens that, as a result of
competition, there is an oversupply of commodities, which from this
very fact are unsalable, or must be sold for less than their value. In
the periods of prosperity this case is not general. But it is the rule
in crises. Because of their great importance to the relation between
criminality and economic conditions, it is necessary to pause here to
examine the cause and origin of these crises.

Economic crises, that is to say periods in which the economic life is
greatly disturbed, are due to various circumstances; for example, to a
war which puts obstacles in the way of the regular continuance of
international commerce. But aside from such causes there are others
which are natural to the present economic system itself, and which
bring on these crises periodically. It is these causes, which are the
more important, of which it is necessary to treat here.

A crisis is the result of overproduction. This does not imply that in
every case overproduction will bring about a crisis. If one who is
producing for his own consumption happens to produce more than he can
consume, the result will be that during a certain period he will
proceed to produce less, and the equilibrium will be reëstablished. But
when one manufactures not for himself but for the market the situation
is entirely different. Each manufacturer of commodities produces
separately, that is to say without any understanding with his
fellow-manufacturers, articles of which he himself has no need, but
which he attempts to exchange for money in order to obtain what he does
need. If he does not succeed in selling his commodities he is left
without money to buy the commodities that are necessary to him.
Overproduction can thus have very harmful results for those who hold
commodities.

Now how does it happen that the capitalistic mode of production causes
periodically a production greater than the possible consumption? (It
goes without saying that this phrase is not to be taken to mean that
the consumers are physically incapable of using the product, but merely
that there are not enough buyers.) As has been shown above,
capitalistic production is carried on for the sake of the added value,
that is to say, the value of the unpaid labor. In other words, the
working class produces more than it consumes. In feudal society the
surplus was entirely consumed by the class which appropriated it; at
present, on the contrary, the owning class use part of the surplus to
form new capital. For this comes a continually increasing accumulation
of capital, and consequently a greater and greater quantity of products
which in the end find no buyer. For the extension of production
increases the number of workmen necessary, and consequently increases
the demand also, but these workmen produce in their turn more than they
consume. The overproduction is not, then, neutralized by a greater
consumption. On the contrary it furnishes the material for an
overproduction still greater. Hence capitalism causes crises
periodically as the result of an overproduction caused by too small a
consumption on the part of the working class.

Since the mass of capital increases without cessation it is
indispensable to find new investments, and to broaden the market. From
this it results, among other things, that the capitalist class is
forced to take up the policy of political expansion and to conquer
countries where capitalism has not yet become rooted. If it succeeds in
finding a new outlet, then, production increases enormously, existing
factories are enlarged, new ones are established, etc., and the new
market is inundated with goods. But in the end this market ceases to be
able to absorb the continually increasing mass of products, so much the
more since the production of the country itself also increases as
capitalism gains foothold there. The commodities remain, then, unsold,
and a crisis is begun. Production must be stopped or decreased; the
stock of commodities being thus made smaller the equilibrium begins
little by little to reëstablish itself; after which the movement is
repeated. But since the capitalistic method of production little by
little spreads itself over the whole earth, it becomes increasingly
difficult to find countries where capitalism has not been implanted.
Hence overproduction tends to become chronic.

Besides the cause already set forth there is still another circumstance
which can produce a crisis or aggravate one already existing; I refer
to the lack of order in the present mode of production. Suppose that
the demand for iron is great at any given moment. The production will
then increase so quickly, and in such a degree (each manufacturer
ignoring what his competitors are doing), that the supply will far
exceed the demand. As a result manufacturing will be checked. As soon
as overproduction occurs in as important a branch of industry as the
manufacture of iron, there will follow also a stoppage of production in
other branches, and a general crisis will ensue.

The consequences of a crisis for the capitalist class are well known.
Many are forced to stop producing, are no longer able to pay their
creditors, and draw many of their debtors in their train. Because of
the complexity of the present system of production the consequences of
a crisis are very far reaching. It is naturally the small capitalists
who are stricken first, whence it follows that during crises there is a
great concentration of capital.



Just as in the first part of this discussion I proceeded on the
assumption that the capitalist always attains his end, i.e. gains the
surplus-value, just so I have also been speaking as if the workman
always sold his labor. Let us look now at the case of the man who does
not succeed in selling it. In order that a contract be entered into
between capitalist and workman it is necessary that labor be desired
and offered. If the workman for his part cannot deliver the labor
contracted for, or not enough of it, whether from sickness or from
weakness, it is perhaps but a question of exchange, and the workman is
abandoned to his fate. Capitalism rests upon this fact that there is a
class of men, much more numerous than any other, who are deprived of
everything and consequently are forced to sell their labor; otherwise
no workman would care to close a contract.

Let us look at the other side of the question, when the supply of labor
exceeds the demand. Those who do not succeed in selling their labor are
then equally abandoned to their own resources. From what causes in the
capitalistic method of production does it happen that the supply of
labor is in excess of the demand? Are these causes to be found in too
great an increase in the population, or in the method of production
itself?

It has been shown above that the composition of capital changes
incessantly. Machinery becomes more and more developed and a great part
of capital is composed of machines. The introduction of machines has
taken place because they economize labor. Thus a certain number of
workmen find themselves without occupation. It is true that there is a
mitigating circumstance, namely that there is an increased demand for
labor in other branches (manufacture of machines), but this demand can
never be as great as the amount of labor rendered superfluous by
machinery, for otherwise machines would never have been introduced.
However short the apprenticeship required by modern industry, it is
nevertheless impossible for a workman to change from one branch to
another at short notice. Thus the consequences for workmen thrown out
of employment continue to be serious notwithstanding the increased
demand in another branch. The only case in which the introduction of
machines will occasion no unemployment will be when the demand for
commodities increases extraordinarily, as, for example, when a new
market is opened up.

However there are still other causes of forced unemployment. Such are
the introduction of the labor of women and children, the migration of
rural workers to the cities, immigration from backward countries, and
the supplanting of small businesses, by which members of the lower
middle class are forced down into the proletariat.

The causes of overpopulation are found, then, in the system of
production itself, and not in a too great increase of the population; a
conclusion to be drawn also from the fact that as far as actual
productivity of labor is concerned each produces more than enough for
his needs. There are, then, always a number of persons who desire to
work but cannot find employment. In periods of crisis the number of
these increases enormously. The so-called “reserve army of labor” is a
condition indispensable to capitalism. Without it sudden development in
periods of prosperity would be impossible. Without it also the power of
organized labor would become so great that the surplus-value would run
serious danger. It is just because the supply of labor exceeds the
demand that the power of the capitalists over the workmen is so great,
and also that it happens so often that the interests of the workmen are
thwarted.



We come now to the end of my exposition. For our subject it is
unnecessary to continue it further. I should like, however, to draw
attention to two more points. The continually increasing concentration
of capital has as a consequence that the conduct of the business under
the direction of the capitalist himself more and more gives place to
the stock company, which combines the capital of numerous persons, and
gives the direction to a salaried employe. Following this,
concentration drives the owners in one branch of industry to combine
for the purpose of eliminating competition, and thus of increasing
profits; in this way the “trusts” come into being. Competition, the
fundamental principle of capitalism, is changed into its opposite,
monopoly.








CHAPTER II.

SOCIAL CONDITION OF THE DIFFERENT CLASSES.


Let us pass now to the social condition in which the different social
classes live in consequence of the place they occupy in the economic
system.




A. THE BOURGEOISIE.

After a long and difficult struggle against feudalism the bourgeoisie,
the class possessing the means of production, came out victorious. It
has grown and become more powerful, and in almost all the countries
where capitalism exists it is still the directing class.

The bourgeoisie is divided into three groups. The first comprises the
capitalists who direct their business themselves. As has been shown in
the preceding pages the power of this group is based upon its
monopolizing the surplus-value. The idea which predominates among the
bourgeoisie in general, and particularly among the first group, is to
gain money, always more money. This thirst for gold is not quenched
when the man has arrived at a point where he can live a luxurious life
and gratify all his caprices. Thanks to capitalism it is possible to
amass wealth without limit, so that the capitalist is never satisfied,
however enormous may be the sums which he has gained. The consequence
is that in general he is little developed in other directions, uses all
his time in attaining the end he wishes for, has a mind only
superficially cultivated, and if he is interested in art he regards it
simply as a pastime which he procures for money.

Next to this group comes that of the persons whose sole occupation
consists in appropriating a part of the surplus-value to increase their
capital and in spending the rest for a luxurious life. It is
unnecessary to set forth here the regrettable consequences of idleness
and too easy a life. Doubtless there are in this group some persons who
work and do not squander their income. But the fact remains that the
present economic system produces a class who are not forced to work and
can dissipate what others produce. The luxury displayed by the
bourgeoisie has injurious consequences for the whole population. Not
only do many persons aid this class in spending a part of the
surplus-value, but further, as a consequence of the uninterrupted
increase of luxury among the bourgeoisie (the result of the continued
increase in the surplus-value), desire becomes so much the greater
among the other classes as they have the less possibility of satisfying
it.

The development of capitalism (the growth of stock companies) is the
reason why the above-mentioned group of capitalists increases in
comparison with the first group. The control of affairs is more and
more abandoned to salaried employes. With these we come to the third
and last group; the so-called liberal professions, in which men provide
for their needs by intellectual labor. They are not capitalists in the
strict sense of the term, for they live by selling their labor; but as
they are recruited principally from the bourgeoisie, and in general
have nearly the same standard of living as the bourgeoisie, it will be
best to treat them here. Under the capitalistic system those who
cultivate science or the arts are obliged to sell their products. There
was a time when their number being limited their products brought a
high price. However the development of capitalism has been the cause of
a continually increasing demand for these persons. The task of the
state and municipality becoming constantly greater requires an
increasing number of functionaries; the larger application of science
to industry demands more engineers, chemists, etc.; the multiplication
of stock companies puts the direction of affairs more and more into the
hands of salaried employes; etc., etc.

The extension of university education produced a greater supply, and
this occasioned a considerable fall in the price of the commodity. In
the end the supply began to exceed the demand; in this territory also
there is an overproduction. Thence it happens that the price of this
commodity often falls below its value, and thus a sort of scientific
proletariat is formed. Just as the merchant on account of
overproduction in his branch can dispose of his goods only by taking
advantage of every possible method, so men of the liberal professions
must at times have recourse to similar means if they wish to attain a
great success or even to support themselves.

Although I speak of these persons under the head of “bourgeoisie” this
is not an exact classification. Not only does their material condition
sometimes differ from that of the bourgeoisie, but in other regards
they cannot be treated under the same head. Many of them are
descendants of those who have practiced the same profession; others
have come from among the bourgeoisie proper, and have chosen the
profession in question from inclination and natural disposition. These
circumstances as well as the influence of the profession itself bring
it about that for the last group the gaining of money is not the
principal end as with the first, but that other motives also impel
them.

In the next place we must fix our attention upon a matter which
concerns the entire body of the bourgeoisie: the uncertainty of the
future, for no one, not even the richest, is sure of it. In the
exposition of the economic system which we have been considering the
principal causes of this state of things have been indicated; it is
therefore useless to go over the details again. It is not only those
who lack capital or the ability to direct an enterprise, whose position
is uncertain. A manufacturer can be ruined by an invention which makes
his product unsalable; an unforeseen fall in price may have the same
effect upon a merchant; etc., etc. This uncertainty reaches its height
during crises, and, as a consequence of the complexity of economic life
at present, the fall of one has disastrous consequences for those who
have relations with him. From this it happens that to the agitation and
weakness which are the consequences of competition, is added the fear
of losing one’s position.

The cause of this fear is obvious. The capitalist who is ruined, and
the stock-holder whose securities become valueless, see themselves
thereby deprived of everything that makes life worth living, power,
luxury, importance, etc., while the possibility of recovery without
capital seems very small. This is especially true of the first two
groups of the bourgeoisie. Nevertheless the position of the liberal
professions is not very stable, though it is somewhat more so than that
of the other groups.

Whence does the bourgeoisie recruit itself? In great part from the
descendants of the bourgeoisie, in a less degree from the other
classes. If a “petit-bourgeois” or a proletarian finds himself
incorporated into the ranks of the bourgeoisie it is by virtue of
extraordinary circumstances. They may reach this station because they
have qualities which especially fit them to direct capitalistic
enterprises; but in this case circumstances must arise to bring their
capacity to light and give them a chance to develop it.

Although a relatively small number succeed in passing from another
class to that of the bourgeoisie, this does not prevent nearly all from
having an ardent desire to enrich themselves and from seizing every
opportunity which may help them attain this end. (The only exception is
found in those workers who understand that the historic task of the
working class is to found a society where there shall be neither rich
nor poor.) A man will often start a factory or a shop without having
either capital or ability, in the hope of raising himself in the social
scale; and unless the circumstances are extraordinarily favorable
failure follows almost immediately. This applies also quite as strongly
to the capitalists who for one reason or another have failed in
business; they try to gain success in another branch at any cost, even
if capital and ability are lacking. But such a course can only retard
their fall, and they end infallibly by sinking permanently to the rank
of the proletarian.

What I have just been saying brings out strongly the character of the
present process of production. Production is not undertaken for the
sake of consumption, but for profit, so that the man who believes that
he has a good chance to improve his condition goes to work to produce,
without asking himself whether there is need of his products, or
whether he can meet the required conditions.

As to the relation of the bourgeoisie, as a class, to other classes,
and especially to the proletariat, a few words will suffice after the
exposition I have given of present economic conditions. “In every
nation there are two nations.” These words describe the relations in
question. From their mode of life the bourgeoisie and the proletariat
remain strangers to one another. [270] The bourgeoisie, having arrived
at a wrong idea of the present system, do not consider the proletariat
as the class which sustains society by its toil, but as a necessary
evil. According to the bourgeois every strike is a diminution of his
rights, an encroachment upon his property. In the political field the
bourgeoisie, notwithstanding its intrinsic divisions, acts as a unit
against the proletarians; a fact which does not prevent there being
opposing interests within the class: in the first place the contest of
the different groups of capitalists (manufacturers against agrarians,
etc.) and then the opposing interests of the manufacturers within each
group.




B. THE PETTY BOURGEOISIE.

In reality the line of demarcation between the bourgeoisie and the
petty bourgeoisie is not drawn with the precision desirable for a
theoretical exposition. Just as there are numerous gradations in the
bourgeoisie, so are there in the petty bourgeoisie.

It is the petty bourgeoisie which has among its different classes the
most ancient traditions. There was a time when it was strong and
powerful. But the development of capitalism has changed all that.
Industrialism has arisen and undermined the petty bourgeoisie. In the
combat the small capitalist must eventually go down. He has not, like
his adversaries, scientific forces at his disposal, has no great
credit, cannot, in consequence of the insufficiency of his capital,
make use of new inventions; in short, his arms are inferior to those of
his antagonists. All this does not make him renounce the contest at
once; on the contrary, it arouses him to bring all his forces into
play. In consequence of his position in the economic life he has no
breadth of view. He cannot comprehend that what earned bread for his
ancestors during so many years will some day fail. This is the reason
that, as soon as large capital enters into the competition, the small
manufacturer overdrives himself, and not only himself but his workmen
also, and further, attempts to lower wages, lengthen the working day,
and introduce women and children to take the place of men. Competition
forces the merchant to take advantage of his customers in all sorts of
ways, a fact which gives commerce its character; for the art of
commerce is to buy cheap and sell dear. Hence there is opposition
between the merchant and the manufacturer on the one hand, and between
merchant and customer on the other. This is why the merchant is led to
depreciate the article he buys, and to praise that which he is selling.
This tendency naturally becomes stronger as competition becomes
fiercer. Advertising, a system of deceit, is invented to draw
purchasers at any cost; and the point is even reached where men no
longer give exact weight (“My competitors do not give it,” says the
merchant to himself), and sell goods of poorer quality than
represented. This is why commerce has a moral code of its own.

However, notwithstanding their desperate resistance, the situation of
the petty bourgeoisie becomes worse and worse, and this has important
social consequences, for example, the increase of the labor of women
outside of their own homes. Whole groups of the petty bourgeoisie are
so fallen into decadence that the plane of their existence has become
the same as that of the proletariat, or has even fallen below it.
Finally the contest with the large capitalist means not simply
degradation to the petty bourgeois, but absolute ruin. When a crisis
comes the small capitalists are the first to feel the shock. Their ruin
may come in various ways; their business may be annihilated
altogether—in which case they are permanently reduced to the ranks of
the proletariat—or it may become dependent upon great capital under the
name of home industry, i.e. wage labor masked under the appearance of
independence. Only those who have been able to save a part of their
capital from the wreck can try fortune once more in another branch of
industry where great capital has not yet begun to compete, but they are
sure to be pursued and finally overtaken by their enemy.

As in the case of the bourgeoisie, the relations which the different
members of the petty bourgeoisie have among themselves are determined
by the economic system; fierce competition, life in a little circle
where ideas cannot be broadened, all this breeds envy, hatred, and
meanness. [271]

As to intellectual culture a great part of the petty bourgeoisie takes
rank between the bourgeoisie and the proletariat. Generally the
children of this class are better taught than those of the proletariat.
But since the field of their ideas is very restricted and the struggle
for existence requires all their time, their intellectual level remains
in general much below the average level of the bourgeoisie. Others
still who are of the lowest stratum of the petty bourgeoisie have the
same development as the proletariat.

The petty bourgeoisie is recruited from the descendants of the same
class, then from among the bourgeois who have failed in business, and
finally from former proletarians. These last are those who cannot sell
their labor for some reason, and try to gain a livelihood by making an
insignificant capital of value in trading. Their plane of living does
not differ from that of the proletariat unless by being lower.

As to the relation of the petty bourgeoisie to the other classes, it is
naturally hostile to the bourgeoisie, since it is that class which has
deprived it, or is still depriving it, of its influence. This hostility
is, however, of a different kind from that which the working class
feels toward the bourgeoisie. The petty bourgeoisie envies the
bourgeoisie; it desires also to become rich, and thereby powerful. On
the other hand it feels no community of interest with the working
class, whose fixed determination to be free from the wage system it
holds in abhorrence. The political position of the petty bourgeoisie,
placed as it is between the bourgeoisie and the proletariat, has
necessarily become an equivocal one.




C. THE PROLETARIAT.

The proletariat, that class of persons who do not possess the means of
production and who can exist only by the sale of their labor, dates
from modern times. Between the independent artisan and the modern
proletarian comes the journeyman as a link in the chain. The
difference, however, between the journeyman and the proletarian is
great. The journeyman generally lodged with his master, worked with
him, and was considered as a member of the family. And since the means
of production necessary were still quite limited, the journeyman by
saving his wages had a chance some day to become master. With this hope
he came to consider himself as having common interests with his
employer.

The situation of the proletarian is entirely different. His work is
entirely separate from that of his employer; the lengthening of the
working-day does not imply that the capitalist works longer also. The
workman lodges apart, and it makes little difference to the employer
how his employes are housed and fed. The means of production being very
dear, and the knowledge necessary to direct any business being lacking,
the proletarian can almost never become an employer.

As has been shown it is the ruined members of the petty bourgeoisie who
have formed the first stock of the proletariat. But although this class
is still reinforced in the same way the greatest part of the
proletariat is now composed of the descendants of proletarians.

We can easily comprehend the situation of the proletariat provided we
do not lose sight of the basis of the present economic system, that is,
the fact that the object of production is to gain for some the largest
possible surplus-value at the expense of the rest of the population.
The child of the proletarian is set to work at an age when the child of
the bourgeois parents is still leading a care-free life, with nothing
to do but to develop his powers. When taken to the factory the young
proletarian finds himself in the midst of ignorant and coarse men
caring nothing for him, and soon picks up their bad habits. It is in
this environment that the proletarian will pass the greatest part of
his life without hope of ever raising himself above it.

The greater part of the trades practiced have an unfavorable effect,
frequently even very harmful to the health of the workmen (on account
of great heat, too much dust, injurious gases, etc.). These prejudicial
influences might be checked or prevented, but it costs money to make a
factory sanitary, with no immediate return, and hygienic suggestions
are therefore generally not followed. A number of trades constantly
threaten the workers with death or mutilation; but although safety
devices can almost always remove the danger, for the reason above
stated they are still many times left untried.

As regards the length of the working-day, moderate work is a pleasure,
excessive work mere torment. Except in so far as the laws and the labor
unions have intervened, the day has been prolonged until there is left
only the time absolutely necessary for food and sleep. Many workmen are
not even given the night for sleeping, for in many factories the night
force succeeds that on duty in the daytime. We may read in the holy
Scriptures that a day has been set aside for rest, but this does not
prevent Sunday from being a day of work under the capitalistic system,
even though we are supposed to be living in a Christian society.

In general the work in factories is very monotonous, and hence
brutalizing; and further, fatiguing from its great intensity. Moreover
a vexatious discipline is sometimes maintained. However harmful may be
the results of factory labor upon the physical, intellectual, and moral
condition of the worker, they are less so than the results of
sweat-shop labor. For sweat-shop hours are still longer than those of
the factory; and the work is done in a place which is both kitchen and
bedroom, so that not only is the workman injured but his family as
well.

Let us now take up the question of wages. It is necessary that the wage
should be enough to procure what is strictly needful, and in fact wages
generally do not rise above this standard. Further the workman buys at
a high price goods of low quality, for he who cannot spend much is
powerless in dealing with the producers. Since the workman does not
draw his wages till he has done the work, he must get credit for the
necessaries of life (often being obliged to add to his debts on account
of sickness or unemployment). His wages prevent his paying his debts,
and force him, therefore to continue to trade with his creditor, who
cheats him at every turn. Again, in some branches of industry he is
obliged to buy what he wants from the capitalist, or from the foreman
(truck-system), or to live in a house which belongs to the capitalist
(cottage system)—and then gets poorer quality at a higher price than
elsewhere.

Let us take up next the dwellings of the proletariat. Capitalism is the
cause of a great congestion of persons in a limited area. An enormous
rise in the price of land in the cities and consequently a similar rise
in rents have been the result. No class spends a larger part of its
income in rent than the laboring class. The proletariat is not only
lodged expensively but badly. All those who pass through the laborers’
districts know the monotonous rows of houses, ill-built, uniform and
simple. But the internal arrangement of these buildings is much more
miserable; the stairs and landings are narrow, the rooms small, badly
lighted and ventilated, and often must serve for kitchen and bedroom
combined. But notwithstanding the limited space, the number of inmates
often is further increased by taking lodgers, in an attempt to make
both ends meet. For all these reasons the house of the working-man is
not a real home in which he can be at ease.

As if these consequences of capitalism were not serious enough, the
labor of married women is added. By this the life of the family,
already damaged in so many ways, has been destroyed. Furthermore the
physical effect upon the woman, and even more upon the child with which
she is pregnant, is most prejudicial, without reckoning that her moral
condition suffers equally.

Up to this point I have been speaking of the proletarian on the
supposition that he has been able to sell his labor-power. But, as we
have seen already, when this sale is not possible, he and his family
are left to their fate. This then is what freedom of labor means, a
freedom that the slave never knows, freedom to die of hunger. No one
guarantees to the workman or his family the means of subsistence if,
for any reason, he is not able to sell his labor. The slave-owner had
an interest in taking care of a sick slave, for the slave represented
value which he did not care to see diminished. But if a workman is sick
he is discharged and replaced by another. The sickness and death of the
laborer do not harm the capitalist at all.

I have set forth above the numerous causes which prevent the workman
from selling his labor. Forced idleness has become chronic little by
little, reaching its acute stage in times of crisis. Then seasonal
trades make the work of thousands dependent upon the weather. Aside
from general causes, which affect whole groups, there are also
individual causes. A workman displeases his employer, it may be because
he is one of the leaders of a union, or for some other reason; he is
discharged, and runs, especially in times of economic depression, the
risk of not being able to find employment elsewhere. If the worker
falls ill or is injured (this often happens as a consequence of an
unhealthful or dangerous trade), or when he reaches old age (and hard
work ages men quickly), he is condemned. If the period of idleness
lasts long the workman loses his ability and the habit of working (for
working is above all a habit), and the time is not far distant when he
will become altogether incapable of working.

The intellectual condition of the working class is easily understood.
In his youth the child learns but little. The circle of his ideas
remains restricted, since his parents have ordinarily neither the
knowledge, the opportunity, nor the desire to supplement the little
that is learnt at school. At the age when the child begins to think for
himself, and his aptitudes begin to manifest themselves, he is put to
work. The little that the proletarian has learned in his childhood is
quickly forgotten under the pressure of the long, monotonous toil,
which dulls his intelligence and makes him thus less sensitive to
higher impressions. Even if this were not the case, the long duration
of labor fatigues the workman too much, his domestic life does not
permit him to develop himself, and further he has no money for
intellectual pleasures. The pleasures of the workman belong to his kind
of life. Consequently his amusements are rough and coarse. Alcohol and
sexual intercourse are often the only pleasures he knows. [272]

The life of the working-man is less retired than that of the bourgeois.
He sees continually the misery of his companions, which is also his
own, he feels himself more at one with them, but the demand for labor
always remaining below the supply, competition among the workers
arouses antagonistic feeling among them. The possibility of some day
becoming rich being almost entirely cut out, the working-man is less
avaricious than the bourgeois, and less economical; he lives from day
to day, and if he happens to get a little more than usual at any time
he spends it at once.

The situation may be summed up as follows: under the capitalistic
system the greater part of the population, the part upon whose labor
the entire social fabric is based, lives under the most miserable
conditions. The proletariat is badly clothed, badly fed, miserably
housed, exhausted by excessive and often deleterious labor, uncertain
as to income, and ignorant and coarse. [273]

However, the sketch given above shows only one side of the question. At
length the workers have perceived that the interests of the employer
are opposed to their own, that the cause of their poverty lies in his
luxury. They have begun to set up opposition when they learn that by
organizing themselves into labor unions they gain a power by which they
can ameliorate their lot. The work no longer being done separately as
in the time of the guilds, but together, there has been this
consequence for the workmen, that being now in the same position with
regard to the capitalist, and in the same social condition, they have
gained in the feeling of solidarity and in discipline, two conditions
which are essential to victory in the struggle. Little by little the
workers have learned that their enemy is not their own employer simply,
but the whole capitalist class. The strife has become a strife of
classes. And capitalism being international the conflict of the working
class has become international also.

The means by which the working class attempt to better their position
are of various kinds. First there are the unions, which undertake the
contest for the shorter day and higher wages. Then there is
coöperation; and finally, and above all, politics. The movement for
unions, which could not exist without liberty of the press, of meeting,
and of forming associations, forces the working-men to take part in
politics.

At first, when they still had no clear idea of the position they
occupied in society, the working-men permitted other political parties
to make use of them. But coming to understand that the laborers form a
class apart, whose interests are different from those of other classes,
they have formed an independent working-man’s party. Finally, the
contest of the working class could not limit itself to improvements
brought about within the frame-work of the existing economic system; if
they wished to free themselves permanently they saw themselves obliged
to combat capitalism itself. Thus modern socialism was born; on one
side from an ardent desire of the working class to free itself from the
poverty caused by capitalism; on the other side from the development in
the manner of capitalistic production, in which small capital is always
conquered by large capital. The conviction becomes more and more
general that capitalism has fulfilled its historic task, the increase
of the productive forces, and that the means of production must belong
to all if we are effectively to deliver humanity from the material and
intellectual miseries which result from capitalism. The labor movement
blends itself with socialism, then, and thus social democracy becomes
the political organization of the working class.

What have been the results of the opposition made by the working class
to the misery imposed upon them by capitalism? When we compare the
condition of the proletariat in the first half of the nineteenth
century (see, for example F. Engels, op. cit.) with that of today, we
cannot help recognizing that it has been improved. Forced (in order to
avoid worse things) by the labor agitation and also by the ravages
which capitalism had caused in the working class, incapacitating them
for the work required of them, the bourgeoisie decided to put forth
laws limiting the work of women and children, etc. The unions,
consisting principally of skilled workers, have been and still are able
to obtain increase of wages and a shortening of the working-day, by
making use of the weapons at their disposal (strikes, etc.).
Coöperation also has raised the standard of living somewhat for those
who have taken part in it.

From the fact that the working class, in so far as it has been
organized, has improved its condition, the conclusion has wrongly been
drawn that the distance between the two parties, the possessors and the
non-possessors, has been diminished. Those who draw this conclusion
forget that during this period the totality of wealth has been
enormously increased, and that the proletariat has obtained only a
part, while the rest has fallen to the bourgeoisie. And so far as I
know, no one has yet been able to prove that the part falling to the
bourgeoisie must be smaller than that obtained by the proletarians.
[274]

Besides the material consequences of the labor conflict, its spiritual
consequences are also of very high importance. The contest has obliged
the working-men to develop themselves, has taught them that they occupy
an important place in society, and thus has increased their confidence
in themselves. It is socialism especially which, by giving the hope of
a better future to a whole class oppressed and poor, has had the effect
of little by little elevating the proletariat intellectually and
morally.




D. THE LOWER PROLETARIAT. [275]

I must speak now of the fourth and least numerous group of the
population, that of the very poor. Not possessing the means of
production, and not being able to sell their labor, these people occupy
no position in the economic life properly speaking, and their material
condition is therefore easy to understand. Everything that has been
said upon this subject with reference to the proletariat applies here,
but in a much larger degree. The manner in which these people are fed,
clothed, and housed is almost indescribable. The middle class have no
idea of such a life; they believe that the pictures of these conditions
sometimes painted for them are exaggerated, and that charity is
sufficient to prevent their passing certain limits. From these limits
we understand that the bourgeoisie does not mean to be incommoded by
the poor. If charity were to go farther it would require sums so great
that the increase of capital and expenditures for luxury would be
interfered with. That would be quite out of the question.

In order to depict these conditions I wish to give but one quotation,
taken from an interesting article, “Englands industrielle Reservearmee”
in which account has been given of the researches of certain clergymen
in the poorest quarters of London. And everything that is here said of
London applies in general to other great cities. For capitalism
produces the same effects everywhere.

“Think of the condition in which the poor live. We do not say the
condition of their dwellings, for how can those holes be called
dwellings, when in comparison with them the lair of a wild beast would
be a comfortable and healthful place. Only a few who read these lines
have any conception of what pestilential places these nests are, where
tens of thousands of human beings are herded together among horrors
that recall to us what we have heard of slave-ships between decks. To
reach these abodes of misery we have to find our way through hardly
passable courts, impregnated with poisonous and evil-smelling gases,
which rise from the heaps of offal strewn around, and from the dirty
water flowing underfoot—courts, into which the sun seldom or never
penetrates, through which no breath of fresh air ever blows, and which
seldom have the benefit of a cleaning. We have rotten stairs to climb,
which threaten to give way at each step, and in some places have given
way, leaving holes that endanger the lives and limbs of those who are
not accustomed to them. We are obliged to feel our way along dark and
dirty passages swarming with vermin; then, if we are not driven back by
the intolerable stench, we may enter the holes in which thousands of
beings, of the same race as ourselves, lodge together. Have you, dear
reader, ever pitied those poor creatures whom you found sleeping in the
open under railway arches, in wagons or hogsheads, or under anything
that would afford them shelter? You will learn that these are to be
envied in comparison with those who seek refuge here. Eight feet square
is the average size of very many of these ‘living-rooms.’ Walls and
ceiling are black with the accumulation of dirt which has become
fastened there through the neglect of years. It falls down from the
cracks in the ceiling, sticks out of the holes in the walls, in short,
is everywhere. What goes by the name of a window is half stuffed up
with rags or nailed up with boards, in order to keep out the wind and
rain, while the rest is so smeared and darkened that no light can get
in, nor is it possible to see out. If we climb up to an attic room,
where at least we may expect a breath of fresh air through an open or
broken window, and look down upon the roofs or cornices of the stories
below, we shall discover that the already tainted air which might find
its entrance into the window, has come thither over the decayed bodies
of cats, birds, or still more nauseous things. The buildings themselves
are in such miserable condition that the thought naturally arises,
‘Will they fall down upon the heads of the inmates?’ And furniture? We
shall perhaps discover a broken down chair, the rickety remains of an
old bedstead, or the mere fragments of a table; more often, however, as
a substitute for these we shall find only rough boards resting upon
bricks, an old warped trunk, or a box; and more often still nothing but
rags and rubbish.

“Every room in these rotten, damp, fetid houses is occupied by one, and
often by two families. A sanitary inspector reports that he found in a
cellar a man, his wife, three children, and four hogs. In another room
a missionary found a man sick with small-pox, his wife just recovering
from child-birth, and the children half naked and covered with dirt.
Here seven persons live in a cellar-kitchen, and a dead child lies
between the living. In another room a poor widow was living with three
children, and one child who had already been dead thirteen days. Her
husband, a cab-driver, had committed suicide a short time before.—Here
lives a widow and her six children, including a daughter of 29, another
of 21, and a son of 27. Another room contains father, mother, and six
children, of whom two are sick with scarlet fever. In another live,
eat, and sleep nine brothers and sisters from 29 years old down. Here
is a mother who sends her children out on the street from early evening
till late after midnight, because she rents her room during this time
for immoral purposes. Afterwards the poor worms may creep back to their
dwelling if they have not found some scanty shelter elsewhere. Where
there is a bed it consists of nothing but a heap of dirty rags, refuse,
or straw, but mostly there is not even this, and the miserable beings
lie upon the dirty floor. The renter of this room is a widow, who takes
the only bed herself and sublets the floor to a married couple for two
shillings sixpence a week.” [276]

“However miserable these rooms may be they are yet too dear for many,
who wander about all day seeking to get a living as well as they can,
and at night take shelter in one of the common lodging-houses, of which
there are so many. The lodging-houses are often the meeting place of
thieves and vagabonds of the lowest sort, and some are even kept by the
receivers of stolen goods. In the kitchen men and women may be seen
cooking their food, doing their washing, or lounging around smoking and
gambling. In the sleeping room there is a long row of beds on each
side, as many as sixty or eighty in a single room. In many
lodging-houses the two sexes are permitted to lodge together without
any regard for the commonest decency. Yet there is still a lower step.
Hundreds cannot procure even the twopence necessary to secure the
privilege of passing a night in the stuffy air of these dormitories;
and so they lie down on the steps and in the passage ways, where it is
nothing uncommon in the early morning to find six or eight human beings
huddled together or stretched out.” [277]

We may limit ourselves to this sketch of the habitation—all the other
living conditions conform thereto. With so miserable a material life
there can be no question of the intellectual life. Continual poverty
and the permanent fear of dying of hunger destroy all that is noble in
man and reduce him to the condition of a beast, without any aspiration
for higher things; for those who have come to this state from the more
favored classes become more and more degraded and have soon lost the
little knowledge they acquired in earlier periods. Servility and lack
of self-respect are necessary to the poor if they are to get the alms
they need to keep them alive, since they occupy no place in the
economic life. Between them and the workers there is an enormous
difference; they have no feeling of solidarity in the social life.

What is the origin of the lower proletariat, from what classes is it
recruited? If we are to believe many criminologists and sociologists
the answer to this question ought to be that their poverty is not due
to social conditions but exclusively to themselves; that they are
inferior by nature. But to get a true answer we must put the question
in this way: do the existing social classes form the groups into which
men would be classified according to their qualities?

Those who give an affirmative answer to this question reason as
follows: men differ enormously among themselves in their innate
capacities. The largest division of them is made up of people of
moderate worth, a small number rise above this, and the rest are
inferior. Circumstances have little influence upon the development of
these capacities. If any man has great abilities circumstances cannot
keep him from the place to which they entitle him. He who has little
ability also arrives at the place which that fact makes his own. In
other words (to confine myself to capitalism) the bourgeoisie, the
ruling class, is composed of persons predestined to rule; next comes
the petty bourgeoisie, followed by the proletariat, predestined to
rough work; and finally lower proletariat, a class predestined to
succumb in the struggle for existence, since incapable of meeting its
requirements. [278]

An attentive examination of this theory, which is an application to
society of the Darwinian theory of selection, shows at once—even
supposing it to be correct—that there is an important difference
between the struggle for existence in nature and that in society. In
nature the conquered are either annihilated, or are prevented from
reproducing themselves, while in society the lower classes multiply
much faster than the higher. It is no longer a question of the survival
of the most fit, and the annihilation of the rest, as in nature.

Who is it then who remains victor in the struggle for life in society?
To answer this it is necessary first to answer another, Are the chances
the same for all? If this is not the case then it cannot be a question
of the triumph of the best.

There are few questions upon which opinions differ as much as upon
this. Generally these opinions are only conjectures, for they are not
based upon an examination of facts. For this reason I wish to set down
here briefly the very important conclusions of Professor Odin in his
“Genèse des grands hommes”, a work noteworthy not simply from the
wealth of documents of which the author made use, but also from his
very scrupulous care in examining them. Professor Odin has made studies
of the educational environment, the economic environment, the
ethnological environment, etc., of all the men of letters born in
France between 1300 and 1830, to the number of 6382.

As to educational environment, the author has been able to procure
exact information with regard to 827 persons; a good education had been
given to 811, or 98.1 % and 16, or 1.9 % had had a poor education. “All
this forces us to admit that education plays a rôle not only important,
but capital, decisive, in the development of the man of letters.” [279]

The economic environment in which the men of letters had passed their
youth could be discovered in the case of 619. Of these, 562, or 90.7 %,
passed their youth sheltered from all material care, while 57, or 9.3
%, passed their youth in indigence or insecurity. In consequence the
author makes the following observation: “As it appears, only the
eleventh part of the literary men of talent have passed their youth in
difficult economic conditions. This ratio, already very small in
itself, appears much more striking when we strive to represent the
numerical relation which ought to exist for the whole population
between well-do-do families and those that are not. It is impossible to
say, doubtless, what this relation has been on the average for the
whole modern period. But it is clear that we shall be well below the
truth if we admit that the families of the second category are three or
four times as numerous as those of the first. That is to say, from the
mere fact of the economic conditions in which they are born, the
children of well-to-do families have at least forty or fifty times as
much chance of making a name in letters as do those who belong to
families that are poor, or are simply in a position of economic
instability.” [280]

Further, the author shows that the fifty-seven men of letters who
passed their youth in an unfavorable economic environment were by
chance put in a position to develop their capacities. (Only five of
them received a poor education.)

Finally the social environment from which the literary men have sprung:


    ======================+======================================
                          |   Number of Literary Men of Talent
      Social Classes.     |  Relatively to the Total Population
                          |        of Each Social Class.
    ----------------------+--------------------------------------
    Nobility.             |             159
    Magistracy.           |              62
    Liberal professions.  |              24
    Bourgeoisie.          |               7
    Manual labor.         |               0.8
    ======================+======================================


Upon examining these figures we see that of two persons of the same
innate qualities the one who has sprung from the nobility has about 200
times as much chance of becoming a person of importance as the one who
comes from the laboring class. The struggle of our day has been
characterized as a race with a handicap, in which one runs on foot with
a burden on his back, another rides a horse, while the third takes an
express train. The reality, however, is still stronger.

Doubtless we must not forget that the researches of Professor Odin
include in part a period that differs in many respects from our own
(hence the small contingent of the bourgeoisie), and that since this
time education has become more solid and more general, a fact which
increases the chances of success of a gifted man sprung from a poor
environment. In the second place it was literary men and not
capitalists who were the subject of investigation, and since the former
doubtless must have greater natural aptitudes than the latter, it may
well be that it is easier for anyone without money to acquire capital,
than would be suggested by the figures applying only to men of letters.
Nevertheless, all this does not overthrow the fact that the researches
of Professor Odin have proved that the fact of being born in a class
where youth is without care, and enjoys a good education, procures an
enormous advantage in the struggle for existence. [281]

In order to prevent erroneous interpretations I will add Professor
Odin’s own conclusion, from which it is plain that he does not deny
absolutely that men’s innate capacities differ widely (which, indeed,
is disputed by few, and may be considered settled). “Heredity and
environment,” he says, concur with one another in the development of
talent. We may characterize as follows their respective spheres of
action: where the hereditary qualities are identical—to suppose an
impossible case—it is the environment which causes all the difference
between individuals; where the environment is identical, it is
heredity.

“Put in these terms the proposition is banal. What is less so, since
this has been established here with certainty for perhaps the first
time, is that heredity alone can do nothing. However strong may be the
natural disposition given by heredity, it can only develop itself in a
favorable environment. Thrown into an unfavorable environment it will
become weakened in the degree in which the environment is contrary to
it, and may even end by being atrophied to the point of being no longer
perceptible. The supposed omnipotence of heredity is only an illusion,
resulting from an elementary confusion between heredity and simple
parentage.

“This is not all. We have been able to determine more nearly what is
the indispensable environment for the development of literary talent.
It is a good education, made possible by certain circumstances which
are advantageous socially and economically, in other words, a proper
social environment.” [282]

As a second form of the handicap we must speak of inheritance. It is
impossible to estimate this advantage in figures, but it is
incontestable that the man who has become rich in this way has no need
of great knowledge or great intelligence in order to remain rich.
Provided he does not speculate or squander his money, he should be able
to have the enjoyment of it all his life. The struggle for existence is
unknown to him; at the very start of the race his foot is nearly at the
goal.

We see already that these two circumstances have as their result that
the classes do not correspond exactly to the groups into which men are
separated according to their capacities. However we must now leave the
cases in which one has a start of another, and give an answer to the
question, “In what do the conquerors in the contest excel?”

In the first place, attention must be drawn to a group of capitalists
who have acquired their wealth without having their abilities called
into play, but who are entirely indebted to chance, i.e. the
speculators, the winners of the great prizes in lotteries, the men who
make rich marriages, etc. Next we may mention the other capitalists,
the great manufacturers and merchants. Wherein are they distinguished?
First for energy and activity, next for a great talent for
organization, especially as shown in the choice of their chief
employes, and finally for a need of luxury, not too great, lest the
building up of their capital be interfered with, nor too restrained,
lest the suspicion be aroused that their fortune is in danger. The
first of these aptitudes must certainly be considered as the most
favorable; the talent for organization especially is of the highest
importance, for it is without contradiction a factor in social
progress. It is because of this talent and not for their fabulous
wealth alone that the names of Pierpont Morgan, of Rockefeller, and of
other directors of trusts will not be entirely forgotten after they are
dead. But these are not the only capacities which these people must
display. To direct a capitalistic enterprise it is necessary among
other things to have a fair portion of insensibility as well toward
workmen as toward customers; then it will not do to be too scrupulous
about truth (in advertising, etc.), nor to show too much character
(however impertinent his customers may be the capitalist takes it all
through fear of seeing them go over to his competitors).

Nevertheless, he who displays all these qualities, still is not
entirely sure of being able to improve his position, or even to
maintain himself in it; crises, as has been shown, are inevitably bound
up with capitalism itself, and strike at times the most substantial and
energetic capitalists. By a new invention or a new manner of working
the most active and intelligent manufacturer may see himself
out-stripped by a competitor. And aside from all fortuitous
circumstances, in society as it exists today the struggle for existence
is a struggle between those best armed, those who have the best
machines, etc. But the manufacturer who can procure the best machines,
who can bring his establishment up to the latest technical
requirements, who can procure the services of the ablest technicians,
etc., is the man who has most capital. The struggle is not a struggle
of men but of capital.

In his work, “Die Darwinsche Theorie und der Sozialismus” Dr. L.
Woltmann has brought out clearly the difference between the combat in
nature and that which takes place in society. He says: “The history of
the civilization of the human race also proceeds upon the basis of the
great biological principles of adaptation, transmission, and perfection
in the struggle for existence. But between the application of these
principles among the lower animals and in the world of man there are
the following essential differences. In the first place in the animal
world the struggle for existence takes place through the adaptation of
organic means to organic ends, while with men technical tools and
economical means of production enter in, things which are not within
the power of separate individuals, but are made possible by
association. In the second place hereditary transmission in the case of
animals is organic, while in the case of human beings there is added an
external and legally determined hereditary transmission of technical
tools and of capital. In the animal kingdom, in the third place, the
struggle for existence is a rivalry of organic production and
reproduction, while among men, especially under the capitalistic order,
there takes place a competition in commodities and places, a contest
for profit, which has hardly anything in common with natural
selection.” [283]

Thus we see clearly who it is that can rise from the class of
non-possessors to that of possessors: it is those to whom fortune is
peculiarly favorable, or who, possessing the qualities necessary for
the capitalist, meet with the opportunity of putting them in evidence.
Those who are dropped from the capitalist class are those who have been
unfortunate or who do not possess the qualities necessary for
capitalists.

The answer to the question proposed, “Are the present classes also the
groups where men can be ranked according to their qualities”, must be
decidedly negative. The bourgeoisie is not the ruling class because the
most intelligent and energetic persons are found among its members.
There are also included in this class persons without energy, stupid
people, of minor importance in short, just as in the petty bourgeoisie
and the proletariat very capable persons may be met with. The fact of
being excluded from the class of possessors is not a proof of
inferiority. If the superior persons were those who led society they
would be the great thinkers, the savants, for it is they who have made
society progress and who have desired its well-being. For even if
capitalists, more than others, have aided progress, it is by chance,
for they have always had in view only their own profit. [284]

I could easily cite a number of celebrated authors who are unanimously
of the opinion that the conquerors in the present struggle are not such
because they are naturally superior. [285] I will confine myself to
recalling the opinion of one whose authority no one will contest,
namely, Charles Darwin. Here is what Wallace says: “In one of my last
conversations with Darwin he expressed himself as having very little
hope of the future of humanity, and this upon the basis of his
observation that in our modern civilization natural selection does not
occur, and the fittest does not survive. The victors in the struggle
for gold are by no means the best or the most intelligent, and it is a
well known fact that our population reproduces itself in each
generation much more rapidly among the lower than among the middle and
upper classes.” [286]

An examination of the struggle for existence in the middle class shows
that everything which happens in the bourgeoisie on a large scale is
reproduced here on a small scale. He who has little capital is
surpassed by a competitor who has more, even though the former may be
entirely fitted for his business; crises have the same ruinous
influence here, and strike skilful and unskilful alike. The difference,
as far as the struggle for existence is concerned, between the class in
question and the bourgeoisie, consists in this: the less energetic, the
less intelligent of the middle class runs more danger of falling back
out of the ranks than a member of the bourgeoisie who is his equal.

Finally, we come to the proletariat. Here also there is an elimination
of individuals not because they are incapable, but because they are
superfluous in the present mode of production, as well as of those whom
sickness or old age render unfit for labor. Here we must take account
of a factor which is of less importance in the other classes, bodily
health and strength. While the proletarian has need neither of much
knowledge or great intelligence to carry on his trade, he has a
powerful weapon for the struggle in his muscular strength and health.
Unfavorable conditions have a strong influence upon him, and the one
who is weak and ailing must, other things being equal, yield in the
present struggle for existence to a competitor who is stronger and in
better health. And finally, in this contest also the less active, the
less persevering among the workers will have the smaller chance of
success, supposing conditions to be equal.



So we return to the point from which we set out, the lower proletariat.
This class is not composed, then, as has sometimes been claimed, of
beings inferior by nature, of persons who are fit for nothing. In the
great majority of cases social conditions and not their lack of
aptitude, are the exclusive and direct causes of their position. In
support of this I will give some figures, which also show the relative
importance of the causes compared among themselves.


German Empire.

====================================================================+============
Injuries to the person assisted                       }             |   1.04
  ,,     ,,  ,, breadwinner of the family             } By          |   0.09
Death of     ,,      ,,     ,,  ,,   ,,               } Accident.   |   0.36
  ,,     ,,  ,,      ,,     ,,  ,,   ,,                 } Not by    |   8.35
Sickness of the person assisted or of one of his family } Accident. |  15.24
Bodily or intellectual infirmities                                  |   8.97
Weakness of old age                                                 |  12.32
Large number of children                                            |   1.34
Forced unemployment                                                 |   2.23
Alcoholism                                                          |   0.88
Laziness                                                            |   0.71
Other causes designated                                             |   4.09
 ,,     ,,   not designated                                         |   0.06
“Co-assisted”[287]                                                  |  44.32
                                                                    +------------
                                                                    | 100.00[288]
====================================================================+============


This table shows that 44.32% of the persons assisted were
“co-assisted”; that 8.8% have become indigent through the death or
injury of the breadwinner of the family; that there are, therefore,
53.12% of those assisted the cause of whose indigence is not to be
found in the persons themselves, but in their social environment.
(Generally such persons are spoken of as not being poor through their
“own fault”, a term so vague that it would be well to discontinue its
use.) 1.34% are persons with a large family, whose wages are too small
to support so many; 2.23% are out of employment, i.e. they wish to work
but can find nothing to do; 12.32% are prevented from working by old
age. Consequently we reach the figure of 69.01% for those who have
become indigent through causes which do not depend upon themselves.
Finally come 25.25% of those assisted who have been injured, or are
sick, or have bodily or intellectual infirmities.

Further, there are social causes which play a great part in the
etiology of the cases we have been discussing (bad housing conditions
favoring tuberculosis, lack of protective devices for dangerous
machines, causing injuries, etc.). Others of these persons are born
weak or sickly, in which case we may speak of individual causes of
poverty, although social conditions have contributed in their turn by
their influence on the parents to make the children wretched.

It is, however, a social phenomenon that the sick and weak of the
proletariat are left to shift for themselves. They find themselves in
that condition only because they do not possess the means of
production, and are no longer in a condition to sell their labor. Many
times we read in treatises upon morals how shameful it is that nomadic
peoples abandon or kill their sick and aged, and how by these customs
they give proof of their inferior morality. But those who speak in this
way forget how, notwithstanding our present civilization, a great
number of persons still pass their old age in the direst poverty; they
forget also that the manner in which the nomadic peoples live forces
them to rid themselves of their sick and aged, because it would be
impossible to take them with them; they forget also that, on account of
the limited power that nomads have over nature, they find themselves in
exceedingly difficult material circumstances, so that their manner of
acting is not judged immoral by any of their own families who suffer by
it; [289] finally they forget that the productivity of labor is so
enormous at present that all the sick and aged could be supported; a
part of the money spent in superfluous luxuries would be ample for this
purpose.

We have still to examine the last two headings, laziness and
alcoholism. As the figures given above show, these form a very small
part of the causes: together only 1.59%. [290] Among the causes which
have brought these persons to the point where they are, there are
social factors also. Later on I shall speak of the relation between the
present economic system and alcoholism. But at this point we may say as
regards the 0.71% of persons who do not wish to work that a part of
them—it is impossible to say just how many—have grown up in a bad
environment, where they have never been given the habit of working
regularly and diligently, so that they have become totally incapable of
doing so.

There is still another social factor that may be named; the
disagreeable character of many kinds of work, made worse by long hours
and low wages. To adduce but one example: the miner is obliged to work
in a vitiated atmosphere, often in a painful position, and constantly
surrounded by dangers, and this for very low wages. If we stop to think
of this we are more astonished at the millions of workers who pass
their lives under similar conditions, than at the comparatively few who
refuse to work.

However, taking all this into account, it is certain that there are
among the proletariat persons who are predisposed to idleness by their
congenital constitution. It is indubitable that these persons are
invalids, who would be cared for in a well-organized society, but in
ours are abandoned to their fate. Professor Benedikt says, in speaking
of physical neurasthenia: “It represents not so much absolute weakness
as speedy exhaustion coupled with a painful feeling of weakness. We
make in our childhood more muscular movements than is necessary, and
out of the pleasurable feeling which comes from these develop the first
elements of pleasure in work. If, however, the child quickly becomes
weary, and the muscular action soon begets a lively feeling of
discomfort, there arises from this discomfort laziness or physical
neurasthenia.” [291]

The number of those the cause of whose poverty is to be found in
themselves is not, then, very considerable. Nevertheless it is a little
greater than the statistics given would lead one to suppose, for there
are also certain of the bourgeoisie and petty bourgeoisie, ruined in
consequence of the lack of the qualities required for success, who have
gone down little by little and have finally become incorporated with
the lower proletariat.

But is this class of poor persons absolutely fit for nothing? It seems
to me that (leaving the sick out of consideration) the answer must be
decidedly in the negative. It is true that a part of this group
succumbs in the struggle because it is inferior. But it would be as
absurd to say of the runner who comes in last in a race that he cannot
run at all, as to say of the man who goes under in the struggle for
existence that he is fit for nothing. Those who do not succeed in life
are in great part those who through accident of birth have not obtained
the place for which their talents fitted them. How many among the
bourgeoisie are ruined from their incapacity for directing a business
enterprise, while they would have become useful members of society if
they had been able to follow their true vocation? And how many
proletarians have fallen lower and lower through not being fitted for
the trade to which their birth destined them, while their innate
qualities predestined them to a different form of work? [292]

Side by side with these there are individuals who are really inferior,
who have little energy, intelligence, etc. It would be absurd to claim
that these persons are capable of doing great things, even in the most
favorable circumstances. But there is a great difference between not
being able to do great things, and being absolutely useless, as are the
members of the lower proletariat under present conditions. These
persons have need of being guided, cannot stand up without support, and
in order not to perish need to find themselves in a favorable
environment. If their neighbor comes to their assistance they can
assuredly become sufficiently useful, and in any case need do no harm.
Anyone who will look about him may be convinced of the truth of this;
for many persons of just this sort, happening to belong to the
bourgeoisie, have succeeded very well.



Ethnology points out also that classes have not their origin in the
universal fact that men differ in their innate qualities. For if this
were true classes would be as old as humanity itself. This, however, is
not the case; it has been proved that in the evolution of society there
has been a stage (that it was a long time ago makes little difference)
when riches and poverty were unknown, and classes did not exist. [293]
The assertion that the “war of all against all” is a natural
phenomenon, is absolutely false, and proves a very great lack of
sociological knowledge. It is certain that classes have long existed,
but a society like that of our time, in which we can apply the adage of
Hobbes, that “man is a wolf to his fellowman”, is of comparatively
recent date.



Our conclusion, then, is this: the groups into which the population of
capitalistic countries is divided do not originate in the circumstance
that men differ in their innate capacities, but in the system of
production that is in force; it is chiefly chance that determines to
which class an individual belongs; there are inferior beings in each
group, but among the lower proletariat they are more numerous than
elsewhere; but these inferior beings may still be useful enough on
condition that they be placed in a favorable environment.








CHAPTER III.

THE RELATION OF THE SEXES AND OF THE FAMILY.


A. MARRIAGE.

As between the two commonplaces, “There have always been poor people”,
and “The present institution of marriage springs from human nature
itself and is as old as society”, it is hard to say which is repeated
oftenest, but it is quite certain that one is no more exact than the
other. Sociology has proved that marriage, as it exists at present, is
the result of a long process of evolution, and every serious observer
must be convinced that its present form will be no more constant than
those which preceded it, and that the ideas concerning it have
undergone important modifications.

The question to solve is this: “How has monogamy taken its rise?” With
the aid of sociology I shall endeavor to give the answer as summarily
as possible. [294] It will, however, be necessary to recall the ancient
forms of marriage, without which it would be impossible to grasp the
origin and evolution of the present form. Most sociologists are of the
opinion that primitive man lived in promiscuity, which, if true, must
have been in the most remote period, when man was hardly
distinguishable from the anthropoid apes. Other authors, on the
contrary, have attempted to show that such a state of things has never
existed. [295] However, the only thing proved is that no case of
promiscuity has ever been established among peoples observed by serious
ethnologists. But all these peoples, however far removed they may be
from us, had already attained a certain degree of development, and were
by no means in their primitive state. No amount of observation can
prove whether or not primitive man really lived in a state of
promiscuity, and we can only take refuge in hypotheses.

We shall be getting at the truth when we come to an agreement as to the
meaning of the word “promiscuity.” Do we mean by this a state like that
in which dogs live, where after copulation the male and female do not
remain together at all? Then it is very likely that human beings have
never lived in that state, inasmuch as such promiscuity exists rarely
or not at all among the animals most approaching man. [296] If, on the
contrary, we mean by promiscuity a state in which rules concerning the
sexual life are lacking, but where life in common for a longer or
shorter period is not excluded, then, since man is part of the animal
kingdom, it is most probable that there has been a time when this state
has existed, and that it is only little by little that objective rules
have appeared. [297] Let us now leave the domain of hypothesis and
examine the real facts. [298]

The most primitive of the peoples who have been observed in detail have
been named “lower hunters”; they include the Australian aborigines, the
Veddhas, the Botocudos, etc. Among these peoples the men hunt while the
women gather fruit and roots. They are forced to wander in small groups
in order to provide for their needs, as otherwise the game and fruit
would soon fail. Their limited control over nature is a frequent cause
of famine and distress generally, and thus prevents any considerable
increase in the population.

As to their sexual relations, there could not be any question of
promiscuity among these peoples. Each horde is divided into three
age-classes, and the union of a member of one of these classes with a
member of another is forbidden. The cause of this prohibition is not
certain. Grosse [299] (as well as other authors [300]) is of the
opinion that it lies in the fact that these peoples discovered the
unfavorable effects of consanguineous unions upon the children, and
that this discovery led to the prohibition. [301] Other authors believe
that the hordes which practiced this exclusion, without suspecting its
importance, ran less danger of extinction than those which did not
practice it. [302]

The hordes being composed of but few persons, this exclusion would
force the men more and more to seek wives from outside the horde, thus
little by little becoming a group of consanguineous persons with whom
union is forbidden. If a man has procured a woman by capture he becomes
her absolute owner, can maltreat her, abandon her, do what he likes in
short. The power of the man over his wife is less great if he has
acquired her by purchase or exchange, since her family then exercises a
certain control.

The relation of the sexes is sufficiently explained by the mode of
production. When these savages are on the march the woman carries the
little that they possess, erects the tent, and searches for fruit; the
man on the other hand by his natural qualities is fitted for hunting
and for the defense of the hunting ground. Hunting being the principal
resource, and in this period bodily strength being of the highest
importance, it is natural that the man should rule.

The so-called “higher hunters”, among whom we must reckon the North
American Indians of the northwest coast and some peoples of northern
Asia, have reached a higher stage of social evolution. The difference
between these and the preceding class is only quantitative, and results
from the circumstance that they have been able to settle themselves in
countries that are rich in game and fish. This permits them to be more
sedentary, to live in larger groups, and to attain a higher
development.

As with the lower hunters there is among them a division of labor
between men and women: The man hunts, fishes, and constructs the tools
that he has need of; the woman gathers roots and herbs, prepares the
food, and gives herself up to the duties of the household. Some of
these peoples are capable of producing more than they need, a fact
which occasions commerce of some importance, and produces at times a
great inequality of fortune.

At this stage of development the woman is of great use, which brings it
about that the father does not give his daughter but sells her. Since
the man, then, has bought his wife she has become his property, and he
can do with her as he wishes; her infidelity is punished with death. If
the husband has received gifts of value from his father-in-law, he is a
little limited in his power, since, if he wishes to repudiate his wife,
he is obliged to return the gifts. However repudiation is rare, since
the woman is very useful to the man and he has ordinarily paid very
dear for her. This is also why polygyny, though permitted almost
everywhere, is rare. Only the very rich can permit themselves the
luxury of more than one wife.

The position of the wife is rather better when, instead of following
her husband, he comes to live at her father’s house. This happens
sometimes when the man cannot pay the whole purchase price, sometimes
when the father-in-law is much richer than he. In this latter case the
son-in-law prefers to profit by the wealth and power of his wife’s
father, who, for his part, asks nothing better than to keep his
daughter at home, since, in this manner, instead of losing a worker
from the household he gains one by the coming of the husband.

We come now to the “pastoral peoples”, living principally in Asia and
Africa. Just as hunting is not the sole resource of the preceding
groups, so the raising of cattle is not the exclusive occupation of
this group, but simply the principal one; hence their name. The raising
of cattle is naturally the work of the men, seeing that it proceeds
genetically from hunting, while the women in this class, as in the
preceding, gather fruits and herbs and attend to the work of the
household. Although the land is held in common, there are great
diversities of wealth, since cattle, the principal form of possession,
are individual property, and since war and pillage are also frequent
sources of wealth.

Polygyny is permitted, and nomads take as many wives as they can pay
for and support. Only the rich, however, can afford to purchase more
than one wife, for the fathers demand a good price. Once purchased the
woman becomes the absolute property of the man, who can exploit her in
any manner, or abandon her, and when he comes to die can leave her to
his heirs with the rest of his possessions. Adultery on the part of the
woman is severely punished, while the man is free. Often under polygyny
only one of the women is considered the legitimate wife and her
children have the sole right to inherit, while the other women are
considered only as concubines. The position of the legitimate wife
towards her husband does not prevent her being as much of a slave as
the other women. Nowhere else has the woman as humble a place as among
these pastoral peoples, and nowhere else is the rôle of the man as
important as here.

Let us next examine the “lower agriculturists” (among whom are to be
found the greater number of the North American Indians, and a great
number of the peoples of Africa and the East Indies). When hunting
peoples, through chance circumstances (wealth of game for example),
have ceased to wander continually, they may easily pass into
agriculturists. [303] Agriculture in its turn brings it about that
those who practice it become more and more sedentary.

The cultivation of the soil developed in connection with the gathering
of fruit and roots, so that it originally formed part of woman’s sphere
of labor; hence the economic importance of women increased, and a
father became less and less disposed to give his daughter in marriage
for a small equivalent. The future husband is obliged to acquire his
wife at a considerable price, perhaps may have to win her by serving
his father-in-law temporarily. Thus, although polygyny is permitted it
is only the rich and the chiefs who can procure more than one wife.

Since agriculture requires many hands, the parents try to keep their
children with them as long as possible. [304] Thus the custom grows up
of several families living in the same house, and the husband comes to
live with his wife’s family when he is unable to pay the purchase
price. Even if this is not the case, a close relationship exists
between the wife and her family, so that she returns to it with her
children when her husband dies. The more important the position of the
woman in the family becomes, the more it comes to pass that the married
woman remains in her own family and the husband in his, and that the
union consists only in more or less frequent visits paid by the man to
his wife.

It is easy to see why the position of woman at this stage is in general
better than at those which preceded. Ordinarily it is the woman who
tills the soil and cares for the household, while the man hunts and
prepares the necessary tools; and since agriculture gives a more
regular and surer production than hunting, it follows that the position
of woman is improved. The woman becomes less dependent upon the man, to
such a point that, for example, she is able to break the marriage, a
condition very different from those in which the wife was the property
of her husband. (The somewhat numerous exceptions are explained by the
fact that in those cases the man takes part in the cultivation of the
soil.) This is especially the case when a domestic community is formed
in which the women govern (matriarchate). [305] Thus a situation is
developed at times in which the women have an important position even
outside of the family (gynecocracy).

As the preceding considerations show it is not the family which, at
this stage of development, takes the first place. During the periods
which I have examined before this the clan (in Latin “gens”, in German
“Sippe”), a group of persons descended from a common ancestor, is of
importance only inasmuch as members of the clan are forbidden to marry
among themselves. Among the lower agriculturists, however, the clan is
developed into a consanguineous group living in a community, and in
most cases the clan is maternal—that is, descent and the right of
succession are reckoned in the maternal line.

However as soon as agriculture increased greatly in importance,
especially when the raising of cattle, commerce, and industry grew up
beside it, the relation between the sexes became considerably modified.
The man gave up hunting, always a less important resource at this
stage, and applied himself more and more to agriculture and other
branches, and the woman only seconded him in these occupations. In
consequence of the continually increasing productivity of labor, the
man could produce more than he needed for consumption. The possession
of slaves then became advantageous, slavery took on greater and greater
proportions, and in this way the woman’s part in the economic life
became less important. Thus the man becomes anew the principal factor
and his authority resumes the force it had in the earlier periods. It
is no longer the man who lives with the woman and her family but she
lives with him. We have seen above that among the lower agriculturists
it is the clan, and especially the maternal clan, that holds the first
place. Through the economic development the maternal clan is made to
give place to the paternal clan. In the clan there was equality, since
the soil, the most important means of production, and the dwelling were
possessed in common; but the disappearance of this equality followed
the development of commerce and industry, for the products of these
were, from the first, private property. This inequality was increased
still more because private property in land began to grow up side by
side with property in common. In the second place, the booty in war was
not the same for all warriors, and furthermore war brought about the
existence of a class of persons (slaves) whose interests were opposed
to those of the conquerors. This development of private property leads
necessarily to a gradual change from the maternal clan to the paternal.
For in the first case a father had to leave his property to the members
of his clan (we have seen that it was the man who became the possessor
of private wealth); and since his children belonged always to another
clan than his own, the clan of their mother, the children did not
inherit from their father. Hence the change to the paternal clan. [306]

But this was not all. Through the great modifications in the mode of
production of which I have already spoken, the importance of the clan
diminished more and more, and at length disappeared entirely. As long
as there was equality among the members of the clan, as long as the
social relationships were little complicated, the clan and the
organizations that sprang from it (mere combinations of clans) sufficed
for the purposes of social organization. But such an organization,
being purely democratic in its nature, was no longer adapted to a
society in which there were rich and poor, freemen and slaves, in
which, therefore, there was a large group of persons oppressed and a
small group of oppressors.

The clan and the combinations of the different clans were replaced by
the state. This was an organization which had for its principal end the
maintenance of order as far as possible, in a society in which the
interests of different groups, like those of individuals, were opposed
to each other, and the regulation of this conflict of interests. [307]
This organization is consequently entirely different from the clan, the
object of which was to take the interests of the community to heart. It
is evident that in an organization like this it is the most important
and influential class which comes first.

On the one hand, then, the clan loses itself in the state; on the other
hand the family, which played but a secondary part while the clan
system was at its height, became of greater importance. The clan is
divided into “great families” (“Grossfamilien”), i.e. husband, wife,
and their unmarried children as well as their male descendants, with
their wives and children; and the father is the master of all these
persons and all their property. However it is only little by little,
and in proportion as we get away from the clan, that the authority of
the father becomes unlimited. This form of the family has continued
even down to our own day in China and Japan, and was general during the
early days of ancient Rome.

In China the woman, whose work is entirely limited to household
occupations, has a position which, according to all accounts, is only
that of a subordinate. Her whole life is under the direction of her
husband; she can never obtain a divorce, while her husband can dissolve
the marriage without cause; if he takes her in the act of adultery he
has the right to kill her, while he himself may keep concubines. In
Japan the position of woman is much the same, and in ancient Rome also,
though in the course of time the situation of the Roman woman was
improved.

As the method of production became more elaborate and the social life
was modified as a consequence, the “great family” disappeared, to be
replaced by the modern family, consisting of the husband and wife with
their unmarried children. Through the increasing extension of the
division of labor the sons could more easily provide for their own
needs and withdraw themselves in this way from the paternal authority,
and the increasing power of the state favored this tendency by limiting
the authority of the father.

The best sources for the study of the first phases of monogamous
marriage are furnished by ancient Greece. There absolute submission of
the woman to the man still prevailed. After the decease of the husband
the woman was under the guardianship of his son. The man could
repudiate his wife or give her to another. While he had full liberty to
have intercourse with other women, the woman who committed adultery was
severely punished. The occupations of the woman were confined to
spinning, weaving, and housekeeping; her life was concentrated within
the house, though even there her authority was very limited, while
outside it had no force whatever.

In comparing the position of woman during the period in question with
that in the earlier periods (excepting the lower agricultural period)
we see that in general her condition is but little ameliorated.
Monogamy existed in reality for one of the parties only, since the man
was free to keep concubines, while he took every means in his power to
prevent the infidelity of his wife, by isolating her from the outer
world. Hence it is not true, as some would have us believe, that
monogamy is the consequence of an instinct, nor that it is due to a
higher degree of culture, made possible by the increased productivity
of labor. [308] On the contrary, among the lower agriculturists, much
less civilized than the ancient Greeks, the position of women was
better than with the latter; being more free, the woman enjoyed in
general a higher degree of consideration.

The origin of monogamy is explained only by the modifications that the
mode of production has undergone. Through these the man has again taken
the most important place in the economic life, it is he who governs and
the woman has only to obey him. Thus it is that through the continual
increase of private property monogamy sprung up, that is to say the
union of a man and a woman with the object of producing legitimate
children who might inherit the property of the father. [309]

Since that time monogamy has persisted to our own day. However
important the modifications which the method of production has
undergone since the rise of monogamy, the fact remains that a certain
part of the work necessary to existence belongs still to the work of
housekeeping, which, as at other times, is performed by the women. The
more important labors, those which give the greater social power to him
who executes them, fall upon the man, and from this fact his
preponderance still persists.

Though the position of the married woman may be somewhat improved when
compared with that at the beginning of civilization, nevertheless a
study of existing civil codes (especially of the French civil code and
of those for which it has served as a model) shows that the married
woman is in general still in a state of great dependence. The woman
must obey her husband and follow him wherever he wishes; except where
otherwise stipulated in the marriage contract the husband has the
management of his wife’s fortune and the income from it belongs to him;
it is the man who exercises parental authority; the woman cannot appear
in a lawsuit without the assistance of her husband; etc.

The difference between the position of the married woman of today and
that of former times consists principally in that the consent of both
parties is necessary to conclude the marriage, that the husband can no
longer repudiate his wife, but can only dissolve the union for
important reasons (adultery, cruelty, etc.), and that the woman also,
for the same reasons, can obtain separation or divorce.

This raises the question as to why a marriage should not be dissolved
as soon as for any reason the union becomes intolerable to either
party. The answer must be as follows. From the dominant position of the
man in the economic life it is clear that the woman would not be able
to loose the bonds of marriage at her pleasure, except in the case
provided by law, inasmuch as the man could not permit so grave an
assault upon his authority. From this point of view monogamy and the
ancient forms of marriage are alike, for the woman has never been able
to secure a divorce at her own pleasure except among the lower
agriculturists, where, on account of her importance in the economic
life she enjoyed the same rights as the man. The present organization
of society prevents the man, for his part, from getting a divorce
except in certain cases provided by law, for if it were possible for
the husband to break the marriage at will, society today would not have
the necessary solidity and stability; marriage would be a very
hazardous enterprise for the woman, since, from the nature of her
occupation, she is generally not in a position to provide for her own
needs by herself; and the support and education of the children by
their parents would also be less assured. But even this is not all. As
we have seen, monogamy was created as soon as private property became
general. Reciprocally monogamy is one of the causes which support and
increase the spirit of property in men. It is in the narrow circle of
the family, away from the contact with society, that a keen desire to
possess is developed among children.

The deepest roots of marriage as it exists today are found in our
present state of society, based as it is on private property; and, in
its turn, marriage is a support for that society. Here is also the
reason for the disapprobation of free unions felt by the majority, even
if the motives of these unions are the most noble. And this also is why
the more conservative a man is as to the institution of private
property, the more he holds to the existing form of marriage, a fact
otherwise inexplicable.

An examination of the modifications made during the last century in the
matrimonial law and in matters pertaining to it, shows that the
position of the married woman has improved gradually. To cite only a
few examples, the French civil code gave to the married woman the right
of divorce in the case of adultery on the part of her husband only if
he kept a concubine in the common dwelling (art. 230). In 1884 this
article was modified so that the woman now has the same right of
divorce in case of adultery as the man. (Article 337 of the penal code,
however, punishes the adulterous wife by an imprisonment of from three
months to two years, while article 339 punishes the adulterous husband
only if he has been keeping a concubine in the common dwelling, and
then only by a fine of from one hundred to two thousand francs.) In
England before 1870 the married woman was in a position of dependence.
The right of possession of personal property as well as the
administration of real estate and the benefit of revenues from it
devolved upon the husband. Since 1870 and 1882 there has been a great
change in the matrimonial law, to the great advantage of the woman who
has become, among other things, the sole owner of her fortune, etc.
[310] In the countries where there have been no modifications in the
last century, public opinion is such that we may be sure that the
condition of women will be better in case of an eventual revision of
the matrimonial law.

In searching for the causes of the changes of opinion upon this
question we discover that here again they are due in the last analysis
to the economic life. This springs from the fact that the number of
women who work independently, who gain their own bread, increases
continually. The causes which bring this about are of diverse kinds but
can be reduced to the following. In the first place, the number of
marriages contracted is in general diminishing, and this decrease is
due to the continually diminishing number of marriages among the
moneyed classes, and to the fact that these marriages take place later
in life than formerly. [311] It is not difficult to see that a
retrograde movement in the marriages of the bourgeoisie must tell.
Marriage brings an increase of expenses indeed, but among the
proletariat it brings also an increase of revenue (the woman may earn
something by working away from home, or save by doing the work of the
house herself). Among the bourgeoisie, on the other hand, it brings
with it pecuniary disadvantages only, at least if we except those cases
in which the wife is more or less rich. The struggle for existence
becomes more and more difficult, and especially among the members of
the petty bourgeoisie and those who practice the liberal professions
marriage does not take place until later in life, and in general the
number of marriages diminishes. [312] To this it is still necessary to
add the fact that in Europe and in some of the states of North America
the number of women exceeds that of the men. [313]

The diminishing opportunity for women of the more or less well-to-do
classes to marry forces them to earn their own living. The change that
housekeeping has undergone and is still undergoing must also be taken
into consideration. The importance of housekeeping continually
decreases in consequence of the extension of manufacturing, which
absorbs the special tasks of the household one after another. While
formerly clothes were made at home, bread was baked there, etc., at
present there remains for the work of the household only the care of
the house and the preparation of the food. And even these occupations
may soon be taken out of the house. [314] Unmarried women of the
bourgeoisie used formerly often to be able to find a home with members
of their family, since they were able to be of service. At present they
are in general only superfluous persons in the household.

Even the married women of the bourgeoisie find themselves more and more
forced to contribute to the revenues of the family by working for
money, [315] and this for reasons already cited in speaking of
unmarried women: the increasing difficulty of the struggle for
existence, and the diminution of the importance of household
occupations. Outside of those whose economic situation forces them to
work for money, the number of women who seek to earn something is
becoming greater and greater. With these it is not necessity that
forces them, but the spirit of independence awakened in them by the
example of the others. If, on the one hand, the supply of women’s labor
increases, on the other hand the demand is increasing also; for though
it has been asserted that women are incapable of anything beyond
housekeeping, they have proved their aptitude for many of the
professions. And besides, the labor of women is much sought after, for
not being yet organized like men, the wages they can obtain are not so
large.

And if the women of the bourgeoisie are engaging more and more in paid
labor, the women of the proletariat were forced into it long ago. The
labor of women became possible through the development of mechanical
processes, as our exposition of the present economic system has shown.
Since then this form of labor has assumed larger and larger
proportions. The unmarried women of the proletariat are all obliged to
provide for their needs, while the married women also often are, and
the number of these is continually increasing. [316]

By what has gone before it has been indicated how important a change
has taken place and is still taking place in the economic position of
women. This change is in the last analysis the reason why women have
revolted more and more against the inferior position in which the law
places them, and why their opposition has already taken the form of
deeds. This is the reason also why the legal position of woman is best
in general in those countries where she has freed herself most by her
independent work, as, for example, in the United States.



Up to this point we have examined only the legal side of the question.
We must go on to add some observations concerning the material side.
The civil codes rest, among other things, upon the fiction that all
persons are equal. No mention is made of the division into distinct
classes; and it is the same with marriage. Before the law all marriages
are equal, while in reality they are not so. It is necessary, therefore
to treat of the conjugal conditions of the different classes. [317]

In the first place take marriage in the bourgeois class. The conditions
of life for the two sexes are different before marriage. Leaving out of
account the fact that the number of women who provide for their own
needs is increasing (they are still in the minority), it is
incontestable that the aspirations of the women of the bourgeoisie tend
toward marriage, the earliest and best marriage possible, in order that
their future may be assured. And since the possibility of making a good
marriage is becoming less, husband-hunting with all its unfortunate
consequences becomes more and more eager. While the whole education of
women looks only to marriage, that of the great majority of young men
has as its object the attainment of wealth or an important position as
soon as possible. Even when the marriage is contracted in consequence
of a reciprocal inclination, the differing conceptions of life held by
the two parties contain the germs that may render it unhappy. In
speaking of these very frequent cases Mme. Dr. Adams-Lehmann very
justly says: “Neither understands the other. Sundered in everything
that belongs to life, from childhood up, nature succeeds in uniting
them at one point for a short time only. From this point on their paths
diverge. The husband complains often and bitterly that his wife does
not understand him. What would he have, when she belongs to an entirely
different civilization? She has her own virtues, her own failings and
vices, but they are not those of her husband, and serve principally to
set her at variance with him. And the same is true of the man, over
whose lack of understanding his wife just as often and bitterly
laments. Different systems of culture, different aims, different
ideals,—in such an atmosphere how should harmony thrive?” [318]

But these causes are further strengthened when economic motives have
influenced the marriage more or less. If the two parties have frankly
made their union on this basis they will not be too exacting, and will
know how to submit to the inevitable; but when, as is ordinarily the
case, the marriage has been contracted under false pretenses, the
situation is much worse. [319]

It is plain, then, from this how little the legal form shows the
reality. In order that the marriage may be contracted, the consent of
the two parties is necessary, no matter how that consent is obtained.
It is very often the parents who have made the choice, being guided by
calculation alone. Such is the reality, and the formal free consent is
only the appearance.

Weighty causes, sprung from social conditions, then, often bring it
about that the married life is one of hate and discord. Aside from the
reasons cited there is yet another which does not proceed from social
conditions. Even when the marriage has been brought about through
mutual inclination, there is no guarantee that this inclination will
last. Not only may the parties be deceived as to each other’s character
and temperament, but their feelings may change, and the marriage bond
become insupportable.

The law permits divorce only in certain fixed cases; and since divorce
brings with it serious economic disadvantages for the woman, and
sometimes for the man as well, it is not often resorted to. The fear of
losing the good opinion of one’s friends may also prevent divorce. And
this fear of blame where a divorce is desired proves once more how
little real love has to do with the origin of monogamy.

If it is difficult, then, if not impossible, to break a marriage, the
consequence is bound to be adultery, especially on the side of the man,
since his manner of life gives him easy opportunity for it, and he does
not fear the consequences as a woman does. The difference between
monogamy and the more ancient forms of marriage is not great. Before
the law monogamy alone is recognized and polygamy prohibited; but in
reality polygamy always exists.

Let us go on now to marriage among the proletarians. [320] Here there
can be no question of a different education for the boy and the girl;
both are put to work while still children, and their relations are
quite free. Among the working classes marriage usually takes place at
an early age, because the workman early reaches the maximum of his
earning capacity, and as a consequence it is useless for him to wait
long before marrying; besides which he reaches maturity sooner than the
bourgeois. Often marriage is contracted after it has been consummated
and the sexual intercourse has had results. This is easy to understand
when one observes the life of the proletariat, their housing
conditions, their work in common, etc.

While it is not true that the marriages of the proletariat are always
marriages of inclination, as has been asserted (for material interests
play some part here also), yet they are oftenest of this kind. One of
the causes, then, which often make marriages among the bourgeoisie
unhappy does not exist here. On the other hand there are other causes
which can bring about the same result. In the first place, this
inclination is in many cases of a sexual nature only, without there
being any sympathy of character. If this inclination dies out,
therefore,—a thing which happens very often, since marriages in the
proletariat are made at an early age, and the women soon grow old
because of their hard life—there is no longer any basis for a happy
marriage. There is a lack of that intellectual development which may
render the difficulties of married life supportable. In consequence of
this lack the slightest differences may result in great altercations,
and the causes of unhappiness are sought in the person and not in the
circumstances of which the person is but the victim. Then in the next
place there are the heavy cares of the struggle for existence. If a
laborer’s family have already enough difficulty in making both ends
meet, in the case of sickness or forced unemployment their misery is
extreme, and it is often this misery which causes disputes and even
blows. Further, the labor of women, the bad housing conditions, and
alcoholism all tend to the same result. And because of hard work and
many cares the wife of the workman soon grows old. In the proletarian
class, therefore, marriages are threatened by many causes.

There is besides all this a very important difference between the
marriages of the bourgeoisie and those of the proletariat as to their
bases. The preponderating power of the man, which is strongly marked in
bourgeois marriages, is less so in the proletarian, especially in those
families where the woman provides for herself by paid labor. And
private property, one of the “raisons d’être” of legal monogamy with
the bourgeoisie, is lacking among the proletariat. This “raison d’être”
is found with the latter in the necessity that the man should be
charged with providing for the material needs of the children. Thus, in
the proletariat the free union between a man and a woman generally
meets with disapprobation only when there are offspring. The
consequences are, first, that conjugal unions without legal sanction
are not as much frowned upon by the proletarians as by the other
classes; second, that the decision to dissolve the union, whether free
or legal, is much more easily made among proletarians than among the
bourgeoisie. [321]

With regard to marriage among the lower proletariat a word or two will
suffice. Persons who have recently fallen to this class keep the ideas
of the class from which they came. But when the persons have been born
in the lower proletariat, or when their poverty has lasted for a long
time, they become demoralized, and the relations between men and women
show the effects of it. [322]

We come, then, to the end of our exposition. It seems to me that it has
been shown that the different forms of marriage are in the last
instance determined by the respective modes of production. Hence the
origin of monogamy, the most recent form of marriage, is not to be
found in the innate desire of the man and the woman to be united for
the whole of their lives, a desire which the law is supposed to
sanction. Quite on the contrary men are not all monogamous, and still
less monogamous during the whole of their life; a circumstance because
of which the present economic conditions have produced the legal
marriage, obliging two persons to remain together; if it were otherwise
the law would not concern itself with the relations between man and
woman.

Some important modifications have taken and are taking place in this
matter. The bases upon which the present marriage system rests are
changing. This is due to different reasons. In the first place woman is
coming little by little to occupy a higher and more independent social
position. Next, the importance of housekeeping in the economic life is
diminishing. The only moral basis for marriage is little by little
coming to be mutual love and sympathy, for true love can only exist
between persons free and equal. [323] There is a constantly increasing
number of persons who, in place of stigmatizing as immoral a union that
is non-legitimate, but contracted because of mutual love and sympathy,
consider it, on the contrary, as superior to a legal marriage
contracted for economic reasons.

Finally, it is to be noted that the present economic and social life
has bound up the sexual life with the economic life, by making marriage
possible only for those who have the necessary means at their disposal,
and consequently has caused the compulsory celibacy of millions of men
and women.




B. THE FAMILY.

In the preceding pages we have fixed the attention principally upon the
relation between the man and the woman, and it now remains to treat of
the position of the children born of their union.

It is a biological fact that the mother is designed by nature to have
the care of the child during its first years, and consequently this
care persists through all phases of the social development. It is,
then, superfluous to speak of it in a sociological treatise.

The relations between parents and children have not always been the
same in the different phases of social development, and it is therefore
impossible to speak here of relations instituted by nature. A glance at
the respective situations in the different periods shows that among the
“lower hunters”, where the woman is considered as the property of the
man, the children born are also in the absolute power of their father,
who has the right of life and death over his children, and whose power
over them ceases only when he has sold his daughters to their husbands,
or when his sons, having become adults, are recognized as members of
the tribe. [324]

Among the upper hunters and the pastoral peoples it is, as with the
peoples named above, to the father, in general, that the children
belong, or to whom they owe obedience. The mother, herself in
subjection to the father, has little or no authority over the children.
[325]

Among the lower agriculturists the conditions in question differ
relatively very much. As has been shown in the considerations upon
marriage among these peoples, the position of woman is often quite
other than during the preceding periods. She is not at all in so
subordinate a situation, her position is even not without importance,
thanks to the place which she occupies in the economic life. And this
importance shows itself also in her relations with her children. In
general it is to the mother that the education of the children falls,
while the influence of the father is little or nothing. In these last
cases a greater or less power belongs to the mother’s brother (under
the matriarchate the grandfather and father of the children belong to
another clan, and the maternal uncle and the children belong to the
clan of the mother). [326]

As has already been said above conditions among the higher
agriculturists were patriarchal. The father had unlimited power over
his unmarried daughters, and over all his sons with their descendants.
[327] It is from these so-called “great families”, that the present
form of the family springs (husband, wife, and their not yet
emancipated children) as a consequence of the fact that the adult sons
have been able to emancipate themselves on account of the modifications
that the economic life has undergone. From this time especially the
affection for children in general which is found among almost all
people, takes on an exclusive character, and becomes limited to one’s
own children. For monogamy is before all a consequence of the desire of
the man, which came in with private property, to leave his possessions
to the children of his legal wife, whose father he knew himself to be.
[328]

In its essence this form of the family has been maintained down to the
present day. The modifications it has undergone may be reduced to the
two following. [329] In the first place, in consequence of her improved
position as wife, the mother has obtained a greater influence over the
education of her children, though her power is, under the law, still
subordinated in every way to that of her husband. In the second place
the state manifests a continually increasing tendency to exert an
influence over the relations between parents and their children. To
begin with, the state imposes upon married parents the task of
supporting and bringing up their children, and prohibits by the penal
law slaying or abandoning them. The origin of these requirements must
be found in the fact that the state is interested in having the
children cared for, in order that the population may be as numerous as
possible. (The state being once formed, while the causes of infanticide
among primitive peoples have almost disappeared, the law has no
occasion to make any great change in the existing situation.) If the
married parents were not forced by the state to support and bring up
their children [330] it would be necessary to impose this task upon
other institutions which do not exist in our present society. The state
is not an institution for the public well-being; it is chiefly a means
of maintaining the external order in the disorder which results from
the complicated and muddled system of capitalistic production; it is
before all a system of police. If it were otherwise, the state would
consider it as one of its first duties to deprive parents of their
rights over their children, if they did not perform their task, or did
it badly, and would itself undertake the care and training of these
children, as well of those whose parents were dead or otherwise
absolutely unable to care for them. For society as a whole, as well as
the children themselves, has a very great interest in this matter.

However, the state in general does not assume any duty towards
abandoned or neglected children, and only in a hesitating way
intervenes to punish or to take away the parental authority of those
who have been guilty of such acts. [331] Little by little, as the ideas
upon the duties of the state become modified however (principally under
the influence of organized labor, which aims at transforming the state
into an organized community), it interests itself more in the person of
the child. As to the care of the child’s property all the codes are
already very much detailed!

There are two points with regard to which the state quite generally has
an influence over the lot of the child. First, it prohibits or limits
his paid labor; and second, it obliges parents to send their children
to school.

We have already spoken of this prohibition, which is made necessary
from the fact that the physical condition of the working classes is
becoming worse, and because the labor movement exercises a pressure
upon the state. Compulsory education has its origin, on one side, in
the fact that, in some occupations, capitalism cannot make use of
workmen who are altogether ignorant; on the other side, in the fact
that without compulsory education the youth of the working class would
be even more brutalized than at present. The opposition to compulsory
education on the part of whatever is conservative is another clear
indication of what an intimate connection there is between the
individual family and the present economic system. The economic
position of the man as breadwinner for his wife and children is the
cause of his desire to be limited in his power as little as possible.



Up to this point we have been treating of conditions past and present
only in so far as they are regulated by law (the formal side); we must
now go on to treat conditions from the material side. Here we must
consider three subjects: physical education, intellectual education,
and moral education. In treating of criminality, however, we have
naturally little to do with the first two, while the third is of the
highest importance for us.

As to physical education it is enough to say that it is the “conditio
sine qua non” of the two others. The intellectual and moral qualities
of a child that is badly cared for physically, can never be entirely
developed. The parents (and the child himself) use up all their energy
in providing for their bodily necessities, so that there is none left
for the other needs. Dr. A. Baer says: “Children of this kind (i.e., of
the poor classes) already at an early age bear the cares and sorrows
that life imposes upon them; they early become acquainted with the
claims and demands of life, and not infrequently are very early
influenced by living-conditions which will necessarily affect them long
afterward.” [332]

It is only among the bourgeoisie and the relatively well-to-do portion
of the petty bourgeoisie that there can be any sufficient physical
education for the children. Among the proletarians, and those of the
petty bourgeoisie who are in a similar situation as regards material
conditions, it is insufficient, and worse, if possible, among the lower
proletariat. However, if there is a lack of it among these last, there
is at times a superabundance among the bourgeoisie. There children are
often brought up in such luxury that they are early made blasé and
rendered unhappy for the future. Dr. Baer says upon this subject: [333]
“It is through other circumstances and causes that the children of the
rich and well-to-do classes are brought to a condition of precocity,
accompanied by sickly irritability and arrogant self-conceit. Here are
good-living, luxury, and the superabundance of bodily enjoyments, the
early familiarity with the theater, balls, and outside social life in
general, which make them incapable of the harmless pleasures of
childhood. Improper education in the family is responsible for the fact
that children in widely separated social classes are already at any
early age left to themselves and fall into evil ways. ‘One must have
lived in a great city,’ says von Krafft-Ebing, ‘and have visited the
hovels of the poor, and the palaces of the rich to know what mistakes
in the bringing up of children are committed there, where the children
of the poor, amidst dirt and drink, and those of the rich, amidst
arrogance and rascality, are going to ruin physically and morally....
Every day may be seen children falling asleep at the theater or other
places of amusement to which their parents’ folly and desire for
pleasure have dragged them. Other parents provide for their children
the doubtful happiness of children’s balls and soirées. Is it any
wonder, then, if we now, especially in the great cities, very seldom
meet with any real children?’”

In the countries where education is compulsory, it is guaranteed that
all the children will acquire a certain amount of knowledge. It is
unnecessary to say that in general this amount of knowledge is very
small in the case of the children of the poor, and consists of the
rudiments of reading, writing, and arithmetic, so that there is no real
intellectual education. For the children of the bourgeoisie quite a
different preparation is made; here there is rather an over- than an
undersupply of the means of education. The great competition in present
day society, the superabundance of intellectual forces, the ardent
desire to see their children succeed in spite of everything, all this
obliges parents to crowd their children’s intellectual capacities, even
to the detriment of their other qualities. “The thing which in our
modern life conduces most to the giving of a one-sided, inharmonious
development to the child, is the fact that too little weight is given
to the development of the disposition, and too much to the development
of the understanding. Because there is no influence exerted upon the
spiritual and emotional life, the mind of the child is often from early
youth turned toward the material and sensuous, the life of pleasure,
and comes to bend its thought wholly to the practical and utilitarian.”
[334]

Thus we arrive at the very subject we have in view, moral education. As
I have already remarked, one of the characteristic differences between
education among the primitive peoples and that of our own day is this,
that as a consequence of the great complexity of our present society,
and the numberless conflicts between individual interests, the task
imposed upon the educator is now much broader and more onerous. [335]

The first condition, without doubt, that might be demanded of one who
is to make a child into a moral man, a man of character, is surely
this, that he should be himself a man of character. It goes without
saying that no person can give more than he has. Leaving aside for the
moment the criminal class, of whom I shall treat later, it is clear
that no one without character, or weak in character, can ever train
children to have well developed moral sentiments. He may be able, it is
true, to teach them to distinguish good from bad, but such lessons
concern only the intellectual part of the nature and not the moral
part, and they cannot transform children into persons who feel morally.
It cannot be denied that the number of persons who do not feel morally
is great, and that these have children. Without forgetting the fact
that it is the father to whom the law gives especially the parental
authority, we must recognize that it is the mother upon whom the task
of education generally rests, because the father is almost always away
from home. But the inferior position of woman, maintained now for
centuries, has been extremely harmful to her character, and thus it
often happens that this lack of character passes to the children as
well. [336]

A second condition without which successful education is impossible is
that educators shall have the innate qualities necessary for their
task. We should doubt, and not without reason, the common sense of
anyone who dared to assert that every person was capable of becoming a
good sculptor or even carpenter. Just so no one could say that everyone
possesses the qualities necessary for an art as difficult as that of
education.

To be a good educator it is necessary to be very fond of children, to
have much patience and zeal, to know how to put one’s self on a plane
with the child, to have a clear and practical intellect, especially
when the teacher has a great affection for the child, since without
intelligence the excess of affection will only be harmful. There are
parents who possess these qualities in a very high degree, and it is
only to be regretted that they teach only their own children, and not
those also of parents in whom the teaching faculty is entirely lacking.
Next comes the group of those who have a modicum of the requisite
qualities, and finally a smaller group who have little or no aptitude
for the task. The least fit to give a good education, however, are
psychopathic individuals, because of their changeable disposition,
their quick fits of temper, etc.

Just as educators differ greatly in their innate fitness for teaching,
so different children need to be guided in different ways. If there are
children who require little care in order that they may presently be
able to adapt themselves to the requirements of society, others, who
form the great majority, require more; while there remains a second
minority who, if they are to be made fairly useful men and women, must
have constant and minute attention. Among these last are to be classed
the victims of heredity. If they have parents without great teaching
ability, as is often the case with these psychopathic individuals, the
results are even worse.

Aside from innate fitness it is necessary that an educator should have
received the necessary education. The teacher without notions of
psychology, of pedagogy, etc., often deceives himself, even if he has
all the necessary innate qualities, and consequently warps the
character of his pupils.

The instructor must learn his trade, and if this is so, why should not
the educator in charge of the moral education of the child need an
apprenticeship, since moral education is a task no less difficult than
intellectual education (which is about all that our present schools
undertake)? However, it is incontestable that in all classes of society
today moral education is practiced in dilettante fashion, as was
formerly the case with intellectual education. [337]

Finally, there remains the condition that the teacher should have the
time necessary to perform his task, for without this the most capable
cannot attain good results. Having now laid down the general
conditions, let us go on to examine in a few words education as it is
actually practiced in the different classes.

Let us begin with the bourgeoisie. As has already been remarked, the
children in this class are often spoiled by the great luxury that
surrounds them, and further by the fact that their intellect is
developed at the expense of their moral qualities. As my remarks
concerning capacity, character, etc., apply to all classes, it is
unnecessary here to speak of them more fully. Only it must be observed
that, as far as positive knowledge of pedagogy is concerned, the
bourgeoisie is much superior to the proletariat, from which there
follows among other things a corresponding superiority of the bourgeois
education. The character of the bourgeois woman, who occupies, like all
women, a lower rank in society, has generally suffered still more from
her easy mode of life, and her weakness of character is transmitted to
her children if she brings them up herself. This condition must be
added, for society life, or in other words, the habit of doing nothing
at all, is often the cause of mothers’ having their children brought up
by some one who has neither natural aptitude nor acquired capacity for
this task, but only takes charge of the children for the sake of a
place. There are even children who are not suckled by their mothers but
by nurses, since the mothers are afraid of diminishing their own
charms. This proves once more the weakness of the allegation that the
parents are the natural educators of the child; for we see in this case
that the social environment can lead to the renunciation of duties that
are really natural. [338]

The moral education of the children of the bourgeoisie is generally
superficial, and has especially in view the task of teaching the
children to conduct themselves according to the proprieties, much more
than that of developing their real moral nature. [339] In the second
place this education develops among them a very strong feeling of
class, so that they consider the members of the proletariat as inferior
beings, born by nature to serve the bourgeoisie, in place of seeing in
them only their own fellows, who have become different merely because
of fortuitous circumstances.

In the third place, our present educational system makes children
egoistic, those of the bourgeoisie more than those of the proletariat.
This assertion contradicts, it is true, the numerous authors who are
convinced that our present education in the family is a source of
altruism. [340] They are right when they say that altruistic sentiments
between the members of the family themselves have their rise within the
circle of the family. For a long time the life within the family
constituted a man’s whole life (as it still does for a very great
number of women), but in the society of today a great part of the time
is passed outside of the family circle, and for this reason the opinion
of these authors, though shared by many persons, is not correct. In the
family circle the child, especially when he has neither brothers nor
sisters, [341] soon discovers that his own interests come first, that
the outside world is his enemy, and that when he grows up he must make
himself as large a place there as possible. It matters little that the
interests of others will then be injured. It must be added further,
that if on the one side the family is an economic unity, and that the
interests of the members of the family are so far parallel, on the
other hand there exist opposing interests, such as inheritance, which
may destroy the homogeneity of interest.

It may be objected here that in our present society, consisting as it
does for the most part of adherents of Christianity, most children are
taught to love their neighbor as themselves. This is true, but in a
society such as ours, where the interests of all men are opposed, the
effect of this commandment cannot be great, or will be practiced only
in words and not in acts, and so end in hypocrisy. He who wants to
follow this commandment to the letter sees himself at once defeated in
the conflict of life, unless he changes his opinion. [342]

No one known to me has better characterized the existing educational
system than Owen. “As society is now constituted,” he says, “no
children can by possibility be really well educated. The fundamental
errors upon which it has been based, filling the early mind with error
and hypocrisy and all manner of conflicting ideas, opposed to facts and
to nature, render it impracticable for any child to be rationally
trained or treated by society. And the more education of this kind is
given to children, the more they are estranged from a knowledge of
themselves, or of human nature generally, and the less competent will
they be to understand what society has been made to be, and yet less
what it ought to be, and how it may be made what it is desirable that
it should be, for the happiness and well-being of all.

“Mothers and fathers thus taught, are incompetent to teach and educate
their children in the spirit, manner, and conduct, which should, for
the benefit of all, be given to all children. Their affections also,
especially the strong natural animal affections of the mother, are, in
almost all cases too strong for the very limited powers of judging
accurately respecting their own children and those of other parents,
which females now acquire from their present mal-education.

“The individual family arrangements confining the child to the limited
number of ideas among them—to their early deep impressions in favor of
family interests and supposed rights—to the narrow and partial
experience of a family and its usual small connections, are equally
destructive of a good sound practical education or well-training of
children.

“The individual system of society which has so long prevailed in all
nations, and amongst all peoples, is also a strong barrier to the
proper education of beings intended to be made rational. The individual
system of society is injurious to man now, under every point of view in
which it can be considered; but especially in the education of children
of all classes. It confines all their strongest feelings to self first,
then to family, afterwards to kindred, and then to small neighborhoods
and districts, regularly and systematically training each child to
become at maturity a merely localized, ignorantly selfish animal,
filled with family and geographical prejudices.

“As long as this individual system shall be continued, it will be vain
to expect that any child can be well educated, or properly trained to
become a rational being—a man with the full physical and mental powers
of humanity, intelligent, moral, and virtuous. The isolated character
formed by the individual system will, as long as children shall be
educated under it, and in accordance with all its innumerable errors in
practice and principle, render it impossible for any child to be so
educated and placed in society as not to become, more or less, a cause
of anxiety to its parents. Every child under this system comes into
society, at its birth, opposed by the capital and experience of
society; and as it advances in its progress, and has to take part in
the jostle, bustle and business of life, it has to contend for itself,
often, not only against these general powers of society, but on the
death of parents, or sometimes even before, with brothers and sisters,
for individual property or other advantages.

“Besides, children before they have any resisting powers of mind, being
forced to receive the errors of their parents and other early
instructors, respecting their supposed faculties of believing and
disbelieving, loving and hating, are by this process, placed through
life in direct opposition to nature; and, as vice has been made, by the
gross errors of our ancestors, to consist in acting in accordance with
nature, and virtue in acting in opposition to it, and as nature
continually impels the individual to desire to act in accordance with
its own laws, in defiance of man’s unwise and unjust laws, the great
probability is that children will be more liable to obey nature than
man; and thus, where there are children, they must be a source of
constant anxiety to parents; and that anxiety must be injurious to the
best formation of the organization of the remainder of the infants that
may be born to them.” [343]

We have still to fix our attention upon the sexual education of the
children of the bourgeoisie. In our society the Christian sexual ethics
is dominant, often even among non-Christians, without their being
conscious of it. According to this system the whole sexual life
proceeds from the evil one, and man would be better without any sexual
instincts. [344] This is why children are generally raised in an
absolute ignorance upon this subject, or even have lies told to them
about it. As nature cannot be suppressed it follows that the curiosity
of the child only becomes the more inflamed, and that the conduct of
men in this regard becomes hypocritical. [345]

Secondly, let us take up education in the petty bourgeoisie. Upon this
point we can be very brief. A part of this class joins on to the
proletariat from the conditions of its life, and another part to the
bourgeoisie. It is unnecessary, therefore, to speak of it at length. It
is only the core of the petty bourgeoisie who, having kept the
traditions of their class, show any differences in this regard. Here
there is no danger of the demoralizing influence of the luxurious
surroundings of the rich, and the surveillance of the father is
greater, and thus the education more severe; but the limited conception
of life, and the continual efforts of the parents, eager to procure
advantages for their families, develop egotism among their children in
a high degree.

With regard to the proletariat it has already been shown that the
material advantages necessary for a sufficient education are lacking in
the case of this class. Housing conditions are here of the greatest
importance. Generally there is not room enough for the children at
home, so that they spend the greater part of the day in the street.
Then again the housing conditions are responsible for the fact that the
children often are thrown with persons whose influence is harmful to
them (prostitutes, etc.). And finally the small apartments bring it
about that the children are too early instructed in sexual matters, and
this in a bad way (through sleeping in the same small room with their
parents, or in the same bed with children of the opposite sex, etc.).

Then children need to grow up in an environment not poisoned by cares,
one in which poverty does not harden the heart, and extinguish all
gayety, and where the knowledge necessary for education is not wanting.
Further, in this class the father has generally no opportunity to busy
himself with the education of his children in consequence of the long
duration of his hours of labor outside of the home. A great many
working men have to leave home in the morning to go to work long before
their children are awake, to return only after the little ones have
already been put to bed; and the situation is much the same where the
laborer works at night, and consequently sleeps during the day.

The development of capitalism has led to the paid labor of married
women, and consequently to one of the most important causes of the
demoralization of the children of the working class. When there is no
one to watch a child, when he is left to himself, he becomes
demoralized. In his work, “The Condition of the Working-Class in
England”, F. Engels has put the situation briefly: “The employment of
the wife [in the factory] dissolves the family utterly and of
necessity, and this dissolution, in our present society, which is based
upon the family, brings the most demoralizing consequences, both for
parents and for the children. A mother who has no time to trouble
herself about her child, to perform the most ordinary loving services
for it during the first year, who scarcely indeed sees it, can be no
real mother to the child, must inevitably grow indifferent to it, and
treat it unlovingly, like a stranger. The children who grow up under
such conditions are entirely ruined for later family life, can never
feel at home in the family which they themselves found, because they
have always been accustomed to isolation, and they contribute therefore
to the already general undermining of the family in the working class.”
[346]

Finally, when, through death or otherwise, the parents are no longer in
a position to support and raise their children, they are left to their
fate, unless there are charitable persons or benevolent institutions
that wish to take charge of them. For the state, for reasons shown
above, does not lay upon itself the duty of caring for such children.

It remains now to speak of the lower proletariat, among whom
prostitutes and criminals are included. The education of these persons
is not only much neglected, as is often the case with the children of
the proletariat, of whom it may be said that they receive a negative
education—but these receive in addition a positive education in evil.
It might be possible to dispute the advantages of a good education, but
it is indisputable that children brought up by immoral people, or even
incited to evil (prostitution or crime) run the greatest risk, unless
exceptional circumstances present themselves, of becoming persons
hurtful to society.

In this connection it is necessary to fix our attention, finally, upon
the situation in which illegitimate children find themselves. Since
marriage, at once the consequence and support of existing social
conditions, is the only form of sexual union legally recognized,
illegitimate children are legally and socially treated as pariahs.
[347]

It is difficult to form an idea of the great number of children who, in
our present society, are neglected or abandoned. The following passage
may help form some conception of it: “If the reader will imagine a
procession of 109,000 children marching past him, and notice
attentively child after child as it goes by, he will get some idea of
the extent of the suffering of children with which the ‘National
Society for the Prevention of Cruelty to Children in England’ has
actually had to do during the first ten years of its existence.

“The first 25,437 are sufferers from injuries inflicted upon them with
boots, crockery, pans, shovels, straps, ropes, pokers, fire, boiling
water, in short with every imaginable instrument that came to the hand
of the brutal and vindictive parents—covered with wounds and bruises,
burned, scalded, and covered with plasters and bandages.

“Then come 62,887 sufferers from neglect and starvation—covered with
dirt, eruptions, and sores, trembling, in rags, half-naked, pale, weak,
faint, feeble, pining, starving, dying—many of them borne in the arms
of the nurses of the hospitals.

“Then come 712 funeral processions, where the maltreatment ended
fatally.

“Then come 12,663 little beings, their sufferings displayed to turn the
lazy and cruel benevolence of the street to those who are answerable
for their pallor, leanness, and coughs—most of these, too, are still in
arms, but in the arms of vile drunkards and vagabonds.

“Then come 4460 pitiable girls, victims of the lust of human monsters.

“Then come 3205 little slaves of unsuitable and harmful occupations and
dangerous performances, untimely births in traveling vans, acrobats at
fairs, trapeze performers and tight-rope walkers in circuses, laboring
under too heavy a load, and suffering the most diverse outrages. The
procession is 60 miles long and takes 24 hours to pass by.” [348]

The society spoken of above is a private institution. The extent of its
labors is very limited, which is why it has not taken cognizance of a
great number of the children who have been thus treated. At the time
when the report containing the above figures had just appeared, it had
only been in operation ten years—during the last five more effectively,
as a part of the first five was taken up with the organization of its
service. Finally the field of its labors includes only the United
Kingdom, while capitalism reigns over a great part of the world and has
everywhere the same consequences. In consideration of these facts we
can form an idea of the great destitution in which a multitude of
children are found, and what sort of persons children so treated are
likely to grow up to be.

To sum up what has been said, we see that the system of education for
the child has not always been what it is now, and that we cannot
therefore speak in this connection of institutions created by nature,
except as regards the relation between mother and child during the
first years of the latter’s life. It has been shown, I think, that the
present system of education is closely bound up with the method of
production of the day. No one can deny that in this regard also we are
far from living in the “best of possible worlds.” [349]




C. PROSTITUTION. [350]

By prostitution must be understood the social fact that there are women
who sell their bodies for the exercise of sexual acts, and make a
profession of it. The putting of one’s body at the disposal of another
for the purpose of sexual intercourse constitutes then at times the
sale of merchandise. To find the cause of prostitution in our present
society it is necessary to begin by asking: “What are the causes for
the demand for this merchandise?” These causes may be reduced to the
following:

a. The difficulty or impossibility of marrying found by many men. We
have already seen that in our present society there is a continually
increasing number of the petty bourgeois and of those who practice the
liberal professions who, in consequence of the insufficiency of their
incomes, cannot marry, or only at a rather advanced age. As we have
seen, also, this is not in general the case with the proletariat. They
reach the maximum of their wages while still quite young, and are less
exacting as regards their material needs. All this brings it about that
they marry sooner and so have less recourse to prostitution. (Soldiers
and seamen, who are often forced to remain unmarried, form an
exception.)

b. Besides those of whom I have been speaking, those also must be
mentioned who do not wish to attach themselves for life to a single
woman. Further, separate education, inducing a different life for the
two sexes, is often an obstacle to the easy meeting of two persons who
might make a marriage of inclination. Many men renounce marriage
because the intellectual plane of women is altogether different from
theirs, as a consequence both of their education and of their manner of
life, and also because with them the thought of improving their
economic position by marriage predominates. [351]

The larger contingent of men who have recourse to prostitutes is made
up of bachelors, [352] and the smaller of married men. Whence springs
the following cause:

c. Often the marriage is not contracted from inclination, but for
financial reasons, which brings it about that the men often indemnify
themselves with prostitutes. But this is applicable also to those cases
where the marriage has not been made for the reasons named, but in
which, for any cause, an antipathy has sprung up between the couple,
without the dissolution of the marriage, either because of the
difficulty of securing a divorce, or from motives of expediency. Since
monogamy does not proceed from an innate inclination, prostitution is a
necessary correlative of marriage.

d. The keeping of extravagant mistresses is a pastime for those who
have been demoralized by a life of luxury and ease, and at the same
time is a means by which these people can get rid of their incomes.

e. Finally, prostitution is a means whereby rich perverts satisfy their
inclinations.

Before leaving the causes of the demand for prostitutes there is one
further matter to consider. Those who have recourse to prostitutes must
necessarily have a low opinion of woman, whom they consider only as an
object existing for pleasure, and thus bound to be ready, as soon as a
man wishes, to furnish him what he desires, for money, and not because
of affection. This vile fashion of regarding women has been universal
for centuries, and is still pretty general. It is to be explained from
the long-continued inferior social position of women. We have seen that
this position has been improved little by little, and that the result
of this improvement has been an increase in the number of men who have
a higher opinion of woman, and who wish to have sexual relations with a
woman only when there is a mutual affection between them. These persons
form even today only a small minority, however.

In the presence of a majority still thinking quite differently it is
absurd to preach total sexual abstinence to all unmarried young men, as
certain moralists do (Tolstoi, for example). Though there are men who
abstain without injury to their health, these moralists forget that the
satisfaction of the sexual desires is one of the most important needs
of the majority of men (the life of our day certainly increases these
desires), and that present social conditions are the cause of men’s
considering woman their inferior. Dr. Blaschko, in his work “Die
Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”, rightly says: “The sexual requirement
in the case of mankind as of all other beings is an entirely natural
one. To be sure, it is not so strong and compelling as the necessity of
food and drink; it can be suppressed in the case of anyone for a time,
and with many permanently, without injury to the health. But what is
true of this or that person does not hold for the mass of mankind, for
whom sexual intercourse is doubtless a necessity.” [353]

It is now necessary to inquire why there is a sufficient supply to meet
this demand. Before beginning, however, one remark must be made. The
point of departure of the etiology of prostitution must be the
incontestable fact that modesty is not an innate but an acquired
quality. The problem is chiefly, then, what are the causes why the
feeling of modesty is not sufficiently developed among certain women.
The following are the principal causes:

a. Immoral environment. We shall examine this first in so far as it
affects children. [354] In running over the statistics which mention
the age of prostitutes one is particularly struck by the fact that a
great number of them are still very young. To cite some examples: Dr.
G. Richelot gives the following figures in his work “La Prostitution en
Angleterre”: [355]


London, 1836–1854.

Prostitutes Sentenced in Cases of Summary Jurisdiction.

=====================+==================
        Age.         |  To the 10,000.
---------------------+------------------
From 10 to 15 years  |         27
 ,,  15 ,, 20  ,,    |      2,463
 ,,  20 ,, 25  ,,    |      3,623
25 and over          |      3,887
=====================+==================


Edinburgh, 1835–1842.

Prostitutes Admitted to “Lock Hospital.”

================+==================
      Age.      |  To the 1,000.
----------------+------------------
Below 15        |       42
From  15 to 20  |      662
 ,,   20 ,, 25  |      199
25 and over     |       97
================+==================


In the “Reports from the Select Committee of the House of Lords on the
Law Relating to the Protection of Young Girls” [356] the following
figures may be found:


England, 1881–1882.

Received into an “Asylum for Girls and Women.”

==========+==========+=============
  Age.    | Number.  | Percentage.
----------+----------+-------------
12 to 14  |    8   } |
14 ,, 16  |    6   } |
16 ,, 18  |   28   } |     55
18 ,, 20  |   34   } |
20 ,, 23  |    9    }|
23 ,, 25  |   25    }|     45
25 ,, 39  |   27    }|
          +----------+-------------
          |  137     |    100
==========+==========+=============


In his work “De la Prostitution dans la ville de Paris”
Parent-Duchatelet gives the following figures: [357]


Paris, 1831.

Registered Prostitutes.

============+===========+=============
    Age.    |  Number.  | Percentage.
------------+-----------+-------------
12 years    |      1  } |
13  ,,      |      3  } |
14  ,,      |      8  } |
15  ,,      |     17  } |
16  ,,      |     44  } |     23.6
17  ,,      |     55  } |
18  ,,      |    101  } |
19  ,,      |    115  } |
20  ,,      |    216  } |
21  ,,      |    204  } |
22  ,,      |    249   }|
23  ,,      |    240   }|
24  ,,      |    207   }|     76.4
25  ,,      |    193   }|
26 and over |  1,582   }|
            +-----------+-------------
            |  3,235    |    100.0
============+===========+=============


C. J. Lecour gives the following table: [358]


Paris, 1855–1869.

Registered Prostitutes.

================+===========+=============
     Age.       |  Number.  | Percentage.
----------------+-----------+-------------
Below 18 years  |     513   |      8
From 18 to 21   |   1,704   |     26.6
Over 21         |   4,190   |     65.4
                +-----------+-------------
                |   6,407   |    100.0
================+===========+=============


Dr. Augagneur gives the following ages for prostitutes admitted to the
hospital: [359]


Lyons.

========+===============+================+==========
 Years. |  Older Girls. | Younger Girls. |  Total.
--------+---------------+----------------+----------
  1877  |  520 (65.5%)  |   274 (34.0%)  |    794
  1887  |  144 (68.2%)  |    67 (31.8%)  |    211
        +---------------+----------------+----------
        |  664 (66.07%) |   341 (33.73%) |  1,005
========+===============+================+==========


S. Sighele gives the following figures: [360]


Italy.

Registered Prostitutes.

=======+=================+=========+=============
 Year. |       Age.      | Number. | Percentage.
-------+-----------------+---------+-------------
 1875  |  From 16 to 20  |  2,455  |    26.98
       |   ,,  21 ,, 30  |  4,766  |    52.50
       |  31 and over    |  1,867  |    20.52
       |                 +---------+-------------
       |                 |  9,088  |   100.00
       |                 |         |
 1881  |  From 17 to 20  |  2,953  |    31.90
       |   ,,  21 ,, 30  |  5,456  |    58.92
       |  31 and over    |    850  |     9.18
       |                 +---------+-------------
       |                 |  9,259  |   100.00
       |                 |         |
 1885  |  Under 20       |  3,228  |    27.76
       |  From 20 to 30  |  4,589  |    54.70
       |  31 and over    |  1,471  |    17.54
       |                 +---------+-------------
       |                 |  8,388  |   100.00
=======+=================+=========+=============


Dr. L. Fiaux gives the result of an official enquiry, as follows: [361]


Russia, 1889.

Out of a Total of 17,603 Prostitutes.

================+==================
     Age.       |    Percentage.
----------------+------------------
15 and under    |     0.3 }
From 15 to 16   |     1.3 }
 ,,  16 ,, 17   |     3.5 }
 ,,  17 ,, 18   |     6.9 }   69.9
 ,,  18 ,, 19   |     8.8 }
 ,,  19 ,, 20   |    10.8 }
 ,,  20 ,, 25   |    38.3 }
25 and over     |    30.1     30.1
                |   -----    -----
                |   100.0    100.0
================+==================


Dr. A. Baumgarten gives the following figures: [362]


Vienna.

Prostitutes Not Registered.

=======+=======================
 Age.  |  Number to the 1,000.
-------+-----------------------
  13   |            4
  14   |           19
  16   |           94
  17   |           97
  18   |          111
  19   |          119
  20   |           83
       +-----------------------
       |          527
=======+=======================


As these figures show, there is a considerable portion of the
prostitutes who are minors, but they do not tell us of the number of
adults who embraced the profession while they were yet under age. As to
this point, Dr. Bonhoeffer gives the following, showing the age at
which the prostitutes whom he examined began the practice of their
profession: [363]


Breslau.

        16 years old or under      30   }
        Between 17 and 18 years    44   }    54%
          ,,    19 ,,  20  ,,      28   }
          ,,    21 ,,  50  ,,      88        46%
                                  ---       ----
                                  190       100%


Parent-Duchatelet gives the following table: [364]


Paris.

=================================+===========+=============
Age at the Time of Registration. |  Number.  | Percentage.
---------------------------------+-----------+-------------
 10                              |      2  } |
 11                              |      3  } |
 12                              |      3  } |
 13                              |      6  } |
 14                              |     20  } |
 15                              |     51  } |
 16                              |    111  } |     50.4
 17                              |    149  } |
 18                              |    279  } |
 19                              |    322  } |
 20                              |    389  } |
 21                              |    303  } |
 Over 21 years                   |  1,610    |     49.6
                                 |-----------+-------------
                                 |  3,248    |    100.0
=================================+===========+=============


Dr. Fiaux gives the following figures: [365]


Russia.

=================================+================
Age at the Time of Registration. |   Percentage.
---------------------------------+----------------
11 or younger                    |    1.2 }
13 to 15                         |    9.0 }
15 ,, 16                         |   12.9 }  80.5
16 ,, 18                         |   30.8 }
18 ,, 21                         |   26.6 }
21 and over                      |   19.5    19.5
                                 |  -----   -----
                                 |  100.0   100.0
=================================+================


A large majority of prostitutes, then, have been placed upon the
registers of the police while still under age. We may very well say,
moreover, without fear of mistake, that a great part of those who are
registered at a later period of life have already been among the
clandestine prostitutes. Dr. Augagneur says: “How many of these women,
devoted indefinitely to the life of a common prostitute, would not have
fled all its horrors if a society, careless of the interests of its
members, had furnished them with sufficient means of defense up to the
age at which they all have succumbed,—under 21 years? When a woman has
not prostituted herself before 21, she will not prostitute herself
later. Look for exceptions to this rule and you will find that they are
very few. The woman who is older and more experienced knows the
consequences of her acts; less passionate, less weak, and less
impressionable, she resists better a first temptation whose
consequences she is fully aware of. [366]

However this may be, it is certain that a very great proportion of the
prostitutes have taken up their profession, or have been seduced, while
they were still very young. Upon this latter point the following
figures enlighten us: [367]


England.

=======================================+===============
Age at which Prostitutes Were Seduced. |   Number.
---------------------------------------+---------------
11                                     |      3 }
12                                     |      5 }
13                                     |     16 }
14                                     |     79 }
15                                     |    189 }
16                                     |    184 }  58%
17                                     |    247 }
18                                     |    221 }
19                                     |    297 }
20                                     |    280 }
21                                     |    256 }
22 and over                            |  1,299    42%
                                       |  -----   ----
                                       |  3,076   100%
=======================================+===============


In his work, “La prostitution clandestine”, Dr. L. Martineau informs us
that the age at which the prostitutes whom he observed were deflowered
is distributed as follows: [368]


France.

======+==========
 Age. |  Number.
------+----------
   5  |     1
   9  |     2
  10  |     2
  11  |     2
  12  |     5
  13  |    11
  14  |    31
  15  |    86
  16  |    87
  17  |   115
  18  |    93
  19  |    50
  20  |    37
  21  |    27
      +----------
      |   549
======+==========
90% of a total of 607.


The facts already brought out give rise to the presumption that the
ranks of prostitutes are in a very large measure recruited from the
less well-to-do classes, where the neglect of children has assumed
enormous proportions, and not from the more favored classes where the
children are carefully guarded and kept away from unfavorable
influences. The correctness of this conclusion is shown by a further
examination. According to figures given in the “Reports” quoted above,
only 44 out of 3,076 prostitutes, or 1.4%, came from the well-to-do
classes. [369] In his “Sozialpolitisches Handbuch” Dr. Lux publishes
the following table: [370]


Berlin, 1871–1878.

==========================================+==========+=============
Profession of the Parents of Prostitutes. | Numbers. | Percentage.
------------------------------------------+----------+-------------
Artisans                                  |   1,015  |    48
Factory hands                             |     467  |    22
Lower officials                           |     305  |    14
Commerce and transportation               |     222  |    11
Agriculture, etc.                         |      87  |     4
Soldiers                                  |      26  |     1
                                          +----------+-------------
                                          |   2,122  |   100
==========================================+==========+=============


Dr. Bonhoeffer found that the fathers of the prostitutes whom he
examined practiced the following professions: [371]


Breslau.

=======================+=====+=======
Manufacture and trades |  72 |  42
Unskilled workmen      |  32 |  19
Lower officials        |  24 |  14
Commerce               |  13 |   8
Transportation         |  12 |   7
Lodginghouse-keepers   |   6 |   3.5
Agriculture            |   8 |   5
Traveling musicians    |   2 |   1
Higher officials       |   1 |   0.5
                       +-----+-------
                       | 170 | 100.0
=======================+=====+=======


Dr. Fiaux gives the following figures: [372]


Russia.

==============================================+=============
Classes from Which Prostitutes Are Recruited. | Percentage.
----------------------------------------------+-------------
Peasants                                      |  47.5
Bourgeois                                     |  36.3
Wives and daughters of soldiers               |   7.2
Other classes                                 |   4.7
Foreign subjects                              |   1.5
Nobles and daughters of employes              |   1.8
Merchants and considerable citizens           |    .5
Daughters of members of the clergy            |    .5
                                              +-------------
                                              | 100.0
==============================================+=============


As the table given above shows, the Russian prostitutes are recruited
in greater numbers from the bourgeoisie than in the other countries of
Europe. The Russian bourgeoisie, however, cannot be compared with that
of other countries. It is more like the petty bourgeoisie, as the
following quotation given by Dr. Fiaux proves: “The committee considers
that the great mass of the women registered belong to the lower
classes.” The fact that, of 100 prostitutes, 83 come from poor
families, 16 from well-to-do families, and one from a rich family,
proves the same thing.

After having given the professions of 3,332 fathers of prostitutes,
[373] Parent-Duchatelet arrives at the following conclusion: ...
“prostitutes born in Paris all proceed from the artisan class, and ...
it is not true, as some persons have assured me, that there are to be
found among them a number belonging to very distinguished families;
...” [374]

In speaking of the prostitutes born outside of Paris he says: “...
there is a mass of facts more than sufficient to prove to us that, as
far as the class of society from which prostitutes come is concerned,
the departments do not differ in any way from Paris; we see upon the
last table as upon the first, only working people and those little
favored by fortune, who consequently cannot take care of the education
of their daughters, nor watch them, and still less provide for their
needs when they have reached a certain age, ...” [375]

We must particularize these unfavorable environmental influences. And
the first fact that we meet is that a part of the young prostitutes
have been incited to the profession by their parents. Parent-Duchatelet
mentions 16 cases in which mother and daughter were both registered
prostitutes [376]; and von Oettingen quotes the following from Dr.
Tait: [377]


Edinburgh.

There were found among the prostitutes:

     2   mothers with 4 daughters each, or  8 in all,
     5     ,,     ,,  3    ,,      ,,   ,, 15 ,, ,,
    10     ,,     ,,  2    ,,      ,,   ,, 20 ,, ,,
    24     ,,     ,,  1 daughter   ,,   ,, 24 ,, ,,
    41   mothers with                      67 daughters in all


In the second place it is necessary to speak of the abandonment of the
children of the poor classes. No scientist of consequence admits that
the moral ideas are innate, but simply that the new-born infant is more
or less fitted to appropriate such ideas. It follows that one cannot
expect much from a child whose moral education has been neglected in
youth, however great natural capacity he may have been endowed with.
From this it follows that where there is lack of education and care
because of the death of the mother, or the alcoholism of the father, or
because the father and mother are both at work away from home a great
part of the day, or where the morality of the parents themselves is not
great, the children run great risk of being lost. The following figures
support this assertion:

Von Oettingen shows that, according to Dr. Ryan, 12,000 to 14,000
prostitutes in London became such as a consequence of a neglected
childhood. [378] In the “Reports of the Select Committee,” etc., the
following figures are found: [379] of 3,075 prostitutes 1,481 (48%)
were orphans, and 921 (29%) were half-orphans. In his “La prostitution
clandestine à Paris”, Dr. Commenge gives the following figures
concerning the 2,368 prostitutes whom he observed during the years from
1878 to 1887: [380]


                692 (29%) were orphans;
                456 (19%) had lost their mother;
                811 (35%) ,,   ,,   ,,   father.


Out of a total of 190 cases Dr. Bonhoeffer shows 72 (38%) in which the
education had been positively bad (criminality or prostitution on the
part of the parents, neglect, lack of surveillance, etc.); 106 cases
(56%) in which the education had been probably bad; and only 12 cases
(6%) in which it was proved that the education had been good. [381]

For Russia Dr. Fiaux gives the following figures: [382] 3.6% of the
prostitutes still had father and mother; 47.5% had parents who were
separated, and 18.5% were without any family.

With regard to the cause given for prostitution Dr. Augagneur says as
follows: “The majority of prostitutes are born to prostitution at the
same time that they are to puberty. Their moral sense, if such may be
called that which no one has ever tried to awaken, is not shocked by
their situation; they have prostituted themselves without shame and
without regret. They have left normal and respectable society without
being really aware of its existence, without the desire of ever
returning thither. They have lacked the things necessary to make them
respectable women—instruction in virtue, the example of their
relatives, the suspicious surveillance of their mothers, and material
well-being. The daughters of the people are not, at the day of their
birth, of a clay inferior to that of the daughters of the bourgeoisie
or of the nobility; they are naturally no less intelligent, no more
perverse. And yet if you examine the civil status of a hundred
prostitutes, you will find that 95 at least have sprung from the lowest
strata of society. The existing social inequality, that is to say, is
alone responsible for this unequal distribution.” [383]

Finally I will cite once more the opinion of Parent-Duchatelet, which
is of great value, since this author is the most able sociologist who
has treated of this subject. He says: “The misconduct of parents, and
the bad examples of every kind which they give to their children, must
be considered with regard to many girls, and especially those of Paris,
as one of the causes determining their mode of life. The dossiers of
each girl constantly make mention of disorder in the household, of
fathers who are widowers living with concubines, of lovers of mothers
widowed or married, of fathers and mothers separated, etc. What
surveillance can such parents exercise over their children, and if they
judge it proper to give a reprimand, or give good advice, what
authority could such observations have in their mouths?

“Thus the depravity, the indifference, the necessitous position of many
people of the last class provoke, or do not or cannot prevent, the
corruption of the children; we may say in general with regard to a good
number of prostitutes, what observation continually teaches us of
criminals, that they have for the most part an ignoble origin.” [384]

In the third place, we must name as a cause of the demoralization in
youth bad housing conditions. One of the most pronounced
characteristics of the child is his propensity to imitate. Hence it
follows that the fact that a whole family must live and sleep in one or
two rooms has the most harmful consequences for the sexual morality of
the children. Sexual life has no longer any secrets for the child of
the poor classes at an age at which this life is still a thing unknown
to the children of the well-to-do classes.

I will give here some figures to show how small the dwellings of this
class are. According to an investigation made in Berlin in 1895 there
were 4,718 dwellings without fireplaces, and occupied by 13,700
persons; more than 200,000 dwellings consisted of a single room with a
fireplace, and 22,160 of these were occupied by more than 6 persons.
There was the following percentage of “overcrowding” (in official
statistics this means more than 6 persons in one room with fireplace,
and more than 8 persons in two rooms with fireplace, or in one room
with kitchen attached): in Königsberg 10.6; in Halle 10.3; in Breslau
9.9; in Lübeck 8.75; in Görlitz 6.91; in Leipzig 7.85; in Altona 7.62;
in Munich, 4.41; in Kiel 4.46; in Mannheim 11.8. In 1890 there were
living in overcrowded dwellings the following number of persons to the
1,000: in Berlin 784; in Munich 533; in Breslau 754. [385]

According to the investigation made in 1890 there were in Vienna 23,921
dwellings consisting of a single room, with 64,621 occupants, and
103,433 dwellings of two rooms, with 411,314 occupants. These two
groups include 44% of the dwellings and 35% of the population.
Professor von Philippovich, in the article from which these data have
been taken, shows that in the districts inhabited by the Viennese
working-men, Ottakring, Meidling, and Favoriten, 29.3%, 30.8%, and
31.26% respectively of the dwellings of one or two rooms were
“overcrowded” (i.e. 3 to 5 persons in a room). [386]

The 1899 census of the Netherlands gave the following results: There
were 307,937 dwellings consisting of one inhabited room each, and
occupied by 1,172,014 persons (22.7% of the population); and there were
334,355 dwellings consisting of two rooms each (including kitchens,
alcoves, and covered passages), occupied by 1,497,353 persons (29% of
the population). [387]

The detailed statement shows the situation still better. There were
45,641 dwellings of only one room, with 4 persons in each; 62,548
dwellings of more than one room with 5 or 6 persons; 41,877 dwellings
of only one room, occupied by 6 or more persons; 45,363 dwellings of 2
rooms which were occupied by 3 or 4 persons; 20,582 dwellings of two
rooms with from 4 to 6; and 706 dwellings of two rooms with 6 occupants
or more. [388]

What is often lacking besides is space to place a sufficient number of
beds, or even the means of procuring them. In a great number of cases
children of different sexes must sleep together in one bed, or even
with adults. It also often happens that the inhabitants of these
already insufficient dwellings are obliged to take night-lodgers. There
are the following percentages of dwellings with lodgers: in Leipzig,
17.5; in Breslau, 12.5; and in Berlin, 15.8. [389] In Vienna 6.4% of
the population are night-lodgers, and in Berlin 6.1% [390].

It goes without saying that among these persons lodging together there
are some who are demoralized and dangerous to children. In his work,
“Verbrechen und Prostitution”, P. Hirsch depicts these dangers as
follows: “Think in how narrow a space an entire family is penned up
together, so that at times a separation of the sexes is scarcely
possible, at a time when the sexual instinct of the growing children is
already beginning to develop. The children unhappily only too often are
present at the most intimate occurrences and early lose all feeling of
shame. How can decency and good morals be learned by children whose
parents are obliged to take prostitutes as lodgers? Who shall protect
these unfortunates from moral contamination? Often a word will be
spoken in their presence, or an occurrence take place, which they are
not yet, perhaps, able to understand. But the childish nature is
receptive to such impressions, and what happens in their presence falls
upon fruitful soil, and what has remained fixed in their memory from
earliest youth, will, if later their sensuality is once aroused, bear
terrible fruit. We are astonished when we hear a twelve or thirteen
year old girl use language which we are accustomed to hear only from
prostitutes who have followed their trade for years; we are astonished
at the sophistication of persons still quite young, and are inclined at
once to pass an unfavorable judgment upon them. Truly our judgment
would be quite different, we should have sympathy with them, and should
be made to reflect, if we came to know the holes in which these poor
creatures passed their childhood.” [391]

As a cause of the demoralization of young girls we must note, finally,
child labor. In the first place there are children who are sent to sell
flowers, matches, etc., and this causes them to be neglected and to
frequent bad company. With regard to this Hirsch says: “One has only to
get into conversation with the children who sell flowers, matches, and
the like on the streets of the great cities in the evening, or to
overhear their talk, to be astonished at their sophistication. One
would hardly believe with what shamelessness such boys speak of sexual
matters with growing girls in the same situation, without blushing and
quite as a matter of course, since they have been accustomed to it from
earliest childhood. It is no wonder that from these circles a
considerable contingent is furnished to the ranks of prostitution and
crime....” [392]

A second cause is work in factories, by which girls are brought into
contact with adults who, from their often coarse manners and language,
and their lack of moral sentiments, corrupt these children for their
whole lives. After having spoken of the other dangers which threaten
the morality of children, Lecour says: “If she has escaped these
dangers the child, placed too young as an apprentice, will meet other
perils. There will be the contact with girls who are older and already
corrupted, and workmen who respect neither youth nor innocence, who
boast of debauchery, propagate immorality, and dishonor the daughters
of their comrades. There will be, perhaps, the impure domination of the
proprietor or foreman.” [393]

Let us now look at the influences which demoralize adult women. In the
first place we must speak of the influence of profession. The following
figures serve to show which are the professions from which prostitutes
are recruited most: [394]


Berlin, 1855.

   Factory-workers                 }                     73   }
   Seamstresses, laundry-workers   }   Industrial        16   }   61 %
   Day-laborers                    }   workers           23   }
   Workers at home                 }                     32   }
   Domestics                                             22        9 ,,
   Without declared profession                           70       30 ,,
                                                        ---      ------
                                                        236      100 ,,


1873.

   Factory workers                 }   Industrial     355   }
   Workers at home and saleswomen  }   workers        936   }   64.3 %
   Caretakers of stores            }                  139   }
   Domestics                                          794       35.7 ,,
                                                    -----      --------
                                                    2,224      100.0 ,,


1898.

       Workwomen, seamstresses, and saleswomen   66        43.4 %
       Domestics                                 78        51.3 ,,
       With their parents                         7   }     5.3 ,,
       Nurses of children                         1   }
                                                          --------
                                                          100.0 ,,


In the “Reports of the Select Committee, etc.” we find the following:
[395]


England.

   Domestics                                         1,589    60.7 %
   Seamstresses, dressmakers, and other industrial
   professions                                         967    36.9 ,,
   Barmaids                                             64     2.4 ,,
                                                     -----   --------
                                                     2,620   100.0 ,,


Breslau, 1901. [396]

          Domestics                                72    38 %
          Factory workers                          37    20 ,,
          Seamstresses                             28    15 ,,
          Saleswomen                               14     7 ,,
          Dressmakers                               8     4 ,,
          Barmaids, flower-girls, hairdressers     13     7 ,,
          Dancers                                   4     2 ,,
          Without profession and living at home    14     7 ,,
                                                  ---   ------
                                                  190   100 ,,


In Parent-Duchatelet’s “La Prostitution à Paris” figures are found
showing that domestic servants, in proportion to their number, furnish
the largest contingent of prostitutes, and that working-women who try
to provide for their needs with the needle furnish also a very great
proportion. [397] Dr. Jeannel shows that in 1859, out of 298
prostitutes registered in Bordeaux, 40% had been domestics, and 37%
workwomen who had tried to live by sewing. [398] Out of a total of
6,842 clandestine prostitutes in Paris (from 1878 to 1887) Dr. Commenge
found that 2,681 (39.18%) had been domestics, and 1,326 (19%)
seamstresses. [399]

Dr. Baumgarten gives the following table of percentages for 1,721
prostitutes:


Vienna.

                    Servants                   58.00
                    Working by the day         16.00
                    Cashiers                   14.00
                    Factory workers             5.50
                    Office employees            0.38
                    Children’s nurses           0.36
                    Singers                     0.28
                    Hairdressers and models     5.48
                                              ------
                                              100.00


Dr. Fiaux gives the following figures: [400]


Russia.

    Servants                                              45.0 %
    Seamstresses                                           8.4 ,,
    Factory workers                                        3.7 ,,
    Laundresses                                            1.4 ,,
    Governesses and nurses                                 1.3 ,,
    Merchants, bakers, and others                          1.3 ,,
    Cigar-sellers                                          0.7 ,,
    Singers, circus-performers, and other artists          0.3 ,,
    Practicing different trades and professions            2.7 ,,
    Kept mistresses                                        2.0 ,,
    Without fixed profession                               6.4 ,,
    Living upon the labor of their husbands                1.7 ,,
    Living in their family, or with their parents more
      or less remote                                      22.3 ,,


These statistics show that a quite considerable number of the
prostitutes have been workwomen in factories. (In Russia manufacturing
is very little developed—hence the low figures there.) We may accept it
as indisputable that this labor has in general very disadvantageous
consequences for the morality of the workwomen.

In his work, “The Condition of the Working Class in England”, Engels
depicts these consequences in the following terms: “The collecting of
persons of both sexes and all ages in a single workroom, the inevitable
contact, the crowding into a small space of people to whom neither
mental nor moral education has been given, is not calculated for the
favorable development of the female character. The manufacturer, if he
pays any attention to the matter at all, can interfere only when
something scandalous actually occurs; the permanent, less conspicuous
influence of persons of dissolute character, upon the more moral, and
especially upon the younger ones, he cannot ascertain and consequently
cannot prevent. The language used in the workshops was characterized by
many witnesses in the report of 1833 as ‘indecent’, ‘bad’, ‘filthy’,
etc. (Cowell, evid., pp. 35, 37, and in many other places). It is the
same process upon a small scale which we have already witnessed upon a
great one in the great cities. The centralization of population has the
same influence upon the same persons, whether it affects them in a
great city or in a small factory. The smaller the mill, the closer the
packing, and the more unavoidable the contact; and the consequences are
not wanting. A witness in Leicester says that he would rather let his
daughter beg than have her go into a factory; that they are perfect
gates of hell; that most of the prostitutes of the town had the mills
to thank for their present condition (Power, evid., p. 8). Another in
Manchester ‘did not hesitate to assert that three-fourths of the young
factory employees of from 14 to 20 years of age were unchaste’ (Cowell,
evid., p. 57). Commissioner Cowell expresses it as his opinion, that
the morality of the factory operatives is somewhat below the average of
the working class in general (p. 82). And Dr. Hawkins says (Rept. p.
4), ‘An estimate of sexual morality cannot readily be reduced to
figures, but if I may trust my own observations and the general opinion
of those with whom I have spoken, as well as the whole tenor of the
testimony furnished me, the aspect of the influence of factory life
upon the morality of the youthful female population is most
depressing.’” [401]

And then it happens at times that the proprietors or their foremen by
abusing their power force the working-girls who please them to yield to
their desires. Engels says of this: “It is a matter of course that
factory-servitude, like any other, and to an even greater degree,
confers the ‘jus primæ noctis’ upon the master. In this respect also
the employer is sovereign over the persons and charms of his employees.
The threat of dismissal suffices to overcome all resistance in nine
cases out of ten, if not in ninety-nine cases out of a hundred, in
girls who, in any case have no strong inducements to chastity. If the
master is mean enough, and the official report mentions several such
cases, his mill is also his harem; and the fact that not all
manufacturers use their power, does not in the least change the
position of the girls. In the beginning of the manufacturing industry,
when most of the employers were upstarts without education or
consideration for the social hypocrisy, they let nothing interfere with
the exercise of their vested rights.” [402]

Besides factory workers domestics form a very considerable percentage
of the prostitutes. As the Berlin statistics cited above show the
percentage of workers has diminished and that of domestics has
increased. According to Dr. Blaschko the cause of the diminution of the
percentage of factory workers is to be found not only in the fact that,
the year 1898 being very prosperous, poverty did not come in as an
important factor in the same measure as formerly, but also in the
raising of the intellectual and moral plane of the Berlin
working-women. It is impossible to speak of a similar raising of the
plane of the domestics. The nature of their occupations prevents their
forming associations; they are therefore deprived of the moral effect
of the trades union. [403] The causes of the importance of the
contingent furnished to prostitution by the domestics are of different
kinds. Besides the reason I have just mentioned, the fact is to be
noted that it is not from among the most intelligent and best of the
working classes that domestic servants are ordinarily drawn. For these
prefer the less dependent position of working-woman to that of
domestic. In the second place there is the influence of the occupation
itself. (There are still others, of which I shall speak later.)

It is easy to understand how the occupation of domestic has a
demoralizing influence. Not only do young girls, often ignorant and
without education, come to live in surroundings of a sort to pervert
them, but there is also their dependence upon people who only demand
that their work shall be well done, the lack of civilizing influences,
and the isolation that deprives them of contact with their fellows, all
of which lowers their moral plane. [404]

Aside from the two groups cited there are still other occupations which
may exercise a demoralizing influence, such as that of barmaid, etc.
[405]

Before closing our observations upon demoralizing environment as a
cause of prostitution, we must fix our attention upon the evil
influences to which many women are exposed, those, that is, who must
provide for their own needs and do not live at home. The smallness of
their wages does not permit them to rent a room by themselves but they
are obliged to content themselves with a bed simply. This brings at
once great moral disadvantages. But further, this arrangement drives
the persons in question into the street when not at work, since often
the landlords do not allow them in the house except during the night.
The harmful consequences of this are sufficiently obvious. [406]

b. The maternity of girls and concubinage are among the causes of
prostitution. Parent-Duchatelet gives the following figures: [407]


Paris.

Having come from the provinces to conceal themselves in
  Paris and to find resources there                            280
Brought to Paris and abandoned by soldiers, traveling
  salesmen, students, and other persons                        404
Domestics seduced by their masters and dismissed by them       289
Simple concubines during a longer or shorter period who
  have lost their lovers, and do not know what else to do    1,425
                                                             -----
            Total                                            2,398

46% of a total of 5,183.


In the “Reports of the Select Committee”, etc. we find given as cause
of prostitution: [408]


England.

            Concubines abandoned by their lovers        360
            Girls seduced under promise of marriage     806
                                                      -----
                                                      1,166

            37.9% of a total of 3,076.


In his “Minderjährige Verbrecher” L. Ferriani gives the following:
[409]


Italy.

                  Seduction by a lover          1,653
                     ,,     ,, employer           927
                                                -----
                                                2,580

                  24.7% of a total of 10,422.


The statistics cited show, then, that the cause named occupies a quite
considerable place in the etiology of prostitution. This cause is
entirely a consequence of the existing social conditions, which
maintain the dependent position of woman, and of marriage, which brings
it about that every woman living with a man as with a husband is
despised, even when the union is due to inclination, and that life is
made very hard for her, especially if a child is born of the union.
However, it must be added, that this applies especially to the women of
the middle classes, and that “free love” and the child that is the
fruit of it, are not at all so despised among the proletariat, for, as
we have seen above, the bases of the present legal monogamy have not so
great an importance there. [410]

However this cause of prostitution only makes itself felt when the
woman to whom it applies is also deprived of all pecuniary means. And
so we come to the third category in the etiology of prostitution.

c. Poverty. As the statistics already cited have shown, almost all
prostitutes spring from the classes without fortune, and the great
majority of them have been at first working-women or domestics, and
consequently have belonged to families without fortune. If such women,
for any reason whatever, cannot find work, they are thrown into
poverty. As this happens constantly in society, poor women find
themselves forced into prostitution. The facts are there to prove it.
In treating of the etiology of prostitution Parent-Duchatelet gives the
following figures: [411]


Paris.

Excess of poverty, absolute destitution                       1,441
Loss of father and mother; expulsion from home; complete
  desertion                                                   1,255
To support aged and infirm parents                               37
Eldest of the family having neither father nor mother,
  to support brothers and sisters, and sometimes nieces
  and nephews                                                    29
Widows and deserted wives, to raise a large family               23
                                                              -----
                                                              2,785

53% of a total of 5,183.


The author says among other things: “Poverty, often pushed to the most
frightful extreme, is still one of the most active causes of
prostitution. How many girls abandoned by their families, without
parents, without friends, unable to find refuge anywhere, are obliged
to have recourse to prostitution in order not to die of hunger! One of
these unfortunates, still susceptible to feelings of honor, strove to
the last extremity before taking up a part which she regarded as
extreme, and when she came to register herself it was shown that she
had not eaten anything for three days.” [412]

“One would hardly believe that the career of prostitution has been
embraced by certain women as a means of fulfilling their duty as
daughter or mother; yet nothing is more true. It is not unusual to see
married women who have lost their husbands or been deserted by them,
become prostitutes with the sole purpose of not leaving a numerous
family to die of hunger. It is still more common to find young girls
who, not earning by their labor enough to provide for the wants of
their aged and infirm parents, ply the trade of prostitute in the
evening to make up what is lacking. I have found the marks peculiar to
these two classes of prostitutes too often not to be convinced that
they are more numerous in Paris than one would believe.” [413]

In the “Reports of the Select Committee, etc.”, which I have already
quoted several times, are found the following figures: [414]


England.

        To provide for the needs of her mother           11
        ,,   ,,    ,,  ,,   ,,   ,, ,,  idle husbands    35
        As a consequence of poverty or lack of work     164
                                                        ---
                                                        210

        6.8% of a total of 3,076.


(We must take into consideration the fact that in the case of many of
the 37.9% who are put down in this same set of tables as seduced,
poverty was a contributory cause.)

Ferriani gives the following table: [415]


Italy.

Deserted by husband, parents, or other members of the family        794
Death of husband, parents, or other persons contributing to
their support, or other cause of poverty                          2,139
To provide for the wants of children, parents, or other sick or
needy members of the family                                         393
                                                                  -----
                                                                  3,326

31.9% of a total of 10,422.


Dr. Blaschko shows that the forced idleness among garment makers during
some months of each year causes an increase of prostitution. [416]

As we have seen in the first part of this work, it has been proved at
various times that crime against property increases or diminishes
according as the economic situation is favorable or unfavorable. If
poverty is one of the causes of prostitution it must follow that the
number of prostitutes will vary at the same times as the general
condition. Statistics prove that this is what does actually happen.
However, we need only take into consideration the figures for
registered prostitutes; if we had at our disposal the figures for
clandestine prostitution they would naturally show still greater
modifications.


        Berlin. [417]

        =====+=============+=============
             | Number of   | To 100,000
        Year.| Prostitutes |   of the
             | Registered. | Population.
        -----+-------------+-------------
        1869 |    1709     |     223
        1870 |    1606     |     203
        1871 |    1625     |     197
        1872 |    1701     |     198
        1873 |    1742     |     195
        1874 |    1956     |     210
        1875 |    2241     |     232
        1876 |    2386     |     242
        1877 |    2547     |     248
        1878 |    2767     |     262
        1879 |    3033     |     277
        1880 |    3186     |     284
        1881 |    3465     |     298
        1882 |    3900     |     326
        1883 |    3769     |     306
        1884 |    3724     |     293
        1885 |    3598     |     273
        1886 |    3000     |     230
        1887 |    3063     |     216
        1888 |    3392     |     231
        1889 |    3703     |     244
        1890 |    4039     |     255
        1891 |    4364     |     273
        1892 |    4663     |     288
        1893 |    4794     |     292
        =====+=============+=============


Leaving aside the abnormal years, 1870 and 1871, we perceive that the
prosperous years 1872 and 1873 give very low figures. After this period
times become worse and worse, while the number of prostitutes sustains
a considerable increase. From the year 1882 economic conditions began
to improve, and the figures for prostitution correspondingly fell, to
rise again very noticeably during the unfavorable years 1889 to 1892.

In his work “Statistik der gerichtlichen Polizei im Königreiche Bayern
und in einigen anderen Ländern”, Dr. Mayr also gives convincing proofs
of the parallelism between the changes in the economic situation and
prostitution. [418]

However it is not only forced unemployment leading to great poverty
that is one of the causes of prostitution; we must also consider as
such the fact that the wages paid to women are often so small that it
is impossible for them to pay even their necessary expenses, and are
thus obliged to find some supplementary source of income.

In his work already quoted, “Die wirthschaftlichen Ursachen der
Prostitution”, Pappritz fixes the minimum that a working woman in
Berlin must have for her strictly necessary expenses at 600 marks a
year. Most of the women working in factories generally earn but 500
marks. The average earnings in 1897 were 457 for dressmakers, and 354
for those who made the button-holes (hand labor). And yet the wages
paid in Berlin were not the lowest—the average for all Germany was 322
marks. [419]

It will not be very difficult to quote several authors who, in treating
of this subject as regards Germany, have expressed themselves in the
same way. But I must be brief, and hence shall content myself with
citing a passage from Dr. Frankenstein’s “Die Lage der Arbeiterinnen in
den deutschen Grossstädten”, in which he sums up the result of his
studies upon this subject: “A very great proportion of the
working-women of our great cities receive wages that are not sufficient
to provide the most indispensable necessities of life, and find
themselves for this cause in the dilemma either of seeking a
supplementary trade in prostitution, or of falling into the unavoidable
consequences of bodily and spiritual destruction.” [420]

It is evident that the same thing is true of all the countries where
capitalism reigns. Here is what Faucher, for example, says in his
“Études sur l’Angleterre”: “Work with the needle is so poorly paid in
London that the young persons who give themselves up to it earn only
three or four shillings a week, working sixteen or eighteen hours a
day. The wages of a fancy needle worker, for a hard day, are from 50 to
60 centimes, while linen workers generally get 30 centimes for
stitching a shirt. Nothing more frightful could be imagined than the
existence of these poor girls. They must get up at four or five o’clock
in the morning, at all seasons of the year, to go to work, or to
receive the orders of the merchants. They work without relaxation until
midnight in small rooms, where they are crowded together by fives and
sixes for economy in the use of fuel and light. If they are admitted to
a dressmaker’s or linen draper’s establishment, they are ill-fed, and
under pretext of pressure of business are kept at their task day and
night, with only four or five hours of sleep, which are further
regularly limited on Saturday. This sedentary life and constant
confinement ages them before their time, when phthisis spares them. Is
it to be wondered at if some, frightened and disheartened at finding
the way of virtue so hard, hold out their arms to prostitution?” [421]

Against these long, hard days and small wages are to be set the easy
life and often quite considerable returns—at least in the beginning of
their career—which prostitutes enjoy. Moreau-Christophe in his “Du
Problème de la Misère” says that in London there are prostitutes who
earn $100 to $150 a week, and that the average earnings are $10 a week.
[422]



To conclude I wish to call attention to the opinion of
Parent-Duchatelet concerning this state of things in Paris. He says:
“Of all the causes of prostitution, particularly in Paris, and probably
in the other large cities, there is none more active than the lack of
work, and the poverty inevitably consequent upon insufficient wages.
What do our dressmakers, seamstresses, menders, and in general all
those who work with the needle, earn? If we compare the wages of the
most capable of them with what those of only moderate abilities can
make, we shall see that it is not possible for these last to procure
the mere necessaries of life. And if we then compare the price of their
labor with that of their dishonor we shall not be surprised that so
great a number fall into a life of shame made all but inevitable.”
[423]

Not only does poverty, taken in the sense of the lack of the actual
necessaries of life, act as a cause of prostitution, but also that
relative poverty which prevents women from enjoying luxuries which seem
necessities, like jewelry and fine clothes. With these same women
laziness also plays a part.

Now the general opinion with regard to these factors is that they
belong exclusively to the individual nature, that they are innate to
some women, and that they consequently have nothing to do with the
social environment. In my opinion this is entirely erroneous. Mankind
are born with certain needs. The non-satisfaction of these needs causes
death or the wasting away of the organism. These needs are what we call
the strict necessities. All the other wants are awakened by the
environment: that is to say, each possesses them in germ, but they are
latent as long as the surroundings do not develop them. For example, no
one would suffer from abstaining from tobacco if he did not see someone
smoking; no woman would want expensive clothes if others did not wear
them; etc. The desire to dress expensively, to wear jewelry, etc., is
not at all, then, an individual quality of certain working-women; the
germ of this want is innate in each individual, without any exception
though in different degrees. The present order of society, by
permitting certain women to spend immense sums for senseless luxury,
awakens in others the desire to imitate them as far as possible. Since
these last have not the means necessary to shine, they seek them where
they may find them, and as there is only the way of prostitution, many
follow it. We may add to this that a great number of men use their
money and their distinguished manners to decide those who hesitate.
This is, therefore, also one of the reasons why the ranks of
prostitution are so often recruited from among dressmakers and
domestics, i.e. from among those who come into direct contact with the
luxury of others. [424] Another cause which makes women desire
expensive and useless things is their low degree of culture, which
shows them nothing more preferable than the possession of luxury. And
where women who have all the leisure and the means necessary to busy
themselves with more serious matters set the example of frivolity, we
ought not to be surprised that those without the same advantages try to
follow their example.

The same is true of idleness. If each person who is capable of it would
do a certain amount of work, any normal individual would be ashamed to
pass the day doing nothing. But the fact that there are women who are
esteemed though they remain idle, awakens in other women, who are
obliged to work long and hard, the desire to do nothing also. As
prostitution opens to them the means of remaining unoccupied, they have
recourse to it to satisfy their desire.

The irony which comes out so often in the social life shows itself
here; the rich women who despise prostitutes never suspect that they
themselves are in part the cause of the fall of the others, and that
placed in the same poor surroundings they themselves would not act
differently. [425]

All those who rank the causes last cited among individual factors base
their opinion upon the thesis, equally strange and false, that there
are two kinds of persons: those who by birth are destined to command
and to enjoy, and those who are destined only to obey, to work, and not
to enjoy at all. Looked at from this point of view the person who
rejects these conditions constitutes an individual anomaly.

Perhaps it will be objected that without admitting the existence of
individual causes it will be impossible to explain why, though a great
number of women live under the conditions named, only a small fraction
prostitute themselves. Those who reason in this way commit the error
already spoken of, of thinking circumstances the same when they really
differ. There are no two persons who live under exactly the same
conditions, how much less thousands. To give one example only: all the
women who earn only the strict necessities of life have not been raised
in the same environment. Those who have grown up in favorable
surroundings have perhaps so great an aversion to prostitution that
they prefer a life of poverty to one of abundance procured by
prostitution. It is possible that these women would prefer suicide to
selling themselves, if they came to a state of complete destitution.
Secondly it is necessary that a woman should not be too ugly, or the
possibility of her earning her living by prostitution is excluded. No
one would claim, however, that feminine beauty is one of the causes of
prostitution; placed in another environment a woman would not
prostitute herself simply because of her beauty.

Although the reasons already given refute in great measure the supposed
objection, it must be confessed that the question is not thus entirely
answered. Just as all the beings of a certain species differ among
themselves, so these women differ naturally as to their innate
qualities. The one will have more decided and more numerous wants than
the other, she will be less laborious, more frivolous, etc. (qualities
which in themselves have nothing to do with prostitution), and, other
things being equal, she will be more exposed to the temptation to
become a prostitute. All this is perfectly true, but it has nothing to
do with the etiology of a social phenomenon like prostitution. For we
are here in the presence of two distinct problems; why, of two persons
placed in the same situation (supposing that to be possible), the one
is more in danger of becoming a prostitute than the other; and, second,
what are the causes of the social phenomenon which is called
prostitution? The answer to the first question must be that in part at
least it is because people differ as to the intensity of their
characteristics and of their appetites. The answer to the second is the
social conditions.

When two persons of different height are fording a river, and the
shorter steps into a hole and is drowned, should we have the right to
say that the difference between the height of persons is one of the
reasons why people are drowned? I think not. The only reason why there
are people who are drowned is that a man cannot live in water—which in
no way excludes the fact that a short person runs more danger of
drowning than a tall one.

Now as to prostitution—the atmosphere in which certain women live is
the cause of their fall, which does not prevent its being true that
some of them run more risk than others. The truth of this assertion may
be proved by an observation of the facts. Among women who are not
prostitutes also there are more who are lazy, frivolous, etc. than
those who are not. And though the former have not prostituted
themselves, if they had lived in bad surroundings and in poverty they
would have run more risk than the latter. If all women were exactly
equal prostitution would be as general as it is now; only in this case
it would be in every case the environment which would decide what woman
became a prostitute, whereas in reality there are, alongside of the
environment, individual differences which determine which ones run more
risk than the others.

Those who believe that there are here individual causes at work always
take the point of view that society is not an organism but a collection
of individuals, and that consequently an examination of the individual
will suffice to explain social phenomena. It is by the study of
prostitution, for example, as a social phenomenon that we bring out the
fact that individual differences do not play any part in the etiology
of prostitution.

d. Among the causes of prostitution must not be forgotten the fact that
many persons have pecuniary interests in it. Without this many women
would never have become prostitutes or would not have remained such,
and the opportunity for a man to procure the services of a prostitute
would not be so good. Capital has settled down on this as upon every
place from which profits are to be drawn. The profession of the keeper
of a house of ill-fame being extremely lucrative, great sums have been
invested in it. In order to furnish the necessary material for these
capitalists an international commerce has been created, whose
ramifications extend over almost the whole world, and in which large
sums are employed, the “white-slave trade.” [426] Often before their
entrance into these houses the prostitutes have already plied their
trade, but many innocent girls become the dupes of the false promises
of these traffickers and are given over to the keepers of houses of
prostitution. In his “Der Mädchenhandel” Dr. Hatzig says: “The girls,
in so far as they do not give themselves up voluntarily as objects of
traffic, are generally enticed with illusory promises of a glittering
future.... Advantageous positions in foreign countries are as a rule
offered to them, while nothing is said of the unchaste object of the
business. To this especially is to be ascribed the enormous exportation
of Hungarian girls into Russia, to whom engagements as dancers in St.
Petersburg are promised. When the unhappy victims have once arrived at
their destination they would hardly venture to escape from the hands of
the slave-trader. In helpless case, deprived of the protection of
friends and country, they submit to their fate and are sold to houses
of prostitution.” [427]

Once fallen into the hands of the keeper of such an establishment it is
almost impossible for these women to free themselves. He holds them in
all sorts of ways. For example, he will exchange their clothes for
others not proper to wear in the street, and will charge them so high a
price that they are in his debt; often they do not understand the
language of the country; etc. Legally slavery is abolished, but in
reality it always exists for these women. [428]

e. The ignorance of a part of the women, a consequence of the
environment in which they were brought up, is also one of the causes of
prostitution, and no inconsiderable one. Dr. Richelot gives the
following figures: [429]


London (1837–1854).

==================================================+===========
              Prostitutes Arrested.               |
--------------------------------------------------+-----------
Not able to read or write                         |   34.98%
Able to read only or to read and write imperfectly|   61.29%
Able to read and write well                       |    3.51%
Having a higher education                         |     .22%
                                                  +-----------
                                                  |  100.00%
==================================================+===========


Manchester (1840–1855).

===================================================+===========
Unable to read or write                            |   51.61%
Able to read only, or to read and write imperfectly|   47.60%
Able to read and write well                        |     .78%
Having a higher education                          |     .01% (?)
                                                   +-----------
                                                   |  100.00%
===================================================+===========


In the “Reports of the Select Committee, etc.” the following table is
given: [430]


England.

==================================+========+======
Unable to read and write          | 1,213  |  40%
Able to read only                 |   464  |  15%
Able to read and write imperfectly| 1,016  |  33%
Able to read and write well       |   371  |  12%
                                  +--------+------
                                  | 3,064  | 100%
==================================+========+======


Parent-Duchatelet gives the following figures: [431]


Paris.

==========================+=======+======
Unable to sign their name | 2,503 |  56%
Able to sign, but badly   | 1,868 |  42%
Able to sign well         |   110 |   2%
--------------------------+-------+------
                          | 4,481 | 100%
==========================+=======+======


Dr. Commenge gives the following: [432]


Paris (1878–1887).

======================================+=======+=========
      Unregistered Prostitutes.       |       |
--------------------------------------+-------+---------
Able to read and write                | 4,297 |  68.12%
Able to read and sign their name      |   988 |  15.66%
Able to read but not to write or sign |    11 |   0.18%
Unable to read or write               | 1,012 |  16.04%
--------------------------------------+-------+---------
                                      | 6,308 | 100.00%
======================================+=======+=========


From an examination of the statistics given it is evident that the
number of illiterates is very large, however they may be decreasing in
number now that primary education for the children of the poorer
classes is becoming more and more general. Knowing how to read and
write, however, proves very little as to the culture of the individual.
The statistics only show the number of prostitutes who are totally
illiterate, and we must certainly count many of the others as well
among the ignorant.

It is clear that ignorance alone does not lead to prostitution. But it
is clear that many prostitutes would not have become such, or would not
have lent an ear to the flattering offers of good positions, etc., if
they had known what an abominable life awaited them.

Among the secondary causes of prostitution must certainly also be
classed:

f. Alcoholism. Not only have many women been seduced when they had
drunk too much, and so have become prostitutes, but the demoralization
which is the result of the constant abuse of alcohol may have the same
effect. [433]

g. Degeneracy. According to some physicians (among whom are Professors
Lombroso and Tarnowsky, to cite only the most famous) the cause of
prostitution is not to be found first in the environment, but in a
pathological (or atavistic) condition. These authors have examined a
certain number of prostitutes, and have drawn from this examination the
conclusion that the stigmata of degeneracy often found in them indicate
a state which is the cause of their misconduct; prostitution is in
large part kept up by born prostitutes. [434]

There is one objection to be made to such a manner of proceeding,
namely that we must in the very beginning give a precise definition of
the social phenomenon which is called prostitution. This definition,
which can perhaps be given only by the sociologist and not by the
biologist, will show us at the outset that it is very difficult to
represent anyone as born with a tendency to commit sexual acts for
economic reasons. So Professor Lombroso understands a totally different
thing by prostitution from what it really is. He says: “Sometimes in
the beginning marriage does not even exist and prostitution is the
general rule” [435] and as an example he cites that the Naïrs live in
complete promiscuity. According to Professor Lombroso, then, everywhere
that there is no marriage there is prostitution. In other words,
according to him all nature is one grand brothel, in which, aside from
the married women, all the females would be prostitutes! Truly
Professor Lombroso has some sociological views all his own.

These authors claim, then, that prostitutes often present stigmata of
degeneracy. An examination of the figures shows, however, that 63% of
all the prostitutes examined show almost no such stigmata. [436]

For 63% of them then degeneracy cannot be the cause, nor does it follow
that it is the cause in the remaining 37% of cases. For many women with
these stigmata are not found at all among the ranks of prostitution. To
bring out the real import of the researches in question we must put
beside them the results of an examination of non-prostitutes. It is for
this reason that I wish to call attention to the work of Dr. P. Näcke,
“Verbrechen und Wahnsinn beim Weibe”, in which the author arrives at
the result that only 3% of the normal women examined by him failed to
show signs of degeneracy. [437] It seems to me, then, that when we find
figures so low among normal women the thesis of Professor Lombroso is
not proved.

If his conclusion were true, prostitutes would be drawn from all
classes of society, for degeneracy is present in all classes. But, as
we have seen above, they are drawn almost exclusively from the poorer
classes. Professor Lombroso thinks he has refuted this argument (which
is enough to overthrow his whole theory) by saying: “The woman who,
coming from the lower classes, ends by becoming the inmate of a
brothel, in the upper classes becomes an incorrigible adultress....”
[438] Consequently according to Lombroso there is no difference between
a prostitute and an adultress. It is not necessary to combat such
singular ideas: they refute themselves.

Nevertheless the theory named is not without importance for the problem
of prostitution. The following quotation, taken from a recent study of
Dr. Bonhoeffer shows what its importance is: “We have no more right to
speak of prostitution as inborn than we should have to speak of a born
drinker. The disposition brought about through the defective psychical
condition is inborn. But whether a psychically defective female
individual will become a prostitute is in a certain sense dependent
upon chance and external conditions.” [439]

There are persons who are born with psychic defects. These persons
adapt themselves to their environment only with difficulty, and have a
smaller chance than others to succeed in our present society, where the
fundamental principle is the warfare of all against all. Hence they are
more likely to seek for means that others do not employ (prostitution,
for example). If the defect of a woman has relation especially to the
sexual sphere, so that she feels, for example, extraordinary sexual
desires, the danger of her becoming a prostitute is very great. [440]
Even when the environment in which such persons live is very favorable,
it is nevertheless certain that their actions will be different from
those of others, though it does not at all follow that they will
infallibly become prostitutes. It is certain that these morbid cases
are rare in general, and very rare among prostitutes. [441]
Parent-Duchatelet says: “Finally there are girls who give themselves up
to prostitution in consequence of a licentiousness which one can
explain only by the action of a mental disease ...; but in general
these Messalinas are rare; I have only found one opinion upon this
fact, and it has been abundantly confirmed by my own researches.” [442]

This theory, that the principal cause of prostitution is to be found in
innate psychic defectiveness, contains, as Dr. Blaschko says (in his
“Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”), “a small grain of truth in a
mass of exaggerations.” It is only a very small proportion of
prostitutes who have gone into the profession for this reason, and it
is certain that they would not have done so if circumstances had not
contributed to bring it about. [443]

We have now arrived at the end of our observations upon prostitution.
In our opinion it has been shown that it is partly the inevitable
complement of the existing legal monogamy, and partly the result of the
bad conditions under which many young girls grow up, the consequence of
the physical and mental misery in which the women of the proletariat
live, and the consequence also of the inferior position of woman in our
present society. When we make exception of a few cases where a certain
degeneracy enters in beside the effect of the unfavorable environment,
the prostitution of today is, then, the consequence of existing social
conditions, which, in their turn, spring from the economic system of
our time.

It may be objected that prostitution has presented itself under other
economic systems. I am not ignorant of this, but I know also that 3 × 4
= 12, and 2 × 6 = 12 also; that is to say that two different causes may
produce the same result. The prostitution of our day may be the
consequence of capitalism while that of earlier periods may have been
the consequence of the mode of production of those times. Further, an
examination of the epochs in which prostitution was a general
phenomenon (it never reached proportions as great as under capitalism)
[444] shows us that they did not differ much from our own in those
matters which concern the question in hand, namely, the inferior
position of woman, and the strong contrasts in fortunes.

Many authors who have taken up the question of prostitution declare
that it is as old as humanity itself. If we understand by prostitution
what it really is, and not what imagination makes it out to be, this
assertion is absolutely false. Prostitution is of very ancient date,
but it has not always existed. Westermarck, one of the authors best
qualified to pronounce an opinion upon this matter, says: “Prostitution
is rare among peoples living in a state of nature and unaffected by
foreign influence. It is contrary to a woman’s natural feelings as
involving a suppression of individual inclinations.” [445] I advise
those who, in spite of everything, wish still to maintain that
prostitution belongs to all time and all places, to investigate the
peoples among whom the matriarchate exists. If they are so unfamiliar
with sociology, let them look for prostitution in the country. They
will find none; prostitution exists only in the cities.








CHAPTER IV.

ALCOHOLISM. [446]


We understand by alcoholism the social phenomenon which consists of the
chronic abuse of alcoholic beverages. [447] Before touching upon the
etiology of this phenomenon we must decide the biological question, why
does a man consume alcohol? Always and everywhere it has been
established that the liking for narcotics is natural to man. Those who
believe that human nature is inclined to evil, and that the tendency to
excess is innate, find the solution of the problem very simple. They
reason as follows: “by alcohol this innate desire is satisfied; man is
inclined to excess,—ergo ... alcoholism.” Those who deny the evil
nature of man find here on the contrary the crux of the problem. For,
say they, the facts are there to prove that man has not always and
everywhere been intemperate; there must then be other causes than this
so-called sinful instinct.

Alcoholic beverages are consumed first, because they are agreeable to
the taste (at least some of them); second, and especially, because
aside from the taste they have the power of awaking agreeable
sensations. In his work “Der Alkoholismus” Dr. A. Grotjahn expresses
himself thus upon this point: “Narcotics act ... not primarily through
their agreeable taste, but influence directly the cerebral cortex and
awaken pleasurable sensations which are completely independent of the
activity of the senses or of pleasure-producing perceptions of the
outer world. There is no other means of producing pleasurable
sensations independent of the perceptions arising from the outer world,
and independent of the functions of the senses. Only in this way is it
to be explained that the need for the use of narcotics has attained so
wide a dissemination, and struck such deep roots when once mankind had
learned their use.” [448]

If alcohol is used regularly, then, to drive away disagreeable
sensations, the consumption must necessarily increase if the individual
wishes to attain the same psychical condition, for use continually
weakens the effect.

Here, as in the case of the etiology of other social phenomena, we must
treat the different causes of alcoholism separately, although it often
happens that a number combine to make a man alcoholic. We shall begin
with the causes which lead to alcoholism among the proletariat, for it
is in this class that the abuse of alcohol is most widespread and
produces the greatest ravages, first because the quality of the drinks
consumed is very bad, and secondly, because alcohol has more harmful
effects upon a badly nourished system.

a. There are occupations which, by their nature, lead the workmen who
follow them almost inevitably to the abuse of alcohol. Dr. Grotjahn
says: “The mental condition suffers when the temperature is too high or
too low, more than the capacity for work. The great discomfort while at
work may be removed by regulating the things which influence the
temperature (clothing, housing, heating, ventilation) or the
uncomfortable feelings may be blunted through copious draughts of
spirituous beverages. Hence the peculiar custom of taking alcohol
against great heat and great cold both, a thing which would be absurd
if alcohol worked specifically against the one extreme of temperature
or the other, and did not simply moderate the unpleasant sensations
produced by abnormal temperatures.” [449]

In the second place come the industries in which much powder or gas are
produced. To quote Dr. Grotjahn again: “The dust, which those working
in the open air have at times to endure, but which those who work in
closed rooms must almost always put up with, brings about, through
directly irritating the mucous membrane of the mouth, a highly annoying
thirst, which greatly induces the drinking of beer and brandy. We hear
it on all sides from workmen who outside of working hours are entirely
moderate or even abstemious, that the thirst which is excited by dust
is not nearly so well quenched by water or any ‘soft drink’ as by the
use of alcoholic beverages. Experience shows that in the callings which
are dust-producing there is a marked tendency to beer- and
brandy-drinking, and to a quick passage from moderate to immoderate use
of alcohol. This is the case with masons, carpenters, cabinet-makers,
but especially with grinders and quarry-men. The production of
irritating vapors in chemical works has a similar effect, but more
intense than that of ordinary dust.” [450]

In the third place there are the industries in which the workmen are
brought into direct contact with alcohol. Thus there are, for example,
the workmen in distilleries, [451] breweries, alcohol-warehouses, etc.;
then wine tasters, those who have to use alcohol in their business, and
finally those whose business takes them into establishments where
alcoholic drinks are sold, such as commercial travelers, and the
tenants of the establishments themselves. [452]

b. The too great length of the working-day. Workers who are forced to
work much longer than the human organism can stand are inclined to the
abuse of alcohol for two reasons. In the first place they find in it
the means of repairing temporarily the diminution of force caused by
great fatigue. Since alcohol gives only a temporary increase of
capacity, its continued use, and consequently its abuse, is therefore
almost inevitable. [453] This is the cause of the great development of
alcoholism among longshoremen, who often work for twenty-four hours or
even longer at a stretch.

In the second place immoderately prolonged labor produces a veritable
torture, which can be assuaged by large quantities of alcohol. Those
who have an interest in having the workman toil as long as possible
have always tried to prevent the shortening of the working-day by
claiming that it would increase the abuse of alcohol. The facts have
shown, however, that just the contrary is true. It has been proved that
it is not the shortening of the working-day, but its too great
extension that is one of the important causes of the abuse of alcohol.
So it is not by chance that the retailers of alcoholic beverages are
among the most zealous opponents of the shortening of the day. [454]

c. Bad and insufficient nourishment. There are many workers not
sufficiently nourished for the support of the body. For the purpose of
removing the feeling of discomfort arising from this they make great
use of alcoholic drinks. In these cases the nourishment is insufficient
both objectively (considered from a physiological point of view) and
subjectively (it does not satisfy the individual). Besides these there
are those who are able to procure a sufficient quality of food but lack
the means to vary the dishes and to replace foods that are bulky and
difficult to digest (potatoes, bread, cereals, etc.) by others less
bulky but more nutritious (especially meat). The persons who rely upon
persuasion in combating alcoholism, fix the attention upon the enormous
sums expended for spirituous drinks, and then figure how much bread,
how many beds, and other useful things could have been bought with this
money. All this is well and good, only in reasoning in this way they
make the capital error of representing a workman as a sort of machine
who says to himself: “I do not earn enough for the support of my
family—let us not buy alcohol, then, for it is harmful but rather eat
more potatoes. It is true that the discomfort will persist, but ... I
shall at least be nourished as well as possible.” However, since the
working-man is, no more than other men, a being who is content to
reason, but who feels, the calculations of these Utopists fall to the
ground.

Aside from the bad quality and insufficient quantity of the food, very
often the working family do not know how to give an agreeable taste to
the dishes they eat; and in families where the married woman herself is
employed away from home they often have to content themselves with cold
viands. In these cases spirituous drinks serve to counteract the
discomfort of the monotony and bulkiness of the food. Among a number of
proofs which may be brought in support of what has been said above, we
may cite the researches made by a Swiss inspector of factories, M.
Schuler, upon the relation between alcoholism and the food of the
working-classes. [455] In this investigation the following facts
appear.

In the cantons of Geneva, Vaud, and Neufchâtel the condition of the
people with regard to food is the best; a small consumption of potatoes
and a large consumption of meat. Little brandy is drunk there, the use
of alcohol being mainly limited to a large consumption of wine. The
workmen in the canton of Neufchâtel, except those employed in
watch-making, live in poor circumstances, eat many potatoes and also
drink much brandy.

In the cantons of Berne and Lucerne the living conditions of the
working class, and especially their food, are very bad; they consume
much grain and little meat, and in these districts they drink an
extraordinary quantity of brandy. In Aargau there is a great difference
between the condition of the industrial proletariat and that of the
proletariat engaged in agriculture. The food of the former is
insufficient, potatoes forming the main resource; furthermore the
working day is very long, and the consumption of brandy is
correspondingly great. The food of the agricultural laborers, on the
other hand, is much better (a greater consumption of meat and of milk)
and the consumption of brandy is much less than among the factory
hands. In the canton of Zürich the conditions are much the same as
those in Aargau.

All this shows clearly that it is the bad material condition of the
proletariat which causes alcoholism, for everywhere that the condition
of the industrial worker is raised above that of the agricultural
population (as, for example, among the skilled workmen at Winterthur),
the consumption of brandy is less among the factory people. Just so the
material condition of the small rural proprietors in the canton of Zug
is worse than that of the factory hands, and the consumption of brandy
there is considerable. [456]

d. Bad housing conditions. These conditions often bring it about that
the workman, returning from his work, goes to the dram-shop instead of
to his home. The dwelling is ordinarily small, too small for a large
family, without comfort or attractiveness, gloomy, and often cold in
winter, whereas in the dram-shop there is light, warmth, and gaiety;
comrades are there, and other topics of conversation than the perpetual
cares of life; and, above all, for a little money there may be procured
the means of forgetting for the moment the miseries of life. [457]

e. The uncertainty of existence and forced unemployment. The continual
difficulties, the anguish of not knowing what the future has in store,
produce a depression which may be driven away for the moment by the
consumption of alcohol. In the article by Richard Holst already cited,
is found the following answer given by a workman to the question: What
are the principal causes of alcoholism? “One of the principal factors
is the difficulty of earning a living for one’s family, and also—and
especially—care, the eternal care for the morrow, which fastens upon
the life of the working-man like a bur, and which, as work becomes more
rare, drives him to desperation. This is the principal cause of
alcoholism. Remove this care and men will drink much less alcohol, for
then the heart can open itself to joy instead of deadening itself, as
is at present almost a necessity. For many persons this deadening is
the only, although the fatal, means of ridding one’s self for a moment
of the terrible thought, ‘What will happen if I have the misfortune to
be thrown out of work, or fall sick?’” [458]

Unemployment leads often to alcoholism. “Idleness is the mother of all
the vices”, says an old adage; but among all the vices, that which
arises most directly from idleness is without doubt drunkenness. What
can a man do in the long hours when he has no work? The rich man,
educated, well brought up, finds the means of passing his time
agreeably; but the poor man has only the dram-shop, and is drawn
thither irresistibly. The first time he goes for a change from boredom;
then from habit, and finally from a necessity now become instinctive to
his organism, which at a given moment feels the need of something to
stimulate the nerves. It is in alcoholic drinks that he finds what he
lacks. [459]

f. Ignorance. The lack of other means of enjoyment. One of the lesser
causes of alcoholism, but important enough to be named, is ignorance.
There are a great many persons who think that the regular consumption
of great quantities of alcohol is not harmful, who even believe that
alcohol has nutritive value, and that consequently the consumption of
it is even useful. [460]

From another point of view, however, ignorance, the lack of culture,
emptiness of life, are very important causes if not the most important
causes of alcoholism. The desire for pleasure is innate in every man,
including the working-man, whose life is a hard one in every way. But
for him there are almost insurmountable difficulties in enjoying all
that is truly beautiful, all that nature, art, and science can offer to
man. This is due first, and principally, to material difficulties. In
our present society one can enjoy these things only with plenty of
money. The wages of the working-man are not enough for this. Often he
is too tired when the day is over to take up anything which requires
effort, and his abode is too small and too badly arranged for reading
or any other form of distraction. However, the principal reason why the
proletarian enjoys the products of civilization but little is that his
intelligence is not prepared for it. His capacities have not been
cultivated in this direction, for capitalism has developed in a great
number of people only the capacity for manual work to the detriment of
everything else. Dr. Augagneur, in his article already cited, has
expressed it as follows: “The true cause of alcoholism is entirely of
the intellectual and moral order; it is the insufficiency of cerebral
activity, the intellectual indigence and distress, the mental
unemployment.

“Every individual who, after the business of his calling is completed,
is incapable of busying himself with something else, is a fruitful soil
for alcoholism. How many, aside from their technical efficiency, are
unfitted to think, to comprehend, to explain anything whatever. When
the workman, after ten or twelve hours of mechanical work, leaves the
factory, he is confused, does not know how to kill the time that must
elapse before he goes to bed; he drinks....

“Sundays and holidays ordinary labor is suppressed, the laborer wanders
about the streets, objectless, adrift, embarrassed by his liberty, and
runs fatally aground upon the dram-shop. The days of rest are days of
drunkenness.

“Our society suffers from this intellectual inaction, which is the true
cause of alcoholism. Most men, as soon as their trade no longer makes
them work their arms and in some cases their brains, know not which way
to turn. Alcohol is their refuge, because it procures for the nervous
system sensations which take the place of the absent ideas.” [461]

It is for this reason that the abuse of alcohol is greatest among
unskilled laborers [462] and that it decreases everywhere that the
workmen begin to organize in unions and political parties, since these
lead to the amelioration of conditions, material, intellectual, and
moral. In other words, drinking diminishes wherever the proletariat is
animated by an ideal. And it is also among those workmen who foresee
the future of their class and know what there is to do, that the ranks
of total abstainers are mainly recruited. [463]

There are persons who maintain the thesis that poverty is not the
principal cause of alcoholism among the working classes. As a proof
they say that the laborers who earn the least (farm hands among others)
are not those who drink the most, and that an increase in wages often
brings about a higher consumption of alcohol. They are deceived,
however. They lose sight of the fact that most agricultural laborers
earn so little that they cannot consume alcohol regularly, that beside
the material poverty there is an intellectual poverty, and that a
slight amelioration of the one does not produce simultaneously a
diminution of the other. The abuse of alcohol has, on the contrary,
decreased regularly everywhere that the labor movement has brought
about a continuous amelioration of material and intellectual
conditions. [464]

To close these remarks upon alcoholism among the workers I will quote
the following from Engels in which the causes are concisely set forth:
“All possible temptations, all allurements combine to bring the workers
to drunkenness. Liquor is almost their only source of pleasure, and all
things conspire to make it accessible to them. The working-man comes
from his work tired, exhausted, finds his home comfortless, damp,
dirty, repulsive; he has urgent need of recreation, he must have
something to make work worth his trouble, to make the prospect of the
next day endurable. His unnerved, uncomfortable, hypochondriac state of
mind and body arising from his unhealthy condition, and especially from
indigestion, is aggravated beyond endurance by the general conditions
of his life, the uncertainty of his existence, his dependence upon
possible accidents and chances, and his inability to do anything
towards gaining an assured position. His enfeebled frame, weakened by
bad air and bad food, violently demands some external stimulus; his
social need can be gratified only in the public-house, he has
absolutely no other place where he can meet his friends. How can he be
expected to resist temptation? It is morally and physically inevitable
that, under such circumstances, a very large number of working-men
should fall into intemperance. And apart from the chiefly physical
influences which drive the working-man into drunkenness, there is the
example of the great mass, the neglected education, the impossibility
of protecting the young from temptation, in many cases the direct
influence of intemperate parents, who give their own children liquor,
the certainty of forgetting for an hour or two the wretchedness and
burden of life, and a hundred other circumstances so mighty that the
workers can, in truth, hardly be blamed for yielding to such
overwhelming pressure. Drunkenness has here ceased to be a vice for
which the vicious can be held responsible; it becomes a phenomenon, the
necessary, inevitable effect of certain conditions upon an object
possessed of no volition in relation to those conditions. They who have
degraded the working-man to a mere object have the responsibility to
bear.” [465]

As for the causes of alcoholism in the lower proletariat they are the
same as for the proletariat (if we except the two first named), only
they are much more intense. A very insufficient diet, frightful housing
conditions, the demoralization consequent upon inaction, ignorance, and
the absolute lack of any intellectual life have made of the man a brute
who can forget his misery only by drinking.

The same is true of prostitutes, among whom the abuse of alcohol is
very wide spread. Parent-Duchatelet says: “The taste of these women
(prostitutes) for strong drink may be considered to be general,
although in different degrees; they contract it early, and this taste
ends by plunging some into the last state of brutishness. All the
information that I have gathered proves that they began drinking only
to blunt their sensibilities; gradually they become accustomed to it,
and in a little while the habit becomes so strong that it resists any
return to virtue;...” [466]

Dr. Bonhoeffer says: “In many cases alcoholism is the result of the
manner of life of prostitutes.” [467]

The etiology of the abuse of alcohol in the well-to-do class is
principally as follows:

a. A part of the well-to-do class, those who live exclusively upon the
income from their invested capital, consider one of their occupations
to be the spending of a part of the surplus-value that they receive.
Among the means they make use of for this end is alcohol, which has
also the faculty of dissipating the ennui resulting from the emptiness
of their existence.

“Many persons, belonging for the most part to the well-to-do classes,
have no fixed occupation and feel the need of none. These persons do
not know what it is to love work for work’s sake. Having all that they
need to live upon they imagine that work exists only for those who have
to earn their bread, and they themselves are created for ‘dolce far
niente.’ Unfortunately the ‘far niente’ is not always sweet! Having
nothing to do, these individuals do not know how to use their time;
they are bored, they seek distractions and pleasures. Alcohol presents
itself to them as procuring the pleasure sought for, but as this
enjoyment is only momentary, they are forced to renew it and to prolong
it....” [468]

b. Another part of the bourgeoisie is composed of those who pass their
lives in the fierce combat of competition, who are bent under the
burden of material cares, and whose mind is occupied with a single
idea, that of getting money. This is why in these surroundings also
they frequently have recourse to alcohol to dissipate their vexations,
especially when things go badly.

Having treated of alcoholism among the idle portion of the bourgeoisie,
Kautsky says in the study quoted above: “Not all, of course, and
perhaps not even the majority, of the moneyed class are idlers. Many
work as long and hard as any working-man, even if the work they do is
often superfluous. But it is always one-sided nervous work. Muscular
exercise among the property-holding class has been constantly pushed
ever further into the background since the sixteenth century, and the
demands upon the nervous system have correspondingly increased. Besides
the continual struggle with the working-class, from whom the
surplus-value is taken, there is going on an equally uninterrupted
battle of the spoilers among themselves for a share of this
surplus-value. All these battles are carried on today by nervous, not
muscular, energy, and the contests become constantly more bitter, the
crises more tremendous, the battlefields more colossal, the forces
involved more incalculable.

“Thus the nerves of the bourgeoisie become wrecked through their
activity as well as through their idleness.... If part of the
bourgeoisie befuddle themselves out of wantonness, another part grasp
for stimulants or for means of benumbing themselves, alcohol, morphine,
cocaine, any thing to take away their feeling of sickness, to conquer
their pains, to make them forget their cares; and as it is with the
proletariat, so is it with the moneyed class, the power of resistance
to these agents declines.” [469]

Finally, we must notice some causes of alcoholism which influence the
whole population.

a. Imitation. This is reckoned among the important causes. In the first
place there are many children (for whom alcohol even in small
quantities is extremely harmful) who are accustomed to the use of
alcohol as a consequence of the example set by their families. Dr. R.
Frölich mentioned the following facts at the 8th International Congress
against Alcohol at Vienna: [470]

Out of 81,187 children from 6 to 14 years of age going to school in
Vienna, there were:


  49.5% who already drank beer   and 32.1% who drank beer regularly
  82.1% ,,    ,,     ,,   wine   ,,  11.2% ,,   ,,   wine    ,,
  94.2% ,,    ,,     ,,   brandy ,,   4.1% ,,   ,,   brandy  ,,


But imitation is also important among those who have attained their
full development. In the course of time certain circles have taken up
the habit of drinking, and any one who frequents these circles must do
the same under penalty of being looked down upon. However, I think that
the importance that abstainers give to imitation is exaggerated. The
number of those who are guilty of the abuse of alcohol from force of
example and nothing else is certainly not very great. The other factors
which have been at work at the same time to bring about this result are
not so obvious. Finally we must not forget that imitation is not an
independent factor; what does not exist cannot be imitated, and
consequently there must be other causes primarily responsible.

b. The climate. Although so much importance is not attached to climate
as formerly, it is nevertheless certain that a cold climate, especially
if damp, favors the consumption of alcohol, since this dissipates
temporarily the discomfort resulting from cold and humidity. It is for
this reason that the inhabitants of the northern countries (for
example, England, Denmark, and Holland) consume on the average greater
quantities of alcohol than southern countries (like Spain and Italy).
However the facts show that the social environment is a much more
important factor, and is apt to modify or overcome entirely the
influence of climate. In Sweden and Norway, for example, the
consumption per capita is smaller than in countries farther south, like
Denmark and Holland. The great changes which occur at different times
in the same country, where the climate remains a constant factor, are a
further proof of the truth of this. And notwithstanding the climate the
abuse of alcohol increases greatly in the southern countries in which
industrialism becomes more and more prevalent (like northern Italy).
[471]

c. Race. There are many persons who attribute much importance in the
etiology of alcoholism, as in other social phenomena, to the influence
of race. Where two nations differing racially have not the same
consumption of alcohol, they think they can explain the difference by
race. But in reasoning thus they forget that two nations may present
great differences in their manner of life, and that the greater or less
consumption of alcohol may be explained better by these than by race
(without counting that racial difference in the tendency to alcoholism
is still to be accounted for somehow). To cite an example; the peoples
of the Germanic race are more intemperate, than the peoples of the
Latin race (a fact already explained by the climate, and further
accounted for by the cheapness of wine); this difference it is said is
to be explained in part by race. And yet the use of brandy in northern
Italy increases with increasing industrialism, northern industrial
France gives a very high figure for brandy-consumption, and the
Belgians of the Latin race do not yield to their Germanic compatriots
in the use of alcohol. [472] The proverbial temperance of the Jews is
often attributed to their race, while we should ask whether this
temperance is not rather to be attributed to their manner of life,
which differs from that of other peoples. It is probable that the
Jewish industrial workers, for example, who have broken with the habits
of their coreligionists, have also become consumers of spirituous
beverages. As far as the diamond-cutters of Amsterdam are concerned
this fact is at least averred. [473] The tendency which is observed
among the Slavic peoples of becoming intoxicated periodically in an
extraordinary fashion, is attributed to race, but the same thing is
observed in other countries where wages are very low, thus preventing
regular drinking, and limiting the consumption of alcohol to paydays.
[474]

I believe that the influence of race upon alcoholism is enormously
exaggerated, which does not, however, imply that I deny its influence.
The slight expansion of the use of alcohol among the Mongolians (among
whom, it is to be added, this is replaced by other narcotics,
principally by opium) is to be explained in part perhaps, by race.

d. The psycho- and neuro-pathic condition of some persons enters into
the etiology of alcoholism in three ways. In the first place, the
regular use of small quantities of alcohol may, with the said persons,
result in alcoholism. Secondly, quantities of alcohol which have
results imperceptible in the normal man, may cause drunkenness in a
very neuropathic person. Thirdly, alcoholism is present as the
principal symptom with dipsomaniacs, and as a secondary symptom in the
case of persons suffering from mania, melancholia, or paralytic
dementia. [475]



After what we have said concerning the causes of the consumption of
alcohol, we must add something about the production of it. As is the
case with most articles, the production of alcohol is capitalistic,
that is to say, for the sake of profit. Consumption is only a condition
for attaining this end. If the profits could be greater without
production it would cease. [476] Aside from the producers, the state
also has a great interest in the consumption of alcohol, since it
derives considerable revenue from it.

The consequences of the fact that the production of alcohol is
capitalistic have a great social importance. To instance only some of
these:

First. The number of places where liquor may be drunk is very great.
The more there is consumed, the more profit there is for the producers
and for the retailers. As a consequence there is much advertising, and
many dram-shops, in which the wages are often paid and workmen hired.
These two things increase the profits of the dealer, but exercise an
indirect pressure upon the working-man to make him drink. [477]

Second. The constantly decreasing price of alcohol. As we have seen
above there is a tendency in the present economic system to lower the
price of commodities, since each producer tries to increase his
profits, if only temporarily, by seeking to improve the processes of
production. This is applicable to alcohol also.

Third. The adulteration of alcoholic drinks. Under the capitalistic
system the object of production is not to furnish as perfect a product
as possible, but to make as great profits as possible. Hence comes the
tendency among producers to adulterate their wares, to deliver goods of
poorer quality than they are supposed to be, for the purpose of gaining
greater profits. The adulteration so frequent with alcoholic beverages
has physical and psychical consequences most harmful to the consumers.
[478]



The exposition which I have just given of the etiology of alcoholism
points out the principal causes of it, and proves that they are to be
found in the last instance almost wholly in the present constitution of
society. It is possible that some one will interpose the objection that
this cannot be the case, that there must be, besides pathological
causes, individual causes, since it happens that among persons living
in the same environment some become alcoholics and others do not.

This last fact is incontestable, but it is partly to be explained by
the fact that, while there are persons who live in environments that
are very similar, there are no two individuals whose surroundings are
exactly the same. Take, for example, two workmen. The one may have
passed his youth in circles where they drink little or no alcohol, and
where it is pointed out to him that abstinence is very salutary, while
the other sees only examples of intemperance. It may be that here is
the explanation of the fact that the first has remained temperate,
while the second has not, although the two live in surroundings almost
alike.

But suppose that the environment is and has always been exactly the
same for a group of persons, we shall see then that the tendency toward
alcoholism is not the same for each individual. No one will be able to
dispute the fact, however, that it is the environment that is the cause
of the abuse of alcohol. Individual differences bring it about that one
man is more drawn to the use of alcohol than another, but circumstances
explain why the first has become alcoholic. These differences can never
explain why, at a certain period, the abuse of alcohol has, or has not,
become an almost universal phenomenon.

The proofs are plain. In examining, for example, a period like that in
which capitalism took its rise in England, as it is described by Engels
in his “Condition of the Working Class”, a period, that is to say, in
which the working class found itself in very disadvantageous material
and moral conditions, we see that the workers, with rare exceptions,
were consumers of alcohol, and largely abused it. Since that time
conditions have improved. The moral and material plane having been
raised, those whose tendency toward alcohol was less strong and who had
more marked innate moral qualities, ceased misusing alcohol. As
conditions improve still further those who are weaker follow little by
little the same road to temperance. This process may be observed going
on among unorganized workmen, with whom the tendency to drink is
generally great. As soon as they begin to organize, and in measure as
their organization is developed, we see that first the most
intelligent, etc., among them become temperate, and that little by
little these are followed by the others.

It is a biological fact that men always and everywhere present
qualitative differences. But this constant factor does not give an
explanation of the changes which society undergoes, and is not,
therefore, of great importance to sociology, which, while taking it
into account, has for its task the explanation of the changes in
question. And it is just those changes in the use of alcoholic
beverages which have taken place during the course of the centuries,
which show that the social environment is the principal cause of
alcoholism.

In ancient times alcoholism was unknown. It is true that among the
Israelites, for example, the abuse of alcohol at times occurred, but
the fact that no importance was attached to it proves that alcoholism
properly speaking did not exist. [479] Nor was it to be met with among
the ancient Greeks. At every meal, and at their reunions they drank
wine diluted; it is unnecessary to say that these “symposia” were not
looked down upon by the Greeks, but on the contrary were highly
regarded. “Greek opinion found nothing improper in intoxication, only a
certain self-control in drunkenness was held to be indispensable. Gross
and violent conduct was, like the drinking of unmixed wine, a custom of
the barbarians, and unworthy of a Greek.” [480] Nor was ancient Rome
any more acquainted with alcoholism, though among the Romans, coarse in
comparison with the Greeks and demoralized by their immense wealth, the
abuse of alcohol was often met with. But it was only the very small
group of the rich who were addicted to it. When the barbarians
annihilated the ancient world they were not capable of assimilating the
civilization of the peoples whom they had just subjugated, while they
adopted their pleasures, a thing which did not require so high a state
of development. This is the cause of the great abuse of alcohol among
the Germans. [481] The uncertainty of existence, and the miserable
conditions during the migrations of these peoples were favorable to
this abuse.

In the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries the abuse of alcohol had
reached a high degree of development among the rich. The cause of this
was the birth of capitalism, by which great wealth was accumulated in
the hands of a few without their having occasion to place a great part
of it as new capital. To this fact was joined a low degree of culture,
and it thus came about that the wealthy of the period spent enormous
sums for eating and drinking. [482]

The discovery in the middle of the sixteenth century of the
distillation of spirits from grain brought about a considerable
cheapening in the price of strong drink, which thus came within the
reach of the poor. (Arab physicians had long before discovered how to
extract brandy from wine, but this in the beginning was only used
medicinally.) The great poverty occasioned by the Thirty Years’ War
increased the use of liquor enormously, and the birth of the industrial
proletariat contributed equally to the same result. Mention is made for
the first time of the regular use of liquor to increase the amount of
work done, in 1550 among the Hungarian miners, the first category of
workmen who lived under conditions almost identical with those of the
modern industrial proletariat. With the continually increasing
development of capitalism King Alcohol began his triumphal march, which
has continued without any great obstacle to the present day. Alcoholism
has its deeper causes in the material intellectual and moral poverty
created by the economic system now in force. It is with reason that
Professor Gruber has said: “We cannot shut our eyes to the truth that
alcohol is not without basis in our present order of society. Without
it life would long ago have become unendurable for the suffering part
of the population.”








CHAPTER V.

MILITARISM.


We may be very brief upon the correlation of militarism and the present
economic system. This correlation is so clear that there are few
persons who deny it. The motives which, under all earlier modes of
production, have engendered wars are principally of an economic nature.
But besides these there have been at times others; but we have not to
enquire here what was in the last analysis their correlation with the
mode of production of that day. The relation between capitalism and war
is always so close that we can find in the economic life the direct
causes of the wars waged under the empire of capitalism.

As we have seen above in our exposition of the present economic system,
a part of the surplus-value that comes to the moneyed class is invested
as new capital. The continually increasing amount of capital does not
readily find investment in full in a country where capitalism is
already in force. This is why the moneyed class desires to invest a
part of the surplus-value in countries whither capitalism has not yet
penetrated. If the inhabitants of the country chosen as field of
operation are opposed to this, or if the same country is coveted by
other capitalistic powers, the resulting antagonism generally leads to
war.

In the second place, the producers can sell in their own country only a
part of the increasing quantity of their products; whence come their
efforts to find an outlet into other countries. But as capitalism
expands with increasing rapidity over the whole world, the difficulty
of finding a country in a position to buy, or to which capitalism has
not yet penetrated, becomes greater and greater. Encounters with other
capitalistic powers pursuing the same end are the inevitable
consequence.

It is upon the State that the task is imposed of finding new
territories where capital may be invested, or new outlets for goods
which do not find purchasers in the country where they are produced.
Beside the duty of the State to maintain a certain order in a society
confused and complicated through the nature of our economic life (civil
and criminal jurisprudence), there is its more important duty of
warding off other groups of competitors, or even at need attacking them
by force of arms.

But the army serves not only to act against the foreigner, it has
equally a domestic duty to fulfil. In the cases where the police cannot
maintain order the army reinforces them. The army must especially then
be active at the time of great strikes, when so-called free labor is to
be protected, that is when employers are trying to replace the striking
workmen with others who, in consequence of their poverty, or their lack
of organization, put their personal interests above those of their
comrades. Also it has its part to play in connection with great
political movements, like that to obtain universal suffrage, for
example.

Our present militarism is, therefore, a consequence of capitalism. The
double duty of the army proves it; for its function is to furnish the
bourgeoisie with the means of restraining the proletariat at home, and
of repulsing or attacking the forces of foreign countries.








BOOK II.

CRIMINALITY.


CHAPTER I.

GENERAL CONSIDERATIONS. [483]


A. DEFINITION OF CRIME. [484]

Crime belongs to the category of punishable acts. However, as the term
is applicable to only a part of such acts, it is necessary to be more
exact. The best way to do this, in my opinion, is to exclude
successively all the groups of acts which are punishable without being
crimes.

The first exclusion is in connection with the question, “Who is it that
punishes?” You cannot call that a crime against which one or several
individuals take action of their own motion, and where the social group
to which they belong does not move as such. In this case the word
“punish” is an improper term, for the act in question is one of
personal vengeance. Nor can you apply the name of crime to the act of a
group of persons forming a social entity, against an analogous group.
The reaction of the second group called forth by such act is not
properly punishment, but “blood-” or “group-vengeance”, and is in
reality nothing but a kind of war. [485]

The second exclusion concerns the nature of the punishment. Acts which
bring no other punishment than moral disapprobation are not reckoned as
crimes. They are not so called unless they are threatened with
something more severe than this.

The provisional result is, then, as follows: A crime is an act
committed within a group of persons that form a social unit, and whose
author is punished by the group (or a part of it) as such, or by organs
designated for this purpose, and this by a penalty whose nature is
considered to be more severe than that of moral disapprobation. This
definition, however, considers only the formal side of the conception
of crime; it says nothing as to its essence. It is proper, then, to
consider next the material side.

Crime is an act. [486] The question which presents itself first of all
is this: Is crime considered from a biological point of view an
abnormal act? The answer to this, which is of the highest importance
for the etiology of crime, must be negative. From a biological point of
view almost all crimes must be ranked as normal acts. The process which
takes place in the brain of the gendarme when he kills a poacher who
resists arrest is identical with that which takes place in the brain of
the poacher killing the gendarme who pursues him. It is only the social
environment which classes the second act rather than the first as a
crime. From the biological point of view homicide is not an abnormal
act. Sociology and history prove that men have always killed when they
thought it necessary. No one would maintain, for example, that those
who take part in a war are biologically abnormal.

The same observation may be applied to assaults. No anthropologist
would maintain that a policeman clubbing a mob of strikers was
performing a biologically abnormal act, or that the strikers were
abnormal because they did not choose to let themselves be maltreated
without defending themselves. It is only the social circumstances which
class this defense as a crime, and cause the action of the policeman to
be considered otherwise.

The same thing is true with regard to theft. For centuries it was
considered the right of the soldiers to pillage the country of the
conquered (and in colonial wars it is still done at times). Soldiers
are not, however, from this fact considered to be biologically abnormal
individuals. And yet there is no biological difference between these
acts and those of the ordinary thief; for anthropology does not ask
whether one steals on a large scale or on a small. [487]

Continuing our researches into the essence of crime, it is obvious that
it is an immoral act, and one of a serious character. Why do we find
any act immoral? This question cannot be answered by asking of each
individual separately, Why do you think such and such an act immoral?
Moral disapprobation is primarily a question of feeling; ordinarily we
take no account of why any given act is approved or disapproved by us.
Sociology alone can solve the problem by taking the acts considered as
immoral in relation with the social organization in which they take
place. And in treating the matter thus we observe that the acts called
immoral are those which are harmful to the interests of a group of
persons united by the same interests. Since the social structure is
changing continually, the ideas of what is immoral (and consequently of
what is or is not criminal) change with these modifications. [488]

Considered in this way from the material side, a crime is an
anti-social act, an act which is harmful in a considerable degree to
the interests of a certain group of persons. This definition is not yet
complete, however, for many acts of this nature are not crimes.

The best thing to do in order to find what is lacking in this
definition is to examine a concrete case. A short time ago there was
added to the Dutch penal code a new article threatening with a penal
term of some years the railroad employe who went out on a strike. The
proposal of this law, presented after a partial strike of the railroad
employes, aroused great indignation on the part of organized labor,
while the bourgeoisie in general regarded a strike as an immoral act
which would henceforth be followed by a severe penalty. Notwithstanding
the violent opposition on the part of the deputies of the labor party
the plan was accepted.

It is clear that what must be added to our definition (already
contained implicitly in the formal definition) is that the act must be
prejudicial to the interests of those who have the power at their
command. If, in the case cited above, the deputies of the proletariat
had had the majority the Dutch penal code would contain no penalties
against railroad employes on a strike. Power then is the necessary
condition for those who wish to class a certain act as a crime.

It follows that in every society which is divided into a ruling class
and a class ruled penal law has been principally constituted according
to the will of the former. We must at once add that the present legal
prescriptions are not always directed against the class of those ruled,
but that most of them are directed against acts that are prejudicial to
the interests of both classes equally (for example, homicide, rape,
etc.). These acts would without doubt continue to be considered
criminal if the power were to pass into the hands of those who are at
present the governed. However, in every existing penal code hardly any
act is punished if it does not injure the interests of the dominant
class as well as the other, and the law touching it protects only the
interests of the class dominated. The rare exceptions are explained by
the fact that the lower classes are not wholly without power.

Before closing our observations we must put the question, What is the
object of punishment? It seems to me that there are elements of
different nature in punishment as prescribed in our present penal
codes. To begin with the object of punishment is to be found in the
feelings of vengeance excited by the crime, for which satisfaction is
desired. But after this punishment has three things in view:

First, To put the criminal where he can do no further harm, either
permanently or for a certain period.

Second, To inspire the criminal, and other persons as well, with a fear
of committing crime.

Third, To reform the criminal as far as possible.

Most criminologists do not admit that punishment is still in great part
a manifestation of the desire for vengeance (although regulated).
Nevertheless it is indubitable that he who desires that some one shall
be punished solely because he has committed a misdeed, and without his
punishment’s being of any use to the criminal or to others, wishes
simply to satisfy his feelings of revenge. The most subtle theories
cannot refute this fact. Those who from the height of their knowledge
disdain the primitive peoples who practice the rule of “eye for eye,
tooth for tooth”, are nevertheless on the same plane in this matter, as
those they scorn. [489]

It is unnecessary to say that the minority that wishes to exclude all
idea of vengeance from the penal code, and sees in it only a means of
securing the safety of society, and, if possible, of reforming the
criminal, is at present still very small, so that the ideas of this
group are almost never realized in our present penalties. [490]

This is our conclusion, then, that a crime is an act committed within a
group of persons forming a social unit; that it prejudices the
interests of all, or of those of the group who are powerful; that, for
this reason, the author of the crime is punished by the group (or a
part of the group) as such or by specially ordained instruments, and
this by a penalty more severe than moral disapprobation.

To find the causes of crime we must, then, first solve the question:
“Why does an individual do acts injurious to the interests of those
with whom he forms a social unit?”, or in other words: “Why does a man
act egoistically?”




B. THE ORIGIN OF EGOISTIC ACTS IN GENERAL. [491]

What are the causes of egoistic acts? How does it happen that one man
does harm to another? The answers that have been given to this primeval
question may be divided into two groups. The first group attributes the
cause to the man himself, the second to his environment.

The great majority of persons who treat of this question settle it in
favor of innate egoism. They are of the opinion that man is egoistic by
nature and that environment can produce no change in this (this is
implied in the Christian doctrine of original sin). This opinion, in
order to be accepted as true, needs facts to prove that egoism has
always and everywhere been the same among men.

Others, among whom are most of the well-known sociologists, also
consider egoism as a fundamental trait of man, but are at the same time
of the opinion that little by little egoism has decreased, that
altruism has developed, and that this process continues. [492] For this
hypothesis to be correct it must be shown by the facts:

First. That the peoples of a much lower degree of social evolution than
ours show much more egoistic traits of character. [493]

Second. That the animals from whom man has descended are inveterate
egoists.

This theory is naturally of the highest importance for criminal
science, and it becomes still more so from the fact that, according to
Professor Lombroso, crime is a manifestation of atavism, that is, that
some individuals present anew traits of character belonging to their
very remote ancestors. The criminal would thus be a savage in our
present society. We must therefore examine to see whether the said
theory is correct.

We have only to consult one of the standard works on zoölogy to
perceive that there is no basis in this science to uphold the theory.
There are some animals that are complete egoists. Two harpies (South
American birds of prey) for example, upon meeting will attack each
other at once and will fight till one is conquered. Other animals, on
the contrary, show very altruistic traits of character. The following
extract from Darwin’s “Descent of Man”, is one of many proofs which
might be adduced: “Animals of many kinds are social;... We will confine
our attention to the higher social animals; and pass over insects,
although some of these are social, and aid one another in many
important ways. The most common mutual service in the higher animals is
to warn one another of danger by means of the united senses of all.
Every sportsman knows, as Dr. Jaeger remarks, how difficult it is to
approach animals in a herd or troop. Wild horses and cattle do not, I
believe, make any danger-signal; but the attitude of any one of them
who first discovers an enemy, warns the others. Rabbits stamp loudly on
the ground with their hind-feet as a signal; sheep and chamois do the
same with their fore-feet, uttering likewise a whistle. Many birds, and
some mammals, post sentinels, which in the case of seals are said
generally to be the females. The leader of a troop of monkeys acts as
the sentinel, and utters cries expressive both of danger and of safety.
Social animals perform many little services for each other: horses
nibble, and cows lick each other, on any spot which itches; monkeys
search each other for external parasites; and Brehm states that after a
troop of the Cercopithecus griseo-viridis has rushed through a thorny
brake, each monkey stretches itself on a branch, and another monkey
sitting by, ‘conscientiously’ examines its fur, and extracts every
thorn or burr.

“Animals also render more important services to one another: thus
wolves and some other beasts of prey hunt in packs, and aid one another
in attacking their victims. Pelicans fish in concert. The Hamádryas
baboons turn over stones to find insects, etc.; and when they come to a
large one, as many as can stand round, turn it over together and share
the booty. Social animals mutually defend each other. Bull bisons in
North America, when there is danger, drive the cows and calves to the
middle of the herd, whilst they defend the outside.... In Abyssinia,
Brehm encountered a great troop of baboons, who were crossing a valley:
some had already ascended the opposite mountain, and some were still in
the valley: the latter were attacked by the dogs, but the old males
immediately hurried down from the rocks, and with mouths widely opened
roared so fearfully, that the dogs quickly drew back. They were again
encouraged to the attack; but by this time all the baboons had
reascended the heights, excepted a young one, about six months old,
who, loudly calling for aid, climbed on a block of rock, and was
surrounded. Now one of the largest males, a true hero, came down again
from the mountain, slowly went to the young one, coaxed him, and
triumphantly led him away—the dogs being too much astonished to make an
attack. I cannot resist giving another scene which was witnessed by
this same naturalist; an eagle seized a young Cercopithecus, which, by
clinging to a branch, was not at once carried off; it cried loudly for
assistance, upon which the other members of the troop, with much
uproar, rushed to the rescue, surrounded the eagle, and pulled out so
many feathers, that he no longer thought of his prey, but only how to
escape....

“It is certain that associated animals have a feeling of love for each
other, which is not felt by non-social adult animals.” [494]

Later I shall treat of the question why some species of animals show
altruistic proclivities while others do not. At present I wish to
inquire whether peoples showing a much lower degree of civilization
than our own are much more egoistic.

Nansen, the celebrated explorer, in speaking of the Eskimos, among whom
he sojourned for some time, says: “The Greenlander is of all God’s
creatures gifted with the best disposition. Good-humor, peaceableness,
and evenness of temper are the most prominent features in his
character. He is eager to live on as good a footing as possible with
his fellow-men and therefore refrains from offending them and much more
from using coarse terms of abuse. He is very loth to contradict another
even should he be saying what he knows to be false. If he does so, he
takes care to word his remonstrance in the mildest possible form, and
it would be very hard indeed for him to say right out that the other
was lying. He is chary of telling other people truths that he thinks
will be unpleasant to them; in such cases he chooses the vaguest
expressions, even with reference to such indifferent things as wind and
weather. His peaceableness even goes so far that when anything is
stolen from him, which seldom happens, he does not as a rule reclaim it
even if he knows who has taken it. The result is that there is seldom
or never any quarreling among them. [495]

“The only thing that makes him [the Eskimo] really unhappy is to see
others in want, and therefore he shares with them whenever he has
anything to share.”

“The Greenlander is, on the whole, like a sympathetic child with
respect to the needs of others; his first social law is to help his
neighbor.” [496]

“One of the most prominent and attractive traits in the Eskimo’s moral
character is certainly his integrity.... It is of special importance
for the Eskimo that he should be able to rely with confidence upon his
neighbors and his fellow-men; and it is the first condition of this
mutual confidence, on which depends all united action in the battle for
life, that every man should be upright in his dealings with his
neighbors. The Eskimo therefore regards it as in the highest degree
dishonorable to steal from his house-mates or from his
fellow-villagers, and it is very seldom that anything of the sort
occurs.” [497]

“The worst thing that can happen to a Greenlander is to be made
ridiculous in the eyes of his fellows, and to be scoffed at by them.”
[498]

With regard to the American Indians living in the region of the
Columbia river, Dr. Waitz makes the following statement: “The qualities
regarded as virtues by these peoples are honesty and love of truth,
courage, obedience to parents and chiefs, and love of wife and child;
and the Salish, whose moral ideals are here especially indicated, in
general come up to these requirements very well. With them and with
their cousins, the ‘Pends-d’Oreilles’ and Spokane, crimes are very
rare, and a mere rebuke, administered by the chief, is of great
effectiveness. Old age, too, finds among the Salish benevolent support
and care, though children who have the misfortune to lose their fathers
have often a sad lot, their property being frequently taken from them.
Most of these peoples are upright and honest, live together in the most
peaceable fashion, and have friendly intercourse with the whites.”
[499]

G. Catlin, one of the authors who are best informed upon everything
concerning the North American Indians, says of their character:

“I have roamed about from time to time during seven or eight years,
visiting and associating with, some three or four hundred thousand of
these people, under an almost infinite variety of circumstances; and
from the very many and decided voluntary acts of their hospitality and
kindness I feel bound to pronounce them, by nature, a kind and
hospitable people. I have been welcomed generally in their country, and
treated to the best that they could give me, without any charges made
for my board; they have often escorted me through their enemies’
country at some hazard to their own lives, and aided me in passing
mountains and rivers with my awkward baggage; and under all of these
circumstances of exposure, no Indian ever betrayed me, struck me a
blow, or stole from me a shilling’s worth of my property that I am
aware of.

“This is saying a great deal, (and proving it too, if the reader
believe me) in favour of the virtues of these people; when it is borne
in mind, as it should be, that there is no law in their land to punish
a man for theft—that locks and keys are not known in their country—that
the commandments have never been divulged amongst them; nor can any
human retribution fall upon the head of thief, save the disgrace which
attaches as a stigma to his character, in the eyes of his people about
him.

“And thus in these little communities, strange as it may seem, in the
absence of all systems of jurisprudence, I have often beheld peace and
happiness, and quiet, reigning supreme, for which even kings and
emperors might envy them. I have seen rights and virtue protected, and
wrongs redressed; and I have seen conjugal, filial and paternal
affection in the simplicity and contentedness of nature. I have
unavoidably, formed warm and enduring attachments to some of these men
which I do not wish to forget—who have brought me near to their hearts,
and in our final separation have embraced me in their arms, commended
me and my affairs to the keeping of the great Spirit.” [500]

In treating of the question of which of the two are the happier, the
civilized nations or the peoples he visited, the same author says:

“I have long looked with the eye of a critic, into the jovial faces of
these sons of the forest, unfurrowed with cares—where the agonizing
feeling of poverty had never stamped distress upon the brow. I have
watched the bold, intrepid step—the proud, yet dignified deportment of
Nature’s man, in fearless freedom, with a soul unalloyed by mercenary
lusts, too great to yield to laws or power except from God. As these
independent fellows are all joint-tenants of the soil, they are all
rich, and none of the steepings of comparative poverty can strangle
their just claims to renown. Who (I could ask) can look without
admiring, into a society where peace and harmony prevail—where virtue
is cherished—where rights are protected and wrongs are redressed—with
no laws, but the laws of honour, which are the supreme laws of their
land. Trust the boasted virtues of civilized society for awhile, with
all its intellectual refinements, to such a tribunal, and then write
down the degradation of the ‘lawless savage’ and our transcendent
virtues.”

Lewis H. Morgan, after passing a great part of his life among the
Iroquois, says with regard to them: “All the members of an Iroquois
gens were personally free, and they were bound to defend each other’s
freedom; they were equal in privileges and in personal rights, the
sachem and chiefs claiming no superiority; and they were a brotherhood
bound together by the ties of kin. Liberty, equality, and fraternity,
though never formulated, were cardinal principles of the gens. These
facts are material, because the gens was the unit of a social and
governmental system, the foundation upon which Indian society was
organized. A structure composed of such units would of necessity bear
the impress of their character, for as the unit so the compound. It
serves to explain that sense of independence and personal dignity
universally an attribute of Indian character.” [501]

He describes the hospitality of the peoples mentioned as follows:
“Among the Iroquois hospitality was an established usage. If a man
entered an Indian house in any of their villages, whether a villager,
or a stranger, it was the duty of the women therein to set food before
him. An omission to do this would have been a discourtesy amounting to
an affront. If hungry, he ate; if not hungry, courtesy required that he
should taste the food and thank the giver. This would be repeated at
every house he entered, and at whatever hour in the day. As a custom it
was upheld by a rigorous public sentiment. The same hospitality was
extended to strangers from their own and from other tribes. Upon the
advent of the European race among them it was also extended to them.
This characteristic of barbarous society, wherein food was the
principal concern of life, is a remarkable fact. The law of
hospitality, as administered by the American aborigines, tended to the
final equalization of subsistence. Hunger and destitution could not
exist at one end of an Indian village or in one section of an
encampment while plenty prevailed elsewhere in the same village or
encampment. [502]

A. R. Wallace speaks as follows of the primitive population of South
America and the Indian Archipelago: “I have lived with communities of
savages in South America and in the East, who have no laws or law
courts but the public opinion of the village freely expressed. Each man
scrupulously respects the rights of his fellow, and any infraction of
these rights rarely or never takes place. In such a community, all are
nearly equal. There are none of those wide distinctions, of education
and ignorance, wealth and poverty, master and servant, which are the
product of our civilization; there is none of the wide-spreading
division of labor, which, while it increases wealth, produces also
conflicting interests; there is not that severe competition and
struggle for existence, or for wealth, which the dense population of
civilized countries inevitably creates. All incitements to great crimes
are thus wanting, and petty ones are repressed, partly by the influence
of public opinion, but chiefly by that natural sense of justice and of
his neighbor’s right, which seems to be, in some degree, inherent in
every race of man.” [503]

In his work, “Village Communities in the East and West”, H. S. Maine
says:

“Whenever a corner is lifted up of the veil which hides from us the
primitive condition of mankind, even of such parts of it as we know to
have been destined to civilisation, there are two positions, now very
familiar to us, which seem to be signally falsified by all we are
permitted to see—All men are brothers, and all men are equal. The scene
before us is rather that which the animal world presents to the mental
eye of those who have the courage to bring home to themselves the facts
answering to the memorable theory of Natural Selection. Each fierce
little community is perpetually at war with its neighbour, tribe with
tribe, village with village. The never-ceasing attacks of the strong on
the weak end in the manner expressed by the monotonous formula which so
often recurs in the pages of Thucydides, ‘they put the men to the
sword, the women and children they sold into slavery.’ Yet, even amid
all this cruelty and carnage, we find the germs of ideas, which have
spread over the world. There is still a place and a sense in which men
are brothers and equals. The universal belligerency is the belligerency
of one total group, tribe, or village, with another; but in the
interior of the groups the regimen is one not of conflict and confusion
but rather of ultra-legality. The men who composed the primitive
communities believed themselves to be kinsmen in the most literal sense
of the word; and surprising as it may seem, there are a multitude of
indications that in one stage of thought they must have regarded
themselves as equals.” [504]

Scores of pages might be filled with facts proving that the primitive
peoples of all races and in all parts of the world were not only not
egoistic in their relations with the people they lived among, but
rather the contrary. In conclusion I wish to note the opinions of two
distinguished sociologists, Steinmetz and Kovalewsky, opinions which
derive significance from the great ethnological knowledge of these
authors.

At the Fifth Congress of Criminal Anthropology Dr. Steinmetz, in
speaking upon the explanation of crime by the hypothesis of atavism,
says: “It is not at all probable that our true born-criminal resembles
the normal savage. The former is characterized by his ferocious egoism,
while the latter is nothing if not a devoted member of the group whose
customs he respects and whose interests he defends; the savage is very
tender toward the children whom the criminal abandons; the savage is
only cruel toward the enemy, the criminal toward all the world.” [505]

After having cited different altruistic traits of primitive peoples
Kovalewsky says: “The enumeration would wear out your patience if one
were to cite all the proofs that travelers give of the care that
savages and barbarians have for their mutual welfare, and the fulness
of their charity. To these facts, which indicate the prolonged
existence of a sort of communism, others correspond....” [506]

I am of the opinion that no one, taking the above facts into
consideration, will maintain that man has always and everywhere shown
the same egoistic traits, or that there has been a gradual evolution
from egoism towards altruism.

It would be a mistake, however, to suppose that primitive peoples
present under all circumstances the altruistic characteristics that I
have mentioned. I have already remarked that the position of woman is
in general very dependent. In general the primitive peoples are very
fond of their children and give them very tender care. Nevertheless
infanticide is not uncommon among those who are at a low stage of
civilization. And I have already remarked that among nomadic peoples
the sick and aged were often abandoned. Here are then contradictions
which it is necessary to explain.

Apparently—but only apparently—an evolution from egoism towards
altruism has really taken place and has not yet ceased. This appearance
is the effect of the alteration in the character of the egoism under
the present economic system; it has become less violent than at earlier
periods. The fight is no longer carried on with fire-arms or cold
steel, but with other weapons no less dangerous, and this is what is
generally lost sight of. We note that in ancient times the prisoners
were killed; that later they were sold into slavery; that slavery was
superseded by serfdom, which in its turn gave place to free labor.

But it is not always a growing altruistic sentiment that has been the
motive in these changes. The life of prisoners of war has not been
spared from reasons of humanity, but because the extension of the
productivity of labor made it more profitable to make a prisoner work
than to kill him. And slavery was not abolished because slave-owners
had become less egoistic, but because it was more profitable to make
free laborers work than to make slaves do so. [507] We cannot speak of
the diminution of egoism, but of the moderating of violence in the
course of time. It cannot be maintained that a capitalist who tries by
a lock-out to force his workmen to break with their union, in order
that he may escape the danger of a decrease in his profits through a
strike, and who in this way condemns them and their families to hunger,
is less egoistic than the slave-owner driving his slaves to harder
labor. The former does not use force—it is useless—he has a surer
weapon at his command, the suffering with which he can strike his
workmen; he seems less egoistic, but in reality is as egoistic as the
latter. The great speculator who, by manipulating the market, forces
thousands of persons to pay more for the necessaries of life, and to
become his tributaries as it were, is not less egoistic than the
robber-baron of the middle ages who, arms in hand, forced the traveling
merchants to pay him tribute. The difference is merely that the former
attains his end without using violence like the latter. Capitalism is a
system of exploitation in which, in place of the exploited person’s
being robbed he is compelled by poverty to use all his powers for the
benefit of the exploiter. [508]

The same thing is true of colonial history. At first the aborigines of
the countries explored by the Europeans were often pillaged and
massacred. This system has long been abandoned, not from altruism
however, but because it is more profitable to make a conquered people
work than to pillage and exterminate them. When they do not submit
voluntarily, force is used as heretofore.

The apparent improvement has yet another cause. Christianity preaches
“Thou shalt love thy neighbor as thy self.” And since this maxim has
been often preached and many Christians have it always in their mouths,
men come to believe that it is really put into practice. The contrary
is true. The fact that the duty of altruism is so much insisted upon is
the most convincing proof that it is not generally practiced or it
would not be so much spoken and preached about. There are many persons
in our days who ask nothing better than to see men act altruistically,
but they preach in the wilderness; their wish has not come true.
Present society is moulded by egoism. The egoism is less violent,
however, and more disguised.



Before speaking of the real causes of egoism and altruism it may be
well to attempt to answer the question, Whence come these inexact
ideas? It is not difficult, in my opinion, to explain how it comes
about that many men believe that the “homo homini lupus” of Hobbes has
been true always and everywhere. The adherents of this opinion have
studied principally men who live under capitalism, or under
civilization; their correct conclusion has been that egoism is the
predominant characteristic of these men, and they have adopted the
simplest explanation of the phenomenon and say that this trait is
inborn.

If they had known the periods anterior to civilization, they would have
noted that the “homo homini lupus” is an historical phenomenon
applicable during a relatively short period, [509] and that
consequently it is impossible that egoism should be innate in man.
However great have been the social modifications during the period of
civilization, the principal aim of men has always been, and still is,
to acquire personal wealth, and men still remain divided into classes,
that is into groups whose economic interests are contrary. This is why
an examination of the earlier periods is of such high importance for
sociology.

An erroneous interpretation of the Darwinian theory has also
contributed to bring about the strange notion of the eternal character
of the struggle of all against all. Darwin himself maintains nothing of
the sort. In his “Origin of Species” he says in the clearest terms that
the struggle between the individuals of the same species does not at
all happen in every species: “There must in every case be a struggle
for existence, either one individual with another of the same species,
or with the individuals of distinct species, or with the physical
conditions of life.” [510]

The explanation of the second hypothesis, that of the evolution from
egoism towards altruism, is more complicated. In the first place the
facts adduced in support of it are not numerous, and they serve rather
to illustrate a theory than to furnish the materials by which it may be
justified. In the second place a part of the ethnological materials in
relation to the question it has been impossible to utilize. They have
been collected partly by persons convinced beforehand of the
superiority of Christian morality to every other system, and who
consequently disapprove of everything opposed to it, and partly by
persons whose own conduct has caused the enmity manifested by the
peoples with whom they have come into contact. No part of the history
of civilization offers a more hideous spectacle than that of
colonization. [511] In the third place it is necessary to exclude
peoples that have had much contact with Europeans or other civilized
peoples. In the fourth place we often lose sight of the fact that
primitive peoples show great differences of development, and
consequently cannot be placed in the same rank. [512] For example, if
peoples despotically governed show strong egoistic tendencies, we have
no right to declare that all primitive peoples are egoistic.

Finally it is of the highest importance in studying primitive peoples
to make the distinction between the acts which have to do with persons
of the same social group, and those which have to do with strangers.
One of the principal causes of the charge of egoism made against
primitive peoples is to be found in the fact that this dualism of
ethics is forgotten. In the passages I have cited (those from Maine and
Steinmetz, for instance) the great difference between acts committed
within and without the group is brought out. We have seen that the
Indians of North America, although very altruistic toward those who
form the same group with them, as also toward their guests, are the
most pitiless enemies of those who attack their independence or their
hunting ground. Now it has been by these last acts that these peoples
have been generally judged, a wholly wrong method, since the “dualism
of ethics” has always existed. Great would be the astonishment if any
one were to maintain that the South African war proved that the English
were a nation of murderers and incendiaries. Yet this is just the sort
of reasoning that is applied to primitive peoples. [513]



How does it happen that some animal species are social while others are
not? It is impossible to maintain with some authors that sociability
increases according to the degree of development attained by the
animal. [514] Certain insects, for example, are endowed with pronounced
social feelings, while the cat tribe and some kinds of birds are on the
contrary unsocial. Nevertheless the latter occupy a higher place in the
scale than the former. The explanation, then, must be sought elsewhere.
[515]

There are divers reasons that draw a more or less considerable number
of animals to one place—the fact of being born in the same locality,
for example. Most animals are social when they are young, even those
which are no longer so when full-grown, like the arachnids. Another
cause that brings animals together is emigration towards a country
because of great changes of temperature. A third cause, probably the
most important, that unites animals of the same species is the
abundance of the food-supply of certain countries.

However, the occasional assembling of animals does not explain why
certain animals are social while others are not. Lions, for example,
often meet in places where they come to drink, and yet do not become
social. It is not probable that there are animals who have remained
together because they have comprehended the advantages of a life in
common, for this would suppose an intelligence on their part which it
is difficult to attribute to them. In order that these animals should
remain together they must find it agreeable, and disagreeable to be
isolated.

When we study the social species of animals we notice that the life in
common is in general one of their most powerful weapons in the struggle
for existence, a weapon without which it would be nearly or quite
impossible for them to maintain the fight. Consequently the animals for
which the life in common is advantageous and which possess social
instincts stronger than others, have, when brought together by any
cause whatever, a greater chance to survive. [516] Per contra the
animals who have to stalk their prey have more chance of surviving when
life in common is disagreeable to them. It is therefore by survival
that social feelings are developed in some species of animals and not
in others. [517] Habit, and the tendency to imitate increase these
feelings considerably.

The advantages to certain species of animals resulting from life in
common are of two kinds; in the first place a better defense against
their enemies, and in the second place greater ease in procuring
subsistence. Wild cattle give us an example of the first case; while
the wolves who in winter gather into packs for purposes of the chase,
because food has become scarce, furnish us an example of the second.
For other animals (like the simians) social sentiments are helpful in
both ways.

It is unnecessary to amplify further upon the two ways in which life in
groups is of advantage to certain species of animals. We have yet to
turn our attention to the qualities developed by the group struggle for
existence.

One of the principal characteristics of social animals is the pleasure
they experience in living in common, so that a social animal is unhappy
if he is separate from those of the group in which he lives. Further it
is necessary that the animal that cannot live alone, and is happy with
his group, should also feel a sympathy with that group. Pleasure or its
opposite felt by any individual reacts upon the whole group. A social
being will try then to favor the interests of his fellows as far as he
can, and in so far as he comprehends these interests. This sympathy
will not extend to the whole species but only to the group. The general
interest of the group does not permit the sympathy to embrace the whole
species, but on the contrary requires one group to fight the other if,
for example, the latter interferes with its food-supply. And even
within the limits of the group the general interest may demand that a
sick or wounded individual be abandoned, when by its presence it would
for example, attract beasts of prey, and thus put the existence of all
in danger.

Highly developed sympathy produces the spirit of sacrifice, which
impels the individual to assist his companions sometimes even at the
risk of his life. [518] This quality is reinforced by the desire of
gaining the praise and avoiding the blame of companions, which desire
in its turn is brought about only by the life in common. For the one
that lives in conjunction with others, and takes pleasure in doing so,
whose interests are those of the members of the group, must be sensible
of the approval or disapproval of his acts felt by others, since their
feelings of pleasure or displeasure react upon himself. The lack of the
power of speech among animals, however, limits the force of praise or
blame among them.

We come now to the question: what are the causes of altruism among men?
[519] It must be considered as certain that man has always lived in
groups more or less large, and it is even very probable that he is
descended from animals equally social. [520] A study of the means man
has of sustaining the struggle for existence proves that they are of
such a nature that he would have succumbed if he had lived in
isolation. Kautsky puts it thus: “... man ... whose mightiest and most
effective, almost whose only weapon, indeed, in the struggle for
existence, is association. He is, to be sure, distinguished above other
animals by his intelligence, but this too is to the fruit of society,
for in isolation he becomes dull and stupid. All man’s other weapons in
the struggle for existence are less efficient than those of the beasts.
He has no weapons of attack like the beasts of prey, nor is he
protected by his size like the elephant, hippopotamus and rhinoceros.
He lacks the quickness of the squirrel and deer, and cannot repair his
losses through superabundant fertility.” [521]

It is therefore on account of his constitution and of the struggle that
he has had to sustain for his existence that man is a social being; in
other words, those who showed social instincts stronger than the others
ran less danger of succumbing in the contest for life, and had more
chance of transmitting their leanings to their posterity. As man has
greater intellectual capacities than the animals he is more capable of
understanding the joys and sorrows of his fellows, and so is better
able to assist the one and avoid the other. In the second place he has
a developed language at his command, through which a great influence
can be exercised upon conduct by blame and praise. [522]

The fact that man is born with social instincts does not, however,
explain altruism sufficiently, for among animal species there is not
one whose individuals have done so much harm to one another as men,
who, though they are social beings, are capable of committing the most
egoistic acts. How shall we explain these contradictions?

We have seen above that primitive peoples, to whom we have referred
showed very altruistic traits of character. The members of a group
extend mutual aid, and, in their relations with one another, are
benevolent, honest, truthful, and very susceptible to the opinions of
others, [523] etc.

It is impossible to explain this either by the race to which these
peoples belong or by the climate in which they live, for they are of
different races (for example North American Indians and the Hindoos of
the delta of the Ganges) and live under different climates (as the
Eskimos and the South American Indians). Besides this some of these
peoples show towards strangers, qualities directly contrary to those
they display toward members of their own group. Thus, as we have
already remarked, the North American Indians are most cruel enemies,
most pitiless toward those who are not of their group, while they are
quite the reverse toward their own fellow-tribesmen. It is plain, then,
that their altruistic sentiments have nothing to do with race or
climate.

Consequently the cause can only be found in the social environment,
which is determined in its turn by the mode of production. What follows
will show that in the last instance it is the mode of production that
is able to develop the social predisposition innate in man (not in the
same measure for each individual, which is a question that I shall
return to) or prevent this disposition from being developed, or may
even destroy it entirely. Upon examining the modes of production in
force among the peoples cited we see that they are characterized by the
following traits, very different from those of the present system.

The first of these characteristic traits is this: production takes
place among these peoples for personal consumption and not for exchange
as with us. It has often been claimed that the primitive peoples lived
in a state of communism. Taken in the sense of a communism in
production this assertion is true only in part; except for hunts
undertaken in common, production was not carried on in common but was
individual. The weapons and utensils of the hunt were private property,
while the hunting-ground was held in common. Just so as soon as
architectural technique made some progress the houses often became
common property. At its inception agriculture was not practiced in
common. It was only when it had attained a certain development that
this was sometimes the case. [524] But if we take communism in the
sense of consumption in common, then the assertion becomes much more
exact. I do not mean to say that consumption always took place in
common (though several primitive peoples took their food in common),
but when from whatever cause some members of the group had failed to
produce, the other members who had been more fortunate provided for
them. The productivity of labor was still small; there was not
generally any surplus of labor. Even if there had been there could not
have been any possibility of exchange, since the division of labor was
very slight, and consequently each one was capable of making for
himself what others would have been able to offer in exchange.

The second characteristic of the modes of production of the peoples in
question is bound up with the first, namely that there was neither
wealth nor poverty. If there was privation (through scarcity of game,
for example), all suffered; if there was abundance, all profited by it.
[525]

The third fact to be noted is that the subordination of man to nature
was very great, so great that we, who have so largely subjugated the
forces of nature, can have no idea of it. If primitive men were very
weak in their contest with nature even when joined together in a single
group, individually they were absolutely unable to maintain the
struggle, and were thus forced to unite.

If we consider the characteristics of the primitive modes of production
it becomes clear, it seems to me, why the primitive peoples were not
more egoistic. They had neither rich nor poor; their economic interests
were either parallel or equal (the latter in the case of production in
common); the economic life, therefore, did not arouse egoistic
ideas—they were not led into temptation. Where the economic system does
not produce egoistic ideas it accustoms men to being unegoistic, and if
their interests do happen occasionally to conflict, the matter is
looked at altruistically and not egoistically. And since the economic
life is the “conditio sine qua non” of life in general, and thus
occupies the important place in human existence, it stamps the whole
life with its non-egoistic character. Since the struggle for existence
must be sustained in common against nature, if it is to be efficacious
it binds human interests so closely together that they are inseparable;
the interest of one is the same as that of his comrade.

We shall now understand why primitive men feel themselves to be first
of all the members of a unit; why they not only abstain from acts
harmful to their companions, but come to their aid whenever they can;
why they are honest, benevolent, and truthful towards the members of
their group, and why public opinion has so great an influence among
them—characteristics which the quotations that I have already made have
established. The cause of these facts is to be found in the mode of
production, which brought about a uniformity of interest in the persons
united in a single group, obliged them to aid one another in the
difficult and uninterrupted struggle for existence, and made men free
and equal, since there was neither poverty nor riches, and consequently
no possibility of oppression.

It is only in such an environment that the social instincts innate in
man can be developed, and the more the mode of production binds men’s
interests together the greater will this development be. It is a truth
as old as the world that one respects the interests of others and does
not deceive them, only when these others do not make life more
difficult, but aid in supporting it. If not, social instincts will be
suppressed and the contrary instincts formed. The development of the
social feelings is based upon reciprocity. When this is lacking these
feelings lie dormant, but when reciprocity exists they grow stronger by
constantly reacting from one to the other. [526]

There is still another reason which helped strengthen the solidarity
among the members of the same group. The primitive peoples, who
practiced agriculture little or not at all, needed an immense territory
to provide for their needs. Lands whose population would seem small to
the Europeans of our day, had in reality as dense a population as the
mode of production would permit. From this there sprang continual wars
between groups disputing the possession of a certain territory. The
necessity of defending as a body the territory acquired, or of
conquering it anew, resulted in drawing always tighter the bonds
uniting the members of the same group.

The same mode of production which drew the members of a group into an
altruistic solidarity, forced these same persons into a position of
excessive egoism toward those who did not belong to their group and
opposed them in obtaining what they needed. The same act, killing an
enemy for example, is the most egoistic act possible from the point of
view of the enemy but a very altruistic act from the point of view of
the slayer, since he has increased the security of his group. The
development of the social feelings is, then, only determined by the
form of the struggle for existence.

How then shall we explain certain egoistic acts directed against
members of the same group? How, for example, can the infanticide so
common among primitive peoples be explained? In seeking for a solution
we shall see that this egoistic act does not result from innate
insensibility toward children (the contrary is true, as we have seen
above), but from the fact that the limited control over nature makes a
great increase in the population impossible. The children were killed
immediately after birth; no one dreamed of ridding himself of a child
of greater age. Further, the nomadic life prevented the carrying along
of a great number of children. [527]

It is for the same reason that the sick and the aged were sometimes
abandoned by the primitive peoples. They were driven to this because
these feeble persons were unable to make long journeys, and because
their economic means did not allow them to support those who could no
longer work. Here again there could be no question of innate
insensibility. [528] In these cases then, there was an opposition of
interests; the act that was egoistic toward the individual was
altruistic toward the group. If different action had been taken in such
cases all would have succumbed. Thus these acts have fallen into
desuetude as the productivity of labor has developed.

The continual development of the productivity of labor has modified the
structure of society greatly. As soon as productivity has increased to
such an extent that the producer can regularly produce more than he
needs, and the division of labor puts him in a position to exchange the
surplus for things that he could not produce himself, at this moment
there arises in man the notion of no longer giving to his comrades what
they need, but of keeping for himself the surplus of what his labor
produces, and exchanging it. Then it is that the mode of production
begins to run counter to the social instincts of man instead of
favoring it as heretofore.

In his work already quoted Nansen has described the influence exercised
by exchange upon the character of the Eskimos studied by him. (The fact
that this commerce has been developed by the coming of the Europeans
makes no difference. Among primitive peoples exchange must have
developed in the same way, only more slowly.) He says: “How baneful to
them has been the introduction of money! Formerly they had no means of
saving up work or accumulating riches; for the products of their labor
did not last indefinitely, and therefore they gave away their
superfluity. But then they learned the use of money; so that now, when
they have more than they need for the moment, the temptation to sell
the overplus to Europeans, instead of giving it to their needy
neighbors, is often too great for them; for with the money they thus
acquire they can supply themselves with the much coveted European
commodities. Thus we Christians help more and more to destroy instead
of to develop their old self-sacrificing love of their neighbors. And
money does still more to undermine the Greenland community. Their ideas
of inheritance were formerly very vague, for, as before mentioned, the
clothes and weapons of a dead man were consigned with him to the grave.
Now, on the other hand, the introduction of money has enabled the
survivors to sell the effects of the deceased, and they are no longer
ashamed to accept as an inheritance what they can obtain in this way.
This may seem an advantage; but, here, too, their old habit of mind is
upset. Greed and covetousness—vices which they formerly abhorred above
everything—have taken possession of them. Their minds are warped and
enthralled by money.” [529] Thus are born avarice and rapacity, which,
opposed in the beginning by altruistic sentiments developed earlier,
become stronger from one generation to another. [530]

However, this is only one side of the question. Through the development
of exchange not only does man become egoistic towards those who for any
reason are unable to provide for their needs, but exchange itself is an
entirely egoistic act for the two parties who enter into it. Each tries
to get as much profit for himself as possible, and consequently to make
the other lose. The existence of economic laws which in many, and even
in most cases prevent the two parties from injuring each other, does
not change the fact at all. Commerce weakens the social instincts of
man; the loss of one becomes the gain of another. When two persons are
trading there springs up a tendency on the part of each to overvalue
his own property and to disparage that of the other; commerce is one of
the important causes of lying. In addition to this tendency another
arises, that of giving goods of quality inferior to that agreed upon;
the constant attention to one’s own interests produces and develops
fraud.

The more production for one’s own use decreases, and the greater
becomes the production for exchange, the more do habit and tradition
produce in men the characteristics mentioned. As soon as exchange has
developed to a certain point commerce begins to be a special trade. The
merchant is much more exposed to the conditions named than those who
trade only occasionally. Not only does he pass a great part of his life
in exchanging but he is by profession egoistic in two directions;
toward the producer from whom he buys, and toward the consumer to whom
he sells. [531]

When it reaches a certain height the continually increasing
productivity of labor brings a further important modification in the
social structure, namely slavery. For this springs up when production
is so advanced that man can regularly produce more than he actually
needs for himself, and when it is possible for him to exchange the
overplus for things which he can use but cannot make. Prisoners of war
are no longer killed as formerly, but are obliged to work for the
profit of the conquerors. In this way is formed a considerable
opposition of interest between two classes of individuals who together
form a social unit: on the one hand those who, deprived of one of the
most important factors of human happiness, liberty, are obliged to
exhaust themselves for the benefit of others, and have only the strict
necessaries of life; and on the other hand those who profit by the
enslavement and excessive labor of the first.

Slavery (with the other forms of forced service, serfdom and
wage-labor) is one of the most important factors that undermine the
social instincts in man. Slavery, runs the saying, demoralizes the
master as well as the slave. It arouses in the master the notion that
the slave is not a thinking and feeling man like himself, but an
instrument destined exclusively to be useful to him. In the slave
himself it kills the feeling of independence; lacking the arms which
the free man has at his disposal, the slave has recourse to
dissimulation to defend himself against his master.

The overplus which one person can obtain by his own labor must always
remain limited. Without the rise of slavery the great wealth of a
single individual would not have been possible. To the difference
between master and slave is now added that between rich and poor, and
the envy and hatred of the poor for the rich, and the pride of the rich
and their desire to dominate over the poor. Since the division of
society into rich and poor the aristocracy has been formed, which does
not owe its origin to the excellence of its members, as one might
imagine from this inaccurate name, but to their wealth.



The period of civilization during which the social modification
mentioned above has taken place is generally lauded to the skies, as
compared with preceding epochs. In certain relations this is
justifiable. Technique has made immense progress and especially during
the last phase of civilization, capitalism; the power of man over
nature has advanced greatly; the productivity of labor has been so
increased that one class of men, exempted by this from permanent care
for their daily bread, are able to devote themselves to the arts and
sciences. All this is indisputable. But the development of the arts and
sciences and of technique has only an indirect importance for the
etiology of crime. The question first of all to be asked is this: What
influence has this modification in the economic and social structure
had upon the character of man? And the answer to this question can only
be the following: this modification has engendered cupidity and
ambition, has made man less sensitive to the happiness and misery of
his fellows, and has decreased the influence exercised upon men’s acts
by the opinions of others. In short, it has developed egoism at the
expense of altruism.




C. EGOISTIC TENDENCIES RESULTING FROM THE PRESENT ECONOMIC SYSTEM
   AND FROM ITS CONSEQUENCES.

The etiology of crime includes the three following problems:

First. Whence does the criminal thought in man arise?

Second. What forces are there in man which can prevent the execution of
this criminal thought, and what is their origin?

Third. What is the occasion for the commission of criminal acts? (As
the occasion may be one of the causes of the criminal thought, problems
one and three at times form but one.)

For the moment we are still occupied with general considerations with
regard to crime; it is clear then that the first and third questions
will be examined only when we are treating of crimes according to the
groups into which they must be divided because of the great differences
which their nature presents.

It is otherwise with the second question. As we have seen in the
preceding pages, it is certain that man is born with social instincts,
which, when influenced by a favorable environment can exert a force
great enough to prevent egoistic thoughts from leading to egoistic
acts. And since crime constitutes a part of the egoistic acts, it is of
importance, for the etiology of crime in general, to inquire whether
the present method of production and its social consequences are an
obstacle to the development of the social instincts, and in what
measure. We shall try in the following pages to show the influence of
the economic system and of these consequences upon the social instincts
of man.

After what we have just said it is almost superfluous to remark that
the egoistic tendency does not by itself make a man criminal. For this
something else is necessary. It is possible for the environment to
create a great egoist, but this does not imply that the egoist will
necessarily become criminal. For example, a man who is enriched by the
exploitation of children may nevertheless remain all his life an honest
man from the legal point of view. He does not think of stealing,
because he has a surer and more lucrative means of getting wealth,
although he lacks the moral sense which would prevent him from
committing a crime if the thought of it occurred to him. We shall show
that, as a consequence of the present environment, man has become very
egoistic and hence more capable of crime, than if the environment had
developed the germs of altruism.

a. The present economic system is based upon exchange. As we saw at the
end of the preceding section such a mode of production cannot fail to
have an egoistic character. A society based upon exchange isolates the
individuals by weakening the bond that unites them. When it is a
question of exchange the two parties interested think only of their own
advantage even to the detriment of the other party. In the second place
the possibility of exchange arouses in a man the thought of the
possibility of converting the surplus of his labor into things which
increase his well-being in place of giving the benefit of it to those
who are deprived of the necessaries of life. Hence the possibility of
exchange gives birth to cupidity.

The exchange called simple circulation of commodities is practiced by
all men as consumers, and by the workers besides as vendors of their
labor power. However, the influence of this simple circulation of
commodities is weak compared with that exercised by capitalistic
exchange. It is only the exchange of the surplus of labor, by the
producer, for other commodities, and hence is for him a secondary
matter. As a result he does not exchange with a view to profit, (though
he tries to make as advantageous a trade as possible) but to get things
which he cannot produce himself.

Capitalistic exchange, on the other hand, has another aim—that of
making a profit. A merchant, for example, does not buy goods for his
own use, but to sell them to advantage. He will, then, always try, on
the one hand, to buy the best commodities as cheaply as possible, by
depreciating them as much as he can; on the other hand, to make the
purchaser pay as high a price as possible, by exaggerating the value of
his wares. By the nature of the mode of production itself the merchant
is therefore forced to make war upon two sides, must maintain his own
interests against the interests of those with whom he does business. If
he does not injure too greatly the interests of those from whom he
buys, and those to whom he sells, it is for the simple reason that
these would otherwise do business with those of his competitors who do
not find their interest in fleecing their customers. Wherever
competition is eliminated for whatever cause the tactics of the
merchant are shown in their true light; he thinks only of his own
advantage even to the detriment of those with whom he does business.
“No commerce without trickery” is a proverbial expression (among
consumers), and with the ancients Mercury, the god of commerce, was
also the god of thieves. This is true, that the merchant and the thief
are alike in taking account exclusively of their own interest to the
detriment of those with whom they have to do.

The fact that in our present society production does not take place
generally to provide for the needs of men, but for many other reasons,
has important effects upon the character of those who possess the means
of production. Production is carried on for profit exclusively; if
greater profits can be made by stopping production it will be
stopped—this is the point of view of the capitalists. The consumers, on
the other hand, see in production the means of creating what man has
need of. The world likes to be deceived, and does not care to recognize
the fact that the producer has only his own profit in view. The latter
encourages this notion and poses as a disinterested person. If he
reduces the price of his wares, he claims to do it in the interest of
the public, and takes care not to admit that it is for the purpose of
increasing his own profits. This is the falsity that belongs inevitably
to capitalism.

In general this characteristic of capitalism has no importance for the
morality of the consumer, who is merely duped, but it is far otherwise
with the press, which is almost entirely in the power of the
capitalists. The press, which ought to be a guide for the masses, and
is so in some few cases, in the main is in the hands of capitalists who
use it only as a means of making money. In place of being edited by men
who, by their ability and firmness, are capable of enlightening the
public, newspapers are carried on by persons who see in their calling
only a livelihood, and consider only the proprietor of the sheet. In
great part the press is the opposite of what it ought to be; it
represents the interests of those who pay for advertisements or for
articles; it increases the ignorance and the prejudices of the crowd;
in a word, it poisons public opinion. [532]

Besides this general influence upon the public the press has further a
special place in the etiology of crime, from the fact that most
newspapers, in order to satisfy the morbid curiosity of the public,
relate all great crimes in extenso, give portraits of the victims,
etc., and are often one of the causes of new crimes, by arousing the
imitative instinct to be found in man. [533]

As we have seen above the merchant capitalist makes war in two
directions; his interests are against those of the man who sells to
him, and of the man who buys from him. This is also true of the
industrial capitalist. He buys raw materials and sells what he
produces. But to arrive at his product he must buy labor, and this
purchase is “sui generis.”

Deprived as he is of the means of production the working-man sells his
labor only in order not to die of hunger. The capitalist takes
advantage of this necessitous condition of the worker and exploits him.
We have already indicated that capitalism has this trait in common with
the earlier methods of production. Little by little one class of men
has become accustomed to think that the others are destined to amass
wealth for them and to be subservient to them in every way. Slavery,
like the wage system, demoralizes the servant as well as the master.
With the master it develops cupidity and the imperious character which
sees in a fellow man only a being fit to satisfy his desires. It is
true that the capitalist has not the power over the proletarian that
the master has over his slave; he has neither the right of service nor
the power of life and death, yet it is none the less true that he has
another weapon against the proletarian, a weapon whose effect is no
less terrible, namely enforced idleness. The fact that the supply of
manual labor always greatly exceeds the demand puts this weapon into
the hands of every capitalist. It is not only the capitalists who carry
on any business that are subjected to this influence, but also all who
are salaried in their service.

Capitalism exercises in still a third manner an egoistic influence upon
the capitalistic “entrepreneur.” Each branch has more producers than
are necessary. The interests of the capitalists are, then, opposed not
only to those of the men from whom they buy or to whom they sell, but
also to those of their fellow producers. It is indeed claimed that
competition has the effect simply of making the product better and
cheaper, but this is looking at the question from only one point of
view. The fact which alone affects criminality is that competition
forces the participants, under penalty of succumbing, to be as egoistic
as possible. Even the producers who have the means of applying all the
technical improvements to perfect their product and make it cheaper,
are obliged to have recourse to gross deceits in advertising, etc., in
order to injure their competitors. Rejoicing at the evil which befalls
another, envy at his good fortune, these forms of egoism are the
inevitable consequence of competition.

Following the same classification that we employed in the preceding
chapter we come now to that part of the bourgeoisie which, without
having any occupation, consumes what has been made by others. Not to
feel obliged to contribute to the material well-being of humanity in
proportion to one’s ability must necessarily have a demoralizing
influence. A parasite, one who lives without working, does not feel
bound by any moral tie to his fellows, but regards them simply as
things, instruments meant to serve and amuse him. Their example is a
source of demoralization for those about them, and excites the envy of
those who see this easy life without the power of enjoying it
themselves, and awakes in them the desire to exchange their painful
existence for this “dolce far niente.”

The egoistic tendencies work less strongly in the third group of the
bourgeoisie, those who practice the liberal professions. However, the
products of the arts and sciences having become commodities, the
egoistic influence of exchange here too is not to be neglected. Then
competition arising from overproduction is a great cause of
demoralization, for where there is competition men become egoistic. So
in the domain of the liberal professions competition often forces those
who do not find a field of activity in accordance with their ideas, to
work that is contrary to those ideas. Thus it is quite right to speak
of a prostitution of the intellect.

Before concluding these observations upon the bourgeoisie there is
still something to be said about politics. As we have seen above the
state owes its origin to the formation of opposition of interests in
society; the first task of the state being, therefore, the maintenance
of a certain amount of order. This requires above all the holding of
the great mass in subjection. As long as this mass is weak the dominant
class has no need to resort to trickery; but as soon as the oppressed
class can oppose the domination of the others, as soon as brutal power
no longer gives the desired result, the dominant class changes its
tactics. It attempts to create the impression that the concessions it
has been forced to make are acts of charity; and presuming upon the
ignorance of the oppressed, it pretends that their condition is not so
bad, etc. Many of those engaged in politics play this part without
being conscious of their duplicity. However, the contest between the
classes exercises its baleful influence upon them also, for they
involuntarily distort the facts, whereas the evolution of society has
reached such a point that a new social order is necessary.

The power in the State sometimes passes from one party of the ruling
class to another. All profit by the temporary opportunity not only for
the realization of their political program, but also to procure
advantages for their partisans. This struggle for power is carried on
partly by means prejudicial to the character of those interested, while
the end aimed at by some parties can be frankly avowed. It is for the
same reason that international politics is such a source of lying and
hypocrisy, the states not being able to avow their real intention—the
weakening of their neighbors.

The proletariat. To be thorough we begin by making mention of one of
the consequences of the economic position of the proletariat, of which
we have already treated briefly, namely the dependence in which persons
of this class find themselves in consequence of their lacking the means
of production, a state which has a prejudicial influence upon
character. The oppressed resort to means which they would otherwise
scorn. As we have seen above, the basis of the social feelings is
reciprocity. As soon as this is trodden under foot by the ruling class
the social sentiments of the oppressed become weak towards them.

We come now (following the order adopted in the first chapter of Part
II) first to the consequences of the labor of the young. The paid labor
of the young has a bad influence in several ways. First, it forces
them, while they are still very young, to think only of their own
interests; then, brought into contact with persons who are rough and
indifferent to their well-being, they follow these only too quickly,
because of their imitative tendencies, in their bad habits, grossness
of speech, etc. Finally, the paid labor of the young makes them more or
less independent at an age where they have the greatest need of
guidance. Even if the statistical proof of the influence of the labor
of children and young people upon criminality were totally wanting, no
one could deny that influence. Child labor is entirely a capitalistic
phenomenon, being found especially in the great manufacturing countries
like England and Germany. And then one of the most salient facts of
criminality is the amount of juvenile crime, which is so enormous that
England, followed by other countries, has established a special system
to combat this form of criminality. Certainly this increase of juvenile
crime is chiefly due to the influence of bad domestic conditions
(wage-labor of married women, etc.), but the labor of the young people
themselves also plays its part.

Although figures upon the relation in question are not totally lacking,
they are, as far as I know, quite rare. In the first part of this work
I have given the figures furnished by P. Hirsch, to which I refer the
reader. [534] The director of the “Erziehungsheim am Urban” at
Zehlendorf near Berlin, mentions that 80% of his pupils had formerly
practiced a trade. [535]

The following figures are given for the Netherlands: [536]


========+=================+=============+======================+========================
        | Total Sentenced | Practicing  | Percentage Sentenced | Percentage of Children
 Years. |    10 to 16     | a Trade.    |        who           |  in General 10 to 16
        |   Years Old.    | [537]       |  Practiced a Trade.  | who Practiced a Trade.
--------+-----------------+-------------+----------------------+------------------------
 1899   |     791         |     363     |       45.8           |          18.5
 1900   |     671         |     347     |       51.7           |           --
 1901   |     674         |     344     |       51.0           |           --
 1902   |     712         |     331     |       46.4           |           --
 1903   |     671         |     344     |       51.2           |           --
 1904   |     702         |     347     |       49.4           |           --
========+=================+=============+======================+========================


These figures are very significant. Among the young delinquents there
are two or three times as many persons following a trade as among
non-delinquents.

I do not know of any other statistics giving information upon this
point directly. [538]

As to statics (the geography of crime) we encounter great difficulties
of a technical nature. The statistics in which we can compare juvenile
delinquency with the local extent of child labor are rare, often taking
no account of the figures for the non-criminal population. [539] On
this point the statistics of Germany, Italy, and Austria are the best.
[540]

Since the work of young people has increased enormously, and in general
is still increasing, we may expect an increase in juvenile crime also,
unless there are other determining factors, such as special laws, which
work in the opposite direction.

In order to give an example of the extent of child labor we take from
one of the best sets of statistics of occupations the following
figures.

In the census of occupations in the German Empire in 1895 it was shown
that whereas in 1882 16.46% of the population under 20 had some
occupation (other than that of domestic servant), in 1895 there were
17.97% so employed, an increase of 9.1%. [541] The absolute figures are
the following. In 1882 the number of persons below the age of 20 at
work was 3,333,791; in 1895 it was 4,161,600, an increase of 827,809.

In 1895 the number of persons at work below the age of 20 was divided
among the different ages as follows: [542]


        Below 12      having paid occupation    32,687
        From 12 to 14   ,,    ,,      ,,       148,766
         ,,  14 ,, 16   ,,    ,,      ,,     1,131,723
         ,,  16 ,, 18   ,,    ,,      ,,     1,397,161
         ,,  18 ,, 20   ,,    ,,      ,,     1,451,263


If the paid labor of young people has really an influence, then, upon
juvenile criminality, statistics must necessarily show an increase in
this criminality, unless other factors exercise an influence in the
other direction.

The following figures have a bearing on this subject: [543]


Germany, 1882–1896.

=======================+=========================================================================================
                       |               Number Convicted at 12 to 18 Years of Age to 100,000 of the
      Offenses.        |                        Population of the Same Age, in the Years:
                       +-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----
                       |1882.|1883.|1884.|1885.|1886.|1887.|1888.|1889.|1890.|1891.|1892.|1893.|1894.|1895.|1896.
-----------------------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----
Crimes in general      | 568 | 549 | 578 | 560 | 565 | 576 | 563 | 614 | 663 | 672 | 729 | 686 | 716 | 702 | 702
Theft and embezzlement | 370 | 353 | 358 | 335 | 337 | 337 | 334 | 369 | 391 | 392 | 430 | 376 | 393 | 380 | 373
Assaults               |  63 |  65 |  78 |  81 |  84 |  86 |  82 |  88 |  99 | 101 | 108 | 118 | 121 | 126 | 130
Malicious mischief     |  31 |  27 |  31 |  33 |  30 |  34 |  32 |  34 |  40 |  38 |  40 |  41 |  45 |  41 |  46
Fraud                  |  20 |  20 |  21 |  20 |  21 |  22 |  22 |  26 |  27 |  28 |  31 |  26 |  28 |  28 |  26
Insults                |  10 |  10 |  12 |  13 |  13 |  13 |  13 |  13 |  16 |  15 |  17 |  19 |  20 |  19 |  19
Rape, etc.             |  12 |  10 |  11 |  11 |  11 |  12 |  11 |  12 |  12 |  13 |  14 |  14 |  16 |  15 |  15
Domiciliary trespass   |   7 |   6 |   9 |   7 |   9 |   8 |   8 |   8 |  11 |  11 |  12 |  12 |  14 |  14 |  14
Forgery                |   5 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   7 |   7 |   8 |   9 |  10 |   9 |   9 |   9 |  10
Rebellion              |   4 |   5 |   5 |   5 |   4 |   6 |   4 |   5 |   5 |   5 |   5 |   6 |   7 |   7 |   8
Arson                  |   3 |   3 |   3 |   3 |   3 |   3 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   3 |   3 |   3 |   2 |   2 |   3
Crimes against life    |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1
Counterfeiting         | 0.3 | 0.3 | 0.4 | 0.3 | 0.3 | 0.3 | 0.4 | 0.2 | 0.3 | 0.5 | 0.4 | 0.2 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.3
=======================+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====


Consequently, in Germany there is a great and constant increase in
juvenile criminality, both as to crime in general and also in each
crime separately. [544]

The following table gives a comparison between the criminality of the
young and that of adults. [545]


Germany, 1882–1896.
========================+=======================================================================================================
                        |                 Number Convicted at 12 to 18 Years of Age to 100,000 of the
       Offenses.        |                              Hundred, Convicted in the Years:
                        +-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-------------
                        |1882.|1883.|1884.|1885.|1886.|1887.|1888.|1889.|1890.|1891.|1892.|1893.|1894.|1895.|1896.|1882 to 1896.
------------------------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-------------
Arson                   |  24 |  21 |  22 |  26 |  26 |  27 |  29 |  32 |  30 |  37 |  31 |  37 |  29 |  28 |  35 |     28
Offenses against morals |  23 |  19 |  22 |  20 |  18 |  21 |  21 |  22 |  23 |  24 |  25 |  24 |  24 |  22 |  21 |     21
Theft and embezzlement  |  17 |  16 |  17 |  17 |  18 |  19 |  19 |  20 |  22 |  21 |  21 |  21 |  21 |  21 |  21 |     19
Malicious mischief      |  14 |  13 |  13 |  13 |  12 |  14 |  15 |  15 |  17 |  17 |  17 |  16 |  17 |  15 |  16 |     15
Forgery                 |   8 |  10 |  10 |  10 |  11 |  10 |  12 |  12 |  13 |  14 |  13 |  13 |  12 |  11 |  12 |     11
Fraud                   |   9 |   9 |   9 |   9 |   9 |   9 |   9 |  10 |  10 |  10 |  10 |   8 |   6 |   9 |   8 |      9
Counterfeiting          |   6 |   6 |   8 |   8 |   7 |   9 |  12 |   6 |  10 |  14 |  10 |   6 |  15 |  10 |   8 |      9
Crimes in general       |   9 |   9 |   9 |   8 |   8 |   9 |   9 |   9 |  10 |  11 |  11 |  10 |  10 |   9 |   9 |      9
Assaults                |   5 |   5 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   7 |   7 |   7 |   7 |   7 |   7 |   7 |      6
Crimes against life     |   5 |   4 |   5 |   5 |   4 |   5 |   4 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   6 |   5 |   5 |   6 |      5
Domiciliary trespass    |   2 |   2 |   3 |   2 |   3 |   2 |   3 |   3 |   3 |   4 |   4 |   4 |   4 |   4 |   4 |      3
Rebellion               |   1 |   1 |   1 |   2 |   1 |   2 |   1 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |      1.6
Insults                 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   1 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |   2 |      1.4
========================+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=============


If we remember that in 1890 persons from 12 to 18 years of age formed
12.75% of the population, [546] the study of this table will show how
large a part the young play in certain crimes, and in crime in general.
Still it must not be forgotten that criminal statistics include only a
part of the crimes really committed, and that this affects particularly
the figures for juvenile crime, since the persons injured make
complaint against the young less readily, on account of pity. [547]

According to the figures given below (which, it is true, only cover a
short period) juvenile delinquency in England has remained almost
stationary. [548] Here we must remember: first, the great number of
acquittals; second, that the criminality of the young is nowhere better
combated than in England with its system of Industrial and Reformatory
Schools; third, that industrialism has been prevalent in England longer
than elsewhere, and that the increase of criminality during the period
designated cannot be as great as in other less industrial countries.


England, 1893–1899. [549]

======================================+========+========+========+========+========+========+========
  Convicted under 21 Years of Age.    |  1893. |  1894. |  1895. |  1896. |  1897. |  1898. |  1899.
--------------------------------------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------
Convicted                             | 42,926 | 43,950 | 38,994 | 38,637 | 39,821 | 43,538 | 39,111
Sent to the Industrial schools        |  3,180 |  3,703 |  3,311 |  4,658 |  4,289 |  4,635 |  4,981
Correction made for those discharged  |        |        |        |        |        |        |
  under the S. J. A.[550]             |  4,255 |  4,543 |  5,125 |  5,955 |  6,640 |  7,114 |  7,547
--------------------------------------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------
      Total                           | 50,361 | 52,196 | 47,430 | 49,260 | 50,750 | 55,287 | 51,639
--------------------------------------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------+--------
To the 100,000                        | 169.39 | 173.63 | 156.05 | 160.26 | 163.33 | 175.98 | 162.57
======================================+========+========+========+========+========+========+========


Finally, the following table shows of what crimes the young are guilty
in England: [551]


England, 1893–1899.

===================================+======================================================================
                                   |      Number of Persons under 21 to the 100 Convictions.
-----------------------------------+-------+-------+-------+-------+-------+-------+-------+--------------
Years                              | 1893. | 1894. | 1895. | 1896. | 1897. | 1898. | 1899. | 1893 to 1899.
-----------------------------------+-------+-------+-------+-------+-------+-------+-------+--------------
Simple theft                       | 45.51 | 47.31 | 44.73 | 44.54 | 44.14 | 45.27 | 43.19 |    44.95
Theft by domestics                 | 41.07 | 43.17 | 40.26 | 43.12 | 42.60 | 42.71 | 40.70 |    41.80
House-breaking                     | 41.27 | 40.65 | 36.83 | 36.67 | 38.83 | 38.30 | 39.86 |    38.91
Theft upon the person              | 32.93 | 29.73 | 27.53 | 28.77 | 28.95 | 26.85 | 27.68 |    28.93
Malicious mischief                 | 21.51 | 25.95 | 22.89 | 19.98 | 27.22 | 29.29 | 26.82 |    24.80
Extortion                          | 26.61 | 28.99 | 25.35 | 27.22 | 16.42 | 23.26 | 21.60 |    23.92
Crimes against morals              | 25.44 | 23.73 | 23.57 | 23.07 | 23.22 | 22.23 | 21.96 |    23.32
Crimes committed with violence     | 20.48 | 22.33 | 22.76 | 25.82 | 24.69 | 23.82 | 22.77 |    23.23
Forgery                            | 14.01 | 15.56 | 18.62 | 14.34 | 10.63 | 16.74 | 14.64 |    14.93
Obtaining money by false pretenses | 14.12 | 13.98 | 14.75 | 13.80 | 14.04 | 11.56 | 12.02 |    13.46
Counterfeiting                     | 24.39 | 10.10 | 11.53 | 11.76 |  9.19 | 20.17 |  7.61 |    13.53
Assaults                           | 14.74 | 14.20 | 13.22 | 12.93 | 12.39 | 13.44 | 11.57 |    13.21
===================================+=======+=======+=======+=======+=======+=======+=======+===============



If we take into consideration the fact that generally about 23% of the
population are between the ages of 10 and 21, this table shows that
persons at this age have a large part in certain of the crimes.


Austria, 1881–1899 (Crimes). [552]

=======+==============================================
       |      Number of Young Persons Convicted.
       +----------+-----------+----------+------------
Years. | 11 to 14 | 14 to 20. |  Total.  | To the 1000
       |  Years.  |           |          |  Convicted.
-------+----------+-----------+----------+------------
 1881  |    460   |   5405    |   5865   |    17.5
 1882  |    525   |   5258    |   5783   |    18.0
 1883  |    525   |   5256    |   5781   |    19.0
 1884  |    579   |   5538    |   6117   |    19.9
 1885  |    566   |   5249    |   5815   |    18.8
 1886  |    546   |   5287    |   5833   |    19.6
 1887  |    625   |   5358    |   5983   |    20.8
 1888  |    593   |   5241    |   5834   |    20.8
 1889  |    614   |   5617    |   6231   |    21.8
 1890  |    578   |   6001    |   6579   |    22.6
 1891  |    650   |   5779    |   6429   |    22.2
 1892  |    803   |   6238    |   7041   |    22.8
 1893  |    842   |   5959    |   6801   |    23.2
 1894  |    826   |   6378    |   7204   |    23.9
 1895  |    766   |   5976    |   6742   |    23.5
 1896  |    818   |   5945    |   6763   |    23.5
 1897  |    812   |   6473    |   7285   |    24.5
 1898  |   1026   |   7569    |   8595   |    24.9
 1899  |   1015   |   6665    |   7680   |    22.8
=======+==========+===========+==========+============


Consequently there is here, too, both in absolute numbers and in
proportion to adult crime, an increase in juvenile criminality (about
23% in 18 years). Estimates of the number of non-criminal minors are
wanting to give us a complete picture. It must not be forgotten that
Austrian law ranks simple theft, fraud, assault, and the like as
“contraventions”, and that these do not figure in these statistics. The
total figures for young criminals are consequently much higher. [553]

The following table shows of what crimes the young are guilty:


Austria, 1882–1899. [554]

==================+=======================================================
                  |             Convicted from 1882 to 1899.
                  +-----------+-------------------------------------------
     Crimes.      |           |   Persons from 14 to 20 Years of Age.
                  |  Total.   +-------------------+-----------------------
                  |           | Absolute Numbers. | To the 1000 Convicted.
------------------+-----------+-------------------+-----------------------
Rape etc.         |   17,187  |       5,534       |        32.2
Aggravated theft  |  208,686  |      67,106       |        25.0
Extortion         |    2,257  |         547       |        24.2
Counterfeiting    |      642  |         113       |        17.6
Infanticide       |    1,734  |         302       |        17.4
Assassination     |    4,209  |         611       |        14.5
Serious assaults  |   85,055  |      12,202       |        14.3
Defamation        |    3,139  |         410       |        13.0
Homicide          |    2,478  |         312       |        12.6
Fraud             |   51,487  |       5,651       |        10.9
Leze-majesty      |    5,369  |         380       |         7.0
==================+===========+===================+=======================


Belgium, 1861–1885. [555]

=======+============+=============+=============+=============+======================
Years. |  Persons   |  Under 16.  |  16 to 21.  |  Under 21.  | Percentage of Accused
       |  Accused.  |             |             |             |   Persons under 21.
-------+------------+-------------+-------------+-------------+----------------------
 1861  |   24,673   |    1,043    |    2,429    |    3,472    |         14.1
 1862  |   25,357   |    1,224    |    2,355    |    2,579    |         14.1
 1863  |   24,133   |    1,206    |    2,456    |    3,662    |         15.1
 1864  |   24,185   |    1,245    |    2,307    |    3,552    |         14.6
 1865  |   24,236   |    1,115    |    2,483    |    3,598    |         14.8
 1866  |   24,608   |    1,141    |    2,396    |    3,537    |         14.3
 1867  |   25,041   |    1,220    |    2,750    |    3,970    |         15.8
 1868  |   27,469   |    1,500    |    3,064    |    4,565    |         16.6
 1869  |   27,883   |    1,107    |    2,923    |    4,030    |         14.9
 1870  |   26,507   |    1,298    |    3,075    |    4,373    |         16.4
 1871  |   28,819   |    1,550    |    3,344    |    4,894    |         16.9
 1872  |   28,047   |    1,336    |    3,255    |    4,597    |         16.3
 1873  |   29,569   |    1,448    |    3,451    |    4,899    |         16.5
 1874  |   31,653   |    1,261    |    3,408    |    4,669    |         14.7
 1875  |   30,867   |    1,371    |    3,767    |    5,138    |         16.6
 1876  |   33,366   |    1,445    |    4,363    |    5,808    |         17.4
 1877  |   37,964   |    2,183    |    5,096    |    7,279    |         19.1
 1878  |   37,348   |    1,994    |    5,245    |    7,239    |         19.3
 1879  |   36,614   |    1,873    |    5,074    |    6,947    |         18.9
 1880  |   41,653   |    2,546    |    5,680    |    8,226    |         19.7
 1881  |   44,361   |    2,634    |    6,271    |    8,905    |         20.0
 1882  |   45,895   |    2,695    |    6,487    |    9,182    |         20.0
 1883  |   45,325   |    2,681    |    6,942    |    9,623    |         21.2
 1884  |   45,665   |    3,325    |    7,063    |    9,388    |         20.5
 1885  |   46,479   |    2,398    |    7,279    |    9,677    |         20.8
=======+============+=============+=============+=============+======================


In Belgium, therefore, a great increase in the criminality of the young
has taken place.

For France we take the following figures showing the trend of
criminality from 1881 to 1900: [556]


France, 1881–1900.

Court of Assizes. Accused.

==========+=================+=================+=================+==================
          |    1881-1885.   |    1886-1890.   |    1891-1895.   |    1896-1900.
  Age.    +----------+------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+-------
          | Absolute |   %  | Absolute |   %  | Absolute |   %  | Absolute |   %
          | Number.  |      | Number.  |      | Number.  |      | Number.  |
----------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+-------
Under 16  |     32   |  0.7 |     31   |  0.7 |     31   |  0.7 |     26   |  0.7
16 to 21  |    750   | 17.1 |    618   | 14.5 |    631   | 15.6 |    574   | 16.8
          +----------+------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+-------
Under 21  |    782   | 17.8 |    649   | 15.2 |    662   | 16.3 |    600   | 17.5
==========+==========+======+==========+======+==========+======+==========+=======


When we take into consideration the fact that the population of France
has increased a little during the period in question, this table shows
a slight diminution in juvenile criminality. Nevertheless, this
diminution is smaller than that of criminality in general.


France, 1881–1900. [557]

Correctional Tribunals. Accused of Misdemeanors.

==========+=================+=================+=================+==================
          |    1881-1885.   |    1886-1890.   |    1891-1895.   |    1896-1900.
  Age.    +----------+------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+-------
          | Absolute |   %  | Absolute |   %  | Absolute |   %  | Absolute |   %
          | Number.  |      | Number.  |      | Number.  |      | Number.  |
----------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+-------
Under 16  |   5,846  |  3.0 |   6,980  |  3.4 |   6,903  |  3.2 |   5,776  |  2.9
16 to 21  |  28,688  | 15.1 |  27,309  | 13.6 |  31,119  | 14.8 |  30,415  | 15.7
----------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+------+----------+-------
Under 21  |  34,534  | 18.1 |  34,289  | 17.0 |  38,022  | 18.0 |  36,261  | 18.6
==========+==========+======+==========+======+==========+======+==========+=======


Here, then, we have once more a slight diminution in juvenile
criminality, but less great than that of criminality in general.

We should deceive ourselves if we saw in these figures the conclusive
proof that criminality on the part of the young was decreasing. We must
not overlook the fact that these figures do not include those
delinquents whose prosecution was not pushed, whether because they were
thought not to have understood the nature of their acts, or because the
offense was considered as too light. It is well known that judges
incline more and more to the opinion that it is better not to convict
youthful delinquents, but to send them to a house of correction, or to
place them under the care of a guardian. [558] What the figures given
above show is that the increase of juvenile criminality has not been as
great in France as it has been in Germany. (I have not the figures for
child labor in France, but probably the increase is not as great as it
has been in Germany, which is more of an industrial country. The
difference, then, in the juvenile crime of the two countries would be
explained, at least in part.) [559]

Finally, the following figures will show of what crimes and
misdemeanors the young delinquents are guilty:


France, 1900. [560]

=======================================+==========+===========+===========
            Crimes.                    |  Total   |  Number   | Percentage
                                       | Accused. | under 21. |  under 21.
---------------------------------------+----------+-----------+-----------
Aggravated theft                       |   1300   |    367    |    28.2
Rape and indecent assault upon adults  |     65   |     18    |    27.6
Counterfeiting                         |    120   |     27    |    22.5
Infanticide                            |     95   |     21    |    22.1
Assaults                               |    203   |     33    |    16.2
Homicide                               |    620   |    100    |    16.1
Arson                                  |    157   |     19    |    12.1
Rape etc., upon children               |    383   |     42    |    10.9
=======================================+==========+===========+===========


France, 1900. [561]

Correctional Tribunals. Persons Arraigned.

=======================================+============+===========+===========
       Misdemeanors.                   |   Total    |  Number   | Percentage
                                       | Arraigned. | under 21. |  under 21.
---------------------------------------+------------+-----------+-----------
Thefts                                 |   42,127   |   12,483  |    29.6
Sexual offenses                        |    2,939   |      643  |    21.8
Rebellion                              |    3,315   |      676  |    20.3
Assaults                               |   36,592   |    6,600  |    18.0
Vagrancy                               |   11,804   |    1,914  |    16.2
Obtaining money under false pretenses  |    3,179   |      376  |    11.8
Mendicity                              |    9,057   |      778  |     8.5
=======================================+============+===========+=============


As in most countries it is theft, violence, and sexual offenses of
which the young delinquents are most often guilty in France.


Italy, 1887–1889. [562]

=======+================================================================================================
       |                         Persons Convicted Under the Age of 21.
       +----------------------++-----------------------++-----------------------++----------------------
Years. | Up to the Age of 14. ||    From 14 to 18.     ||    From 18 to 21.     ||        Total.
       +----------------------++-----------------------++-----------------------++----------------------
       |    A   |   B  |   D  ||   A    |   C  |   E   ||  A    |   C   |   E   ||  A    |   C   |   F
-------+--------+------+------++--------+------+-------++-------+-------+-------++-------+-------+------
 1887  |  4,566 | 1.48 | 1.60 || 22,361 | 7.24 | 10.55 ||36,871 | 11.93 | 24.52 ||63,798 | 20.65 |  9.85
 1888  |  5,743 | 1.72 | 2.01 || 22,991 | 6.90 | 10.84 ||42,436 | 12.73 | 28.23 ||71,171 | 21.35 | 10.99
 1889  |  6,426 | 1.88 | 2.25 || 24,229 | 7.08 | 11.43 ||38,697 | 11.30 | 25.24 ||69,352 | 20.26 | 10.71
=======+========+======+======++========+======+=======++=======+=======+=======++=======+=======+======

KEY TO COLUMN HEADINGS:

A = Absolute Number.
B = To the 100 Persons Convicted.
C = To the 100 Convicted.
D = To the 1000 of the Population from 9 to 14.
E = To the 1000 of the Population of this Age.
F = To the 1000 of the Population under 21.


This table shows that the increase of delinquents under 18 is quite
large, and that there is an increase followed by a decrease of
criminality among those between the ages of 18 and 21. However, the
period is too short for conclusions of much significance.


Italy, 1890–1895. [563]

======+==========================================================
      |                  Persons Convicted.
      +-------------++-------------++-------------++-------------
Years.|From 9 to 14.||  14 to 18.  ||  18 to 21.  ||  9 to 21.
      +-------+-----++-------+-----++-------+-----++-------+-----
      |Number.|  %  ||Number.|  %  ||Number.|  %  ||Number.|  %
------+-------+-----++-------+-----++-------+-----++-------+-----
 1890 | 2,920 | 2.23|| 12,208| 9.31|| 14,980|11.42|| 30,108|22.96
 1891 | 3,605 | 2.50|| 14,287| 9.95|| 16,166|11.25|| 34,058|23.70
 1892 | 3,354 | 2.25|| 13,952| 9.36|| 16,896|11.34|| 34,202|22.95
 1893 | 3,008 | 2.12|| 12,998| 9.18|| 15,800|11.16|| 31,806|22.46
 1894 | 3,838 | 2.54|| 13,948| 9.21|| 17,826|11.77|| 35,612|23.52
 1895 | 4,026 | 2.40|| 15,468| 9.21|| 19,615|11.67|| 39,109|23.28
======+=======+=====++=======+=====++=======+=====++=======+=====


This table shows (except for 1893) an increase in the number of young
delinquents (about 30% in 6 years), a phenomenon by no means accounted
for by the increase in the population.

The following figures show the crimes of which the young delinquents
are especially guilty.


Italy, 1891–1895. [564]

==========================================+==============================
                                          |To 100,000 of Each Age Group.
                 Crimes.                  +----------+---------+---------
                                          | 9 to 14. |14 to 18.|18 to 21.
------------------------------------------+----------+---------+---------
Simple theft                              |  59.50   | 278.89  | 302.86
Minor assaults                            |  14.64   |  83.40  | 215.04
Aggravated theft                          |  30.95   | 128.96  | 157.28
Rebellion                                 |   1.25   |  24.94  |  83.58
Serious assaults                          |   5.22   |  28.56  |  82.07
Threats                                   |   1.11   |  15.10  |  47.71
Obtaining money under false pretenses etc.|   1.54   |  13.96  |  30.00
Homicide                                  |   0.49   |   3.97  |  15.78
Rape                                      |   1.02   |   6.36  |   9.62
Extortion, blackmail                      |   0.41   |   3.55  |   9.07
Offenses against chastity of minors and   |          |         |
  against public decency                  |   0.38   |   2.93  |   5.70
Offenses against public order             |   1.01   |   2.14  |   4.95
Assassination                             |   0.07   |   0.75  |   3.55
Infanticide                               |   0.01   |   0.02  |   0.36
==========================================+==========+=========+=========


We will close the series of statistics concerning juvenile criminality
with some figures from the Netherlands. [565]


Netherlands, 1896–1900. [566]

======+=================================================
      |                   Convicted.
Years.+-------+---------+---------+---------+-----------
      |Total. |Under 16.|16 to 21.|Under 21.|% under 21.
------+-------+---------+---------+---------+-----------
 1896 |15,567 |   683   |  2,941  |  3,624  |   23.2
 1897 |16,086 |   666   |  3,024  |  3,690  |   22.9
 1898 |15,662 |   712   |  2,967  |  3,679  |   23.4
 1899 |15,390 |   619   |  2,895  |  3,514  |   22.4
 1900 |14,488 |   537   |  2,670  |  3,207  |   22.8
======+=======+=========+=========+=========+===========


Netherlands, 1901–1910. [567]

======+================================
      |           Convicted.
Years.+------+--------------+----------
      |Total.|Under 16 Years|Percentage
      |      |   of Age.    |Under 16.
------+------+--------------+----------
 1901 |13,917|     651      |   4.7
 1902 |14,205|     683      |   4.8
 1903 |13,673|     645      |   4.7
 1904 |14,056|     667      |   4.7
 1905 |13,310|     592      |   4.4
 1906 |12,311|     589      |   4.7
 1907 |12,182|     588      |   4.8
 1908 |13,563|     544      |   4.1
 1909 |13,361|     649      |   4.8
 1910 |13,790|     800      |   5.8
======+======+==============+==========


Juvenile criminality has not changed much, then, as compared with the
criminality of adults. As I have already observed above, there is
reason to suppose that the real facts are different, especially after
1905, when the new law with regard to juvenile crime was put into
effect.

The following figures show what crimes are most often committed by the
young delinquents.


Netherlands, 1896–1901.

====================+=================================
                    |Average for the Period 1896–1901.
                    +----------------------+----------
      Crimes.       |  Number Convicted.   |Percentage
                    +----------+-----------+under 21.
                    |  Total.  | Under 21. |
--------------------+----------+-----------+----------
Aggravated theft    |    894   |     416   |   46.4
Sexual offenses     |    202   |      63   |   31.1
Theft               |  1,713   |     526   |   30.7
Malicious mischief  |    756   |     226   |   29.9
Assault             |  3,927   |   1,030   |   26.2
Domiciliary trespass|    318   |      72   |   22.6
Rebellion           |  1,056   |     216   |   20.4
====================+==========+===========+==========


Keeping constantly in mind that in our days juvenile criminals are less
often sentenced than formerly, we shall find that the foregoing
statistics show:

First. That juvenile crime is increasing.

Second. That this increase is considerable in the countries like
Germany, Austria, and Belgium, where there is a continuous industrial
development; while in countries less developed industrially the
increase is less.

Third. That England, where the capitalism is very intense, shows a
great amount of juvenile crime.

The figures we have given have in general, in my opinion, gone to
support the incontestable truth, that there is a relation between child
labor and juvenile criminality. Although it is of smaller importance
than the lack of care of the children among the proletariat, it is
still one of the factors in the etiology of crime. [568]

Following the order adopted in Part II, chapter I, we come now to the
influence of long hours of labor. It has rightly been said that work
has a strong moral influence. But it is also true that immoderate labor
has the contrary effect. It brutalizes a man, makes him incapable of
elevated sentiments, kills as Key says (in “das Jahrhundert des
Kindes”), the man in the beast, while moderate labor ennobles the beast
in the man. [569]

The housing conditions of the proletariat have also a significance as
regards criminality, and for the special group of sexual offenses their
importance is very great. We shall speak of this more fully when we
treat especially of these offenses, and will, for the moment, note
simply their general consequences.

The disorder and squalor of the home communicate themselves to the
inmates; the lack of room obliges the children to live, during a great
part of the day, on the streets, with the result that they are brought
into contact with all sorts of demoralizing companions. Finally, the
living together of a great number of uneducated persons in one small
dwelling is the cause of constant quarrels and fights. The situation of
those who are merely night-lodgers is especially unfortunate, as we
have already seen.

In Part I we have quoted from authors who have laid stress upon the
importance of the question of housing conditions in the study of
criminality (Hirsch, for example), and we have indicated the gravity of
this cause in speaking of prostitution and alcoholism.

It would be possible to quote a number of authors who have taken up the
effect of housing conditions upon morals. [570] However, it is
naturally very difficult to express this influence in figures. As far
as I know it is Dr. E. Laspeyres who (in “Der Einfluss der Wohnung auf
die Sittlichkeit”) gives the most significant data upon this subject. I
borrow from him the following figures: summarizing part of the results
of a study of “Furnished Rooms” in 2,360 dwellings: [571]


Paris, 1849.

Table I.

================================+==========+===============================
                                |          |    Conduct of the Inmates.
                                |          +---------------+---------------
        Arrondissements.        |   Good   |     Men.      |    Women.
                                |Dwellings.+---------------+---------------
                                |    %     |Good.|Very Bad.|Good.|Very Bad.
                                |          |  %  |    %    |  %  |    %
--------------------------------+----------+-----+---------+-----+---------
The 6 arrondissements with the  |          |     |         |     |
  smallest number of good       |          |     |         |     |
  dwellings                     |   35     |  46 |   10    | 20.4|   19
                                |          |     |         |     |
The 6 arrondissements with the  |          |     |         |     |
  largest number of good        |   44.5   |  50 |    2.5  | 21.7|   14
  dwellings                     |          |     |         |     |
--------------------------------+----------+-----+---------+-----+---------
The 12 arrondissements together |   39     |  48 |    6.4  | 21.0|   16.6
================================+==========+=====+=========+=====+=========
The figures cited above in      |}  89     |  96 |  156    | 97  |  114
  proportion to all Paris = 100 |} 114     | 104 |   39    |103  |   86
                                +----------+-----+---------+-----+---------
                                |  100     | 100 |  100    |100  |  100
================================+==========+=====+=========+=====+=========


Table II. [572]

================================+==========+===============================
                                |          |    Conduct of the Inmates.
                                |          +---------------+---------------
        Arrondissements.        | Very Bad |     Men.      |    Women.
                                |Dwellings.+---------+-----+---------+-----
                                |    %     |Very Bad.|Good.|Very Bad.|Good.
                                |          |    %    |  %  |    %    |  %
--------------------------------+----------+---------+-----+---------+-----
The 6 arrondissements with the  |          |         |     |         |
  greatest number of very bad   |          |         |     |         |
  dwellings                     |   13.6   |    9    | 45  |   20.2  | 21.3
                                |          |         |     |         |
The 6 arrondissements with the  |          |         |     |         |
  smallest number of very bad   |          |         |     |         |
  dwellings                     |    6.0   |    2.2  | 52  |   11.7  | 21.0
--------------------------------+----------+---------+-----+---------+-----
The 12 arrondissements together |   11     |    6.4  | 48  |   16.6  | 21.0
================================+==========+=========+=====+=========+=====
The figures cited above in      |} 124     |   141   | 94  |  122    |101
  proportion to all Paris = 100 |}  55     |    34   |108  |   70    |100
                                +----------+---------+-----+---------+-----
                                |  100     |   100   |100  |  100    |100
================================+==========+=========+=====+=========+=====


Table III. [573]

=====================================+===========+===============================================
                                     |           |           Conduct of the Inmates.
                                     |           +----------------------+------------------------
                                     | Good and  |        Men.          |         Women.
                                     |Rather Good+----------------------+------------+-----------
         Arrondissements.            | Dwellings.| Good and   | Bad and |  Good and  |  Bad and
                                     |           |Rather Good.|Very Bad.|Rather Good.| Very Bad.
                                     |     %     |     %      |    %    |      %     |      %
-------------------------------------+-----------+------------+---------+------------+-----------
The 6 arrondissements with the       |           |            |         |            |
  smallest number of good and        |           |            |         |            |
  rather good dwellings              |     75    |     70     |    30   |      50    |     50
                                     |           |            |         |            |
The 6 arrondissements with the       |           |            |         |            |
  greatest number of good and        |           |            |         |            |
  rather good dwellings              |     86    |     81     |    19   |      58    |     42
-------------------------------------+-----------+------------+---------+------------+-----------
The 12 arrondissements together      |     80    |     74.5   |    25.5 |      53    |     47
=====================================+===========+============+=========+============+===========
The figures cited above in proportion| }   94    |     94     |   118   |      96    |    106
  to all Paris = 100                 | }  107    |    109     |    71   |     109    |     91
                                     +-----------+------------+---------+------------+-----------
                                     |    100    |    100     |   100   |     100    |    100
=====================================+===========+============+=========+============+===========


Although the division according to good and bad conduct is somewhat
arbitrary, and although it is impossible to separate the effect of bad
housing from other influences operative at the same time, yet these
figures say plainly: there is a relationship between housing and
conduct. It is evident that there is a reciprocal effect between the
condition of the dwelling and the conduct of the inmates, but this fact
does not diminish the influence of the dwelling. [574]

Finally, we add some figures upon the influence of furnished rooms as
residence, summarizing the results of an inquiry into industries in
Paris, made in 1860 and including 400,000 persons: [575]


Paris, 1860.

I. Men.

================+=====================+====================
  Occupations.  | In Furnished Rooms. | Conduct Doubtful
                |                     |    or Bad.
----------------+---------------------+--------------------
                |          %          |          %
 90 occupations |          5          |          3
 90     ,,      |         14          |          9
 90     ,,      |         28          |         12
----------------+---------------------+-------------------
270 occupations |         20          |          9
================+=====================+===================


Proportion to all the occupations = 100.

================+=====+=====
 90 occupations |  25 |  13
 90     ,,      |  70 | 100
 90     ,,      | 140 | 133
----------------+-----+-----
270 occupations | 100 | 100
================+=====+=====


II. Women.

================+=====================+==================
Occupations.    | In Furnished Rooms. | Conduct Doubtful
                |                     | or Bad.
----------------+---------------------+------------------
                |          %          |       %
110 occupations |         --          |       3
 60     ,,      |          4          |       6
 60     ,,      |         14          |      15
----------------+---------------------+------------------
230 occupations |          7          |       9
================+=====================+==================


Proportion to the Average of the 230 occupations = 100.

================+=====+=====
110 occupations |   0 |  33
 60     ,,      |  59 |  68
 60     ,,      | 206 | 169
----------------+-----+-----
230 occupations | 100 | 100
================+=====+=====


The evil influence of living in furnished rooms comes out plainly in
these figures.

As has already been said at the beginning of these observations as to
the influence of the economic life upon the development of social
feelings on the part of the proletariat, the egoistic side of the human
character is developed by the fact that the individual is dependent,
that he lives in a subordinate position, and that he feels himself poor
and deprived of everything. However, in so far as the proletarian sells
his labor he is guaranteed against famine, however miserable his
condition, and conscious of the utility of his rôle in society, he
feels himself, notwithstanding his poverty, a man who, except for his
employer, is independent of all men. But if work is not to be found, or
if the proletarian, sick and infirm, is not able to work, it goes
without saying that the resulting unemployment is very demoralizing.
The lack of steady work, the horrors of the penury into which he and
his fall, and the long train of evils which result from both, kill the
social feelings in a man, for, as we have seen above, these feelings
depend upon reciprocity. Let one familiarize himself with the thought
of the condition of the man who lives in the greatest poverty, i.e. the
man who is abandoned by all, and he will understand how egoistic must
be the feelings of such.

From the position in which the proletarians find themselves it follows
that, towards each other, it is rather the altruistic than the egoistic
feelings that develop; living less isolated than the bourgeois, they
see the misfortune that strikes their neighbor, and have felt the same
themselves, and above all, their economic interests are not opposed.
Forced idleness—at present chronic, and acute in times of
panic—modifies these conditions at times; it makes competitors of the
workers, who take the bread out of each other’s mouths. [576]

The proletarian is never sure of his existence: like the sword of
Damocles unemployment is constantly hanging over his head. Upon this
subject Engels says:

“But far more demoralizing than his poverty in its influence upon the
English working man is the insecurity of his position, the necessity of
living upon wages from hand to mouth, that in short which makes a
proletarian of him. The smaller peasants in Germany are usually poor,
and often suffer want, but they are less at the mercy of accident, they
have at least something secure. The proletarian, who has nothing but
his two hands, who consumes today what he earned yesterday, who is
subject to every chance, and has not the slightest guarantee for being
able to earn the barest necessities of life, whom every crisis, every
whim of his employer may deprive of bread, this proletarian is placed
in the most revolting, inhuman position conceivable for a human being.”
[577]

This uncertainty of existence is one of the reasons which explain why,
in relatively prosperous times the working-man often spends his wages
as soon as he receives them, for he knows that the economies possible
to him are so small that he could never be saved from misery in case of
unemployment.

Finally we must speak of ignorance and lack of training on the part of
the proletariat, as a factor of criminality. As we know, this question
of education is one of those which are most debated in criminal
sociology. Certain authors have prophesied that each new school would
make a prison superfluous, while on the other hand it has been claimed
that ignorance and the lack of civilization have nothing to do with the
etiology of crime, but that on the contrary knowledge and civilization
are even factors of crime. Although these extreme opinions are hardly
ever expressed nowadays, the ideas upon the point in question still
differ widely. [578]

In my opinion, no really decisive arguments have ever been adduced for
the opinion that the intellectual condition of men has no influence
upon criminality. In general the reasoning is as follows: ignorance is
decreasing; crime on the contrary increases; ignorance cannot therefore
be a factor. Such a line of argument is very superficial, for ignorance
is surely not the only cause of crime. Its influence may therefore be
neutralized by other factors. And further, from the point of view of
statistics it is not permissible to use the indirect method when the
direct method is practicable. In most criminal and prison statistics
the percentage of the illiterate among the criminals is given, and we
have only to put beside these figures those for the illiterate among
the non-criminal population to be convinced of the existence or absence
of the connection in dispute.

We shall begin, then, by giving the figures that we know.


United States, 1890. [579]

=========================================+==================
      To 82,329 Prisoners there were     |   To 100 of the
------------+------------------+---------+  Population over
            | Absolute Number. |    %    |  Age of 10 Years.
------------+------------------+---------+------------------
Illiterate  |      19,631      |  23.83  |      13.3
============+==================+=========+==================


Austria, 1881–1899. [580]

==========+=======================================================
          |          To 100 Persons Convicted of Crimes.
  Years.  +-------------------+------------------+----------------
          | Unable to Read or | Able to Read and | Having a Higher
          |      Write.       |       Write.     |   Education.
----------+-------------------+------------------+----------------
1881-1885 |       46.2        |       53.5       |      0.2
1886-1890 |       41.0        |       58.7       |      0.3
1891-1895 |       37.5        |       62.2       |      0.2
  1896    |       33.0        |       60.3       |      0.7
  1897    |       34.9        |       64.4       |      0.7
  1898    |       33.2        |       66.1       |      0.7
  1899    |       33.0        |       66.2       |      0.8
==========+===================+==================+================


England and Wales, 1894–1900. [581]

========+==============================================================================================================================================================================================================++==============
 Years. |                          Prisoners Found Guilty.                                                                                                                                                             || Percentage
        |                                                                                                                                                                                                              || of Persons
        +---------------------------------------------------++---------------------------------------------------++-------------------------------------------------++-------------------------------------------------++ Wishing to
        | Unable to Read or Write.                          || Able to Read, or to Read Poorly                   || Able to Read and Write Well.                    || Having a Higher Education.                      ||  Marry who
        |                                                   || and Write.                                        ||                                                 ||                                                 || were Unable
        +---------------------------------------------------++---------------------------------------------------++-------------------------------------------------++-------------------------------------------------++   to Sign
        | Men.                    | Women.                  || Men.                    | Women.                  || Men.                   | Women.                 || Men.                   | Women.                 || their Names.
        +-------------------------+-------------------------++-------------------------+-------------------------++------------------------+------------------------++------------------------+------------------------++---------------
        | Absolute Number. | %    | Absolute Number. | %    || Absolute Number. | %    | Absolute Number. | %    || Absolute Number. | %   | Absolute Number. | %   || Absolute Number. | %   | Absolute Number. | %   || Men. | Women.
--------+------------------+------+------------------+------++------------------+------+------------------+------++------------------+-----+------------------+-----++------------------+-----+------------------+-----++------+--------
1893    |   --             |  --  |   --             |  --  ||   --             |  --  |   --             |  --  ||   --             |  -- |  --              |  -- ||  --              | --  | --               | --  || 5.0  | 5.7
1894    | 20,760           | 18.4 | 11,457           | 27.4 || 86,639           | 76.6 | 29,620           | 70.7 || 5,554            | 4.9 | 797              | 1.9 || 102              | 0.1 |  3               | 0.0 || 0.0  | --
1895    | 18,840           | 18.2 | 11,143           | 27.8 || 80,409           | 77.9 | 28,511           | 71.2 || 3,879            | 3.8 | 386              | 1.0 ||  89              | 0.1 |  2               | 0.0 || 0.0  | --
1896    | 19,377           | 18.1 | 11,844           | 28.5 || 85,199           | 79.2 | 29,261           | 70.6 || 2,806            | 2.6 | 307              | 0.7 ||  52              | 0.1 |  2               | 0.0 || 0.0  | --
1897    | 18,588           | 17.4 | 11,783           | 27.8 || 84,777           | 79.7 | 30,290           | 71.4 || 2,980            | 2.8 | 344              | 0.8 ||  68              | 0.1 |  4               | 0.0 || 0.0  | --
1898    | 18,591           | 16.6 | 12,092           | 26.8 || 86,675           | 77.3 | 32,350           | 71.6 || 6,680            | 6.0 | 726              | 1.6 || 158              | 0.1 |  7               | 0.0 || 0.0  | --
1899    | 17,703           | 16.3 | 11,483           | 25.3 || 84,854           | 78.4 | 35,114           | 73.0 || 5,658            | 5.2 | 740              | 1.6 ||  84              | 0.1 |  6               | 0.0 || 0.0  | --
1900    | 16,583           | 16.6 | 11,519           | 25.3 || 77,967           | 77.8 | 33,169           | 73.5 || 5,460            | 5.5 | 420              | 0.9 ||  81              | 0.1 |  5               | 0.6 || 2.9  | 3.4
========+==================+======+==================+======++==================+======+==================+======++==================+=====+==================+=====++==================+=====+==================+=====++======+========


The following table gives the figures for the different crimes:


Austria, 1899. [582]

=========================+=========================================================
                         |                To 100 Persons Convicted.
        Crimes.          +-------------+---------------+--------------+------------
                         | Illiterate. | Able to Read. | Able to Read | Higher
                         |             |               | and Write.   | Education.
-------------------------+-------------+---------------+--------------+------------
Arson                    | 44.2        | 2.6           | 53.2         | 0.0
Libel                    | 41.7        | 0.8           | 57.1         | 0.4
Assault                  | 40.5        | 1.4           | 58.0         | 0.1
Infanticide              | 39.5        | 2.6           | 57.9         | 0.0
Homicide                 | 39.3        | 3.1           | 57.4         | 0.2
Robbery                  | 35.0        | 1.6           | 63.4         | 0.0
Theft                    | 32.6        | 1.2           | 65.7         | 0.5
All crimes               | 31.7        | 1.3           | 66.2         | 0.8
Fraud                    | 30.8        | 1.3           | 66.2         | 2.7
Extortion                | 27.3        | 1.5           | 70.4         | 0.8
Malicious mischief       | 21.6        | 1.1           | 77.3         | 0.0
Threats                  | 21.0        | 1.7           | 76.9         | 0.4
Leze majesty             | 19.7        | 1.6           | 76.2         | 2.5
Rape, etc.               | 17.2        | 1.7           | 79.3         | 1.8
Criminal breach of trust |  6.0        | 0.2           | 86.4         | 7.4
=========================+=============+===============+==============+============


Belgium, 1899–1901.

==========+=================================================================
          |                     Persons Convicted.
          +-------------+--------------+--------------+------------+--------
  Years.  | Illiterate. | Able to Read | Able to Read | Having a   | Total.
          |             | or Write     | and Write.   | Higher     |
          |             | Imperfectly. |              | Education. |
----------+-------------+--------------+--------------+------------+--------
1899      |  588        | 1389         |  424         | 144        |  2545
1900      |  626        | 1444         |  521         | 176        |  2767
1901      |  619        | 1581         |  604         | 218        |  3022
1899-1901 | 1833        | 4414         | 1549         | 538        |  8334
----------+-------------+--------------+--------------+------------+--------
    %     | 22.--       | 53.--        | 18.6         | 6.4        | 100.0
==========+=============+==============+==============+============+========


According to the census of 1900, 18% of the total male population over
15 years old were completely illiterate. [583]

In 1907 1.32% of the men and 1.75% of the women out of the total
population could not sign their names. [584]


France, 1882–1898. [585]

=======+============================================================================================================+================
       |                             To the 100 Prisoners there were on Entering Prison                             | Number of
       |                                                                                                            | Persons to the
       +----------------+----------------+----------------+----------------+--------------------+-------------------+ 100, who could
Years. | Illiterate.    | Able to Read.  | Able to Read   | Able to Read,  | Having a Complete  | Having an         | not sign their
       |                |                | and Write.     | Write and      | Primary Education. | Education Higher  |   Names when
       |                |                |                | Cipher.        |                    | than Primary.     | they Married.
       +-------+--------+-------+--------+-------+--------+-------+--------+-------+------------+------+------------+-------+--------
       | Men.  | Women. | Men.  | Women. | Men.  | Women. | Men.  | Women. | Men.  | Women.     | Men. | Women.     | Men.  | Women.
-------+-------+--------+-------+--------+-------+--------+-------+--------+-------+------------+------+------------+-------+--------
1882   | 27.60 | 38.04  | 12.62 | 15.41  | 30.56 | 32.36  | 21.17 | 13.01  |  6.24 | 0.87       | 1.81 | 0.31       | 14.4  | 22.6
1883   | 30.08 | 36.11  | 11.91 | 16.78  | 30.48 | 30.60  | 19.00 | 15.28  |  6.60 | 0.87       | 1.93 | 0.36       | 14.2  | 22.4
1884   | 27.54 | 42.61  | 10.14 | 15.02  | 31.71 | 30.57  | 21.67 |  9.93  |  5.72 | 1.39       | 2.18 | 0.46       | 13.6  | 22.2
1885   | 28.44 | 40.25  | 10.19 | 16.15  | 30.02 | 33.53  | 23.55 |  9.17  |  5.33 | 0.69       | 2.47 | 0.21       | 12.7  | 20.2
1886   | 26.63 | 39.93  | 11.20 | 14.52  | 31.19 | 36.64  | 22.81 |  8.06  |  5.63 | 0.85       | 2.54 |  --[#]     | 11.6  | 18.7
1887   | 26.51 | 37.49  | 12.49 | 14.31  | 33.89 | 38.90  | 21.04 |  8.38  |  4.05 | 0.92       | 2.02 |  --        | 10.7  | 17.0
1888   | 24.90 | 32.29  | 14.05 | 12.92  | 32.50 | 42.43  | 22.50 | 10.77  |  4.18 | 1.59       | 2.17 |  --        | 10.6  | 16.2
1889   | 22.50 | 35.13  | 14.18 | 27.22  | 30.06 | 27.78  | 24.99 |  7.70  |  5.80 | 2.17       | 2.47 |  --        |  9.8  | 15.2
1890   | 20.12 | 34.94  | 14.19 | 26.34  | 30.76 | 29.71  | 25.97 |  6.47  |  6.34 | 2.54       | 2.52 |  --        |  8.8  | 13.6
1891   | 20.05 | 33.32  | 12.79 | 22.44  | 31.14 | 33.39  | 26.52 |  8.37  |  6.57 | 2.06       | 2.93 | 0.42       |  8.4  | 12.6
1892   | 20.38 | 33.80  | 13.24 | 24.89  | 28.29 | 30.60  | 28.30 |  7.34  |  6.33 | 2.64       | 3.46 | 0.73       |  8.1  | 12.1
1893   | 22.08 | 29.78  | 11.19 | 24.75  | 28.03 | 32.75  | 27.33 |  9.22  |  7.51 | 2.82       | 3.86 | 0.68       |  --   |  --
1894   | 20.89 | 31.14  | 13.15 | 22.57  | 27.64 | 35.86  | 27.84 |  7.42  |  6.70 | 2.47       | 3.78 | 0.54       |  6.8  | 10.4
1895   | 20.50 | 30.43  | 13.80 | 18.82  | 26.66 | 38.39  | 30.15 |  9.80  |  6.41 | 2.32       | 2.48 | 0.24       |  --   |  --
1896   | 20.91 | 28.58  | 11.97 | 17.09  | 31.00 | 38.70  | 23.78 | 12.04  | 10.40 | 3.22       | 1.94 | 0.37       |  --   |  --
1897   | 21.09 | 28.57  | 10.59 | 15.67  | 27.77 | 40.48  | 30.40 | 12.10  |  8.15 | 2.48       | 2.00 | 0.69       |  --   |  --
1898   | 23.70 | 31.65  |  9.11 |  8.70  | 31.05 | 46.67  | 27.77 |  8.69  |  6.81 | 3.65       | 1.56 | 0.69       |  4.5  |  7.2
=======+=======+========+=======+========+=======+========+=======+========+=======+============+======+============+=======+========


Scotland. [587]

========================+=====================================
                        |              Prisoners.
                        |------------------+------------------
                        |        Men.      |       Women.
                        |----------+-------+----------+-------
                        | Absolute |   %   | Absolute |   %
                        | Numbers. |       | Numbers. |
------------------------+----------+-------+----------+-------
Illiterate              |  3,807   |  12.0 |  2,635   |  20.5
Able to read and write  | 27,849   |  87.9 | 10,245   |  79.5
With a higher education |     46   |   0.1 |      1   |   0.0
                        +----------+-------+----------+-------
    Total               | 31,702   | 100.0 | 12,881   | 100.0
========================+==========+=======+==========+=======


France, 1896–1900. [588]

============================+==================
                            | Percentage
                            |  of Accused
        Crimes.             |    Persons
                            | Completely
                            | Illiterate.
----------------------------+-----------------
Arson                       |    26
Infanticide                 |    21
Poisoning                   |    20
Rape and indecent assault   |
  upon children             |    20
Serious assaults            |    16
Murder                      |    16
Homicide                    |    15
Rape, etc. upon adults      |    14
All crimes                  |    14
Aggravated theft            |    12
Parricide                   |    10
Assaults upon parents, etc. |    10
Fraudulent bankruptcy       |    10
Highway robbery             |     8
Counterfeiting              |     7
Forgery, etc.               |     2
Breach of trust             |     2
============================+===================


Ireland, 1905.

============================+========================================================
                            |                       Prisoners.
                            +------------------+------------------+------------------
                            |      Men.        |      Women.      |      Total.
                            +----------+-------+----------+-------+----------+-------
                            | Absolute |       | Absolute |       | Absolute |
                            | Numbers. |   %   | Numbers. |   %   | Numbers. |   %
----------------------------+----------+-------+----------+-------+----------+-------
Illiterate                  |  4,321   |  22.5 |  3,264   |  32.5 |  7,585   |  25.9
Able to read, or read and   |          |       |          |       |          |
  write imperfectly         |  3,804   |  19.8 |  1,983   |  19.8 |  5,787   |  19.8
Able to read and write well | 11,003   |  57.2 |  4,757   |  47.4 | 15,760   |  53.9
With a higher education     |     93   |   0.5 |     32   |   0.3 |    125   |   0.4
Unknown                     |      2   |   0.0 |     --   |    -- |      2   |   0.0
                            +----------+-------+----------+-------+----------+-------
    Total                   | 19,223   | 100.0 | 10,036   | 100.0 | 29,259   | 100.0
============================+==========+=======+==========+=======+==========+=======


According to the census of 1901 the percentage of illiterates was 12.2
for the men, 13.1 for the women, and 12.7 for the total population 12
years old and over. [589]


Italy, 1881–1889. [590]


======+=====================================++===============================+================
      |       Correctional Tribunals.       ||           Assizes.            | To 100 Married
      +-------------------------------------++-------------------------------+ there were the
      |     To 100 Arraigned there were     ||  To 100 Convicted there were  | Following who
Years.|                                     ||                               |were Illiterate.
      +-----------+-----+--------+----------++-----------+--------+----------+------+---------
      |           |Able |Able to |  Having  ||           |Able to |  Having  | Men  |
      |Illiterate.| to  |Read and| a Higher ||Illiterate.|Read and| a Higher | and  | Men.[591]
      |           |Read.| Write. |Education.||           | Write. |Education.|Women.|
------+-----------+-----+--------+----------++-----------+--------+----------+------+---------
 1881 |   68.38   | 1.74|  27.38 |   2.50   ||   63.40   |  34.87 |   1.73   | 59.07|  48.24
 1882 |   67.93   | 1.61|  27.59 |   2.87   ||   59.05   |  38.11 |   2.84   | 57.43|  46.68
 1883 |   66.45   | 1.82|  28.74 |   2.99   ||   57.64   |  40.00 |   2.36   | 56.67|  45.79
 1884 |   64.61   | 1.71|  30.10 |   3.58   ||   58.99   |  38.76 |   2.25   | 55.81|  44.97
 1885 |   60.93   | 1.80|  32.90 |   4.37   ||   61.24   |  36.75 |   2.01   | 54.92|  44.28
 1886 |   61.34   | 2.20|  33.15 |   3.31   ||   59.66   |  38.25 |   2.09   | 53.31|  43.19
 1887 |   59.25   |  -- |  37.07 |   3.68   ||   59.34   |  37.04 |   3.62   | 52.83|  42.83
 1888 |   61.48   |  -- |  34.51 |   4.01   ||   69.14   |  31.99 |   3.87   | 52.08|  42.27
 1889 |   60.98   |  -- |  35.31 |   3.71   ||   63.75   |  33.14 |   3.11   | 50.83|  41.21
======+===========+=====+========+==========++===========+========+==========+======+=========


The following figures shed light upon the intellectual condition of
those accused of certain important classes of crime:


Italy, 1889 (Assizes). [592]

====================================+===========================================
                                    |To the 100 Accused of Each Crime there were
              Crimes.               +-------------+------------+----------------
                                    |Illiterate or|Able to Read|Having a Higher
                                    | Nearly So.  | and Write. |  Education.
------------------------------------+-------------+------------+----------------
Infanticide                         |    92.9     |     7.1    |       0.0
Perjury                             |    86.8     |    11.3    |       1.9
Highway robbery                     |    75.5     |    24.2    |       0.3
Homicide                            |    72.5     |    26.5    |       1.0
Serious assaults                    |    68.8     |    30.6    |       0.6
Rebellion, etc.                     |    65.9     |    34.1    |       0.0
All crimes                          |    63.8     |    33.1    |       3.1
Rape                                |    63.6     |    32.7    |       3.7
Aggravated theft                    |    59.7     |    38.4    |       1.9
Counterfeiting etc.                 |    50.9     |    46.9    |       2.2
Offenses against public decency etc.|    47.6     |    38.1    |      14.3
Sexual crimes against nature        |    43.8     |    45.8    |      10.4
Forgery                             |    10.4     |    36.2    |      26.4
====================================+=============+============+================


New York State, 1881–1897. [593]

======+===========================================================
      |        To 100 Persons Entering Elmira Reformatory.
Years.+-----------+-----------------+------------------+----------
      |Illiterate.|Able only to Read|Primary Education.|  Higher
      |           |   and Write.    |                  |Education.
------+-----------+-----------------+------------------+----------
 1881 |   19.0    |      59.3       |       16.5       |   5.2
 1882 |   18.5    |      58.7       |       18.0       |   4.8
 1883 |   19.3    |      57.5       |       18.6       |   4.6
 1884 |   19.3    |      56.1       |       20.2       |   4.4
 1885 |   18.3    |      55.7       |       21.9       |   4.1
 1886 |   19.9    |      53.2       |       23.0       |   3.9
 1888 |   19.8    |      50.1       |       26.2       |   3.9
 1889 |   19.5    |      49.9       |       26.9       |   3.7
 1890 |   19.1    |      50.8       |       26.9       |   3.2
 1891 |   18.7    |      48.6       |       29.4       |   3.3
 1892 |   19.3    |      48.8       |       28.6       |   3.3
 1893 |   19.0    |      45.6       |       31.8       |   3.6
 1894 |   18.8    |      43.8       |       33.8       |   3.6
 1896 |   18.3    |      41.3       |       37.0       |   3.4
 1897 |   18.3    |      43.3       |       35.2       |   3.2
======+===========+=================+==================+==========


Netherlands, 1865–1900. [594]

======+===========================
      | Unable to Read or Write.
      +--------------+------------
Years.| Convicts at  |
      |   Time of    |Militia-men.
      |Incarceration.|      %
      |      %       |
------+--------------+------------
 1865 |      38      |    18.2
 1870 |      30      |    16.3
 1875 |      25      |    12.3
 1880 |      25      |    11.5
 1885 |      22      |    10.5
 1890 |      24      |     7.2
 1892 |      25      |     5.4
 1893 |      22      |     5.4
 1894 |      20      |     5.0
 1895 |      20      |     5.4
 1896 |      20      |     4.7
 1897 |      19      |     4.0
 1898 |      19      |     3.6
 1899 |      18      |     2.8
 1900 |      16      |     2.3
======+==============+============


Netherlands, 1903–1905. [595]

==============================+=========================================
                              |     Out of 100 Convicted there were
                              +------+------+------+------+------+------
                              |    1903.    |    1904.    |    1905.
                              +------+------+------+------+------+------
                              | Men. |Women.| Men. |Women.| Men. |Women.
------------------------------+------+------+------+------+------+------
Without elementary instruction|  7.57| 24.70|  6.61| 18.26|  6.36| 13.33
With elementary instruction   | 91.43| 74.71| 92.20| 80.62| 92.50| 85.34
 ,,  secondary education      |  0.74|  0.33|  0.84|  0.22|  0.80|  0.47
 ,,  higher education         |  0.07|  0.00|  0.12|  0.00|  0.11|  0.00
Unknown                       |  0.15|  0.26|  0.23|  0.90|  0.23|  0.86
    Total                     |100.00|100.00|100.00|100.00|100.00|100.00
==============================+======+======+======+======+======+======


The following figures give an estimate with regard to some specified
crimes: [596]


Netherlands, 1901.

=====================================+===============
                                     |To 100 Convicts
               Crimes.               |    Unable
                                     |  to Read or
                                     |    Write.
-------------------------------------+---------------
Marauding                            |     16.6
Vagrancy                             |     10.0
Simple theft                         |      9.9
Malicious mischief, etc.             |      9.4
Aggravated theft                     |      9.1
All crimes                           |      8.6
Assaults                             |      7.9
Domiciliary trespass                 |      7.5
Receiving stolen goods               |      7.4
Defamation and kindred offenses      |      6.9
Offenses against public decency      |      6.5
Embezzlement                         |      5.8
Rebellion                            |      5.7
Rape and other sexual crimes         |      4.3
Obtaining money under false pretenses|      1.7
=====================================+===============


Prussia, 1894–1897. [597]

==========+==============================================+==========
          |Out of 18,049 Recidivists in Prussian Prisons.|To the 100
          |                                              |Recruits.
          +-----------+------------+----------+----------+----------
          |  Without  |Very Little | Primary  |  Higher  | Without
          |Education. | Education. |Education.|Education.| Primary
          |           |            |          |          |Education.
----------+-----------+------------+----------+----------+----------
Number    |   1,491   |   8,589    |  7,782   |   187    |
Percentage|    8.3    |    47.6    |   43.1   |   1.0    |   0.23
==========+===========+============+==========+==========+==========


Switzerland, 1892–1896. [598]

==============================+===========+===========
                              |   Men.    |  Women.
          Education           +-------+---+-------+---
                              |Number.| % |Number.| %
------------------------------+-------+---+-------+---
Illiterate                    |   352 |  3|    82 |  5
Primary education             | 8,665 | 87| 1,580 | 92
Secondary and higher education|   856 |  9|    45 |  2
Unknown                       |   109 |  1|    15 |  1
------------------------------+-------+---+-------+---
      Total                   | 9,982 |100| 1,722 |100
==============================+=======+===+=======+===


The figures for those who have had a primary education are divided up
as follows: [599]


==================+===========+===========
                  |   Men.    |  Women.
State of Education+-------+---+-------+---
                  |Number.| % |Number.| %
------------------+-------+---+-------+---
Good              | 4,394 | 51|   764 | 48
Mediocre          | 4,125 | 47|   750 | 48
Reading only      |   146 |  2|    66 |  4
------------------+-------+---+-------+---
      Total       | 8,665 |100| 1,580 |100
==================+=======+===+=======+===


The redactor of the official statistics of Switzerland observes that
there are no figures to determine the number of illiterates among the
non-criminal population, but the statistics of recruits for the years
1891 to 1895 show that about 19% of the recruits had a higher
education.

I am of the opinion that the statistics which I have quoted, [600]
including, as they do, millions of criminals, are very significant: the
illiterates supply, in general, a great proportion of the criminals, a
proportion much greater than that of the illiterates in the general
population. (In countries with a relatively small number of
illiterates, like England, the Netherlands, and Prussia, for example,
the difference is naturally much greater than in a country like Italy
where the percentage of illiteracy is great. In Prussia for instance,
there are thirty-six times as many illiterates among the recidivists as
among the recruits.)

However, most of the statistics, aside from the figures for illiteracy,
give others which show how many persons really educated are to be found
among the criminals. And then we note that a very great majority of
criminals are ignorant and untrained. In England, for example, there is
among male criminals only 1 to 1,000 who knows more than how to read
and write well, and among the women not even 1 to 1,000; in Austria
there are a little more than 4 to 1,000; and in France a little more
than 20 to 1,000 among the men, and between 4 and 5 among the women.
The relation between ignorance and criminality cannot, then, be
contradicted. But it is impossible to fix exactly the extent of the
influence of the one upon the other, or it is difficult to separate
ignorance from other factors with which it is ordinarily found, as
poverty, for instance.

The ancient idea that crime is only a consequence of ignorance need not
be treated of, for morality and intellect are two distinct parts of the
psychic life, even though there exists a certain relation between them.

The first reason why ignorance and the lack of general culture must be
ranked among the general factors of crime is this: the person who, in
our present society, where the great majority of parents care very
little for the education of their children, does not go to school, is
deprived of the moral ideas (honesty, etc.) which are taught there, and
ordinarily passes his time in idleness and vagabondage.

The second reason which makes ignorance a factor of crime, is that
generally an ignorant man is, more than others, a man moved by the
impulse of the moment, who allows himself to be governed by his
passions, and is induced to commit acts which he would not have
committed if his intellectual equipment had been different.

In the third place, it is for the following reasons that ignorance and
the lack of training fall within the etiology of crime. The mind of the
man whose psychic qualities, whether in the domain of the arts, or of
the sciences, have been developed, has become less susceptible to evil
ideas. His intellectual condition constitutes thus a bridle which can
restrain evil thoughts from realizing themselves; for real art and true
science strengthen the social instincts. The figures cited above
furnish only a slight contribution to this question. There is no doubt
that if we had figures showing how many criminals there are any part of
whose life is taken up by art or science, we should find the number
very small. It could not be objected that the cause of this is in the
innate qualities of the criminals; certainly one man is born with
greater capacity than another, but everyone is born with some
capacities which, if developed, may become a source of happiness; and a
happy man, says the proverb, is not wicked.

Finally ignorance is in still another way a factor in crime. Very often
the author of a crime conceives and executes it in so clumsy a fashion
and with so little chance of success, that we may be certain that he
would not have committed it if he had not been an ignorant person,
without knowledge of the forces with which he had to do.

When the Italian school is reproached with making their researches upon
prisoners only, and not upon criminals and their free equals, the
implication is that it is only the stupid and ignorant criminals that
are in prison, while the others, the shrewd and tricky, remain at
liberty. There is assuredly much truth in this assertion.

The lower proletariat. In the preceding pages I have already spoken of
the influence exercised by bad material surroundings upon a man’s
character; I have pointed out the moral consequences of bad housing
conditions, and also that he becomes embittered and malicious through
lack of the necessaries of life. All this applies to the proletariat in
general, but much more strongly still to those who do not succeed, for
any reason, in selling their labor, that is the lower proletariat.

If the dwellings of the working-class are bad, those of the lower
proletariat are more pitiable still. There are, through sickness or
lack of work, periods of dire poverty in the life of almost every
worker—for the lower proletariat these periods are without
intermission. Its poverty is chronic. And when the poverty makes itself
felt for a long time together, the intellectual faculties become
blunted to such a point that there remains of the man only the brute,
struggling for existence.

Although the material and intellectual poverty of the lower proletariat
is much greater than that of the proletariat, the difference between
them is only quantitative. In one connection, however, there is also a
qualitative difference, and a very important one, namely that the
working-man is a useful being without whom society could not exist.
However oppressed he may be, he is a man who has a feeling of
self-respect. It is different with the member of the lower proletariat.
He is not useful, but a detriment. He produces nothing, and tries to
live upon what others make; he is merely tolerated. He who has lived
long in poverty loses all feeling of self-respect, and lends himself to
anything whatever that will suffice to prolong his existence.

In short, poverty (taken in the sense of absolute want), kills the
social sentiments in man, destroys in fact all relations between men.
He who is abandoned by all can no longer have any feeling for those who
have left him to his fate.

b. The proportion in which the different classes are guilty of crime.
After having treated of the direct consequences of the present economic
system upon the different classes, I shall take up this question, which
is an important one for the problem of criminality, before touching
upon the indirect consequences.

As I have already observed in Part I, the opinions with regard to this
proportion are very divergent. There are authors (Garofalo, for
instance) who are of the opinion that the bourgeoisie commits as many
crimes, in proportion to its numbers, as the proletariat. On the other
hand there are those who maintain that the prisons hold only the poor.
That Garofalo’s conclusion does not hold good for Italy has been proved
by the statistics of Fornasari di Verce and those of Dr. Marro, quoted
in Part I of this book. The figures given by Fornasari di Verce have to
do with the persons sentenced by the assizes, the correctional
tribunals, and the justices of the peace. They show that 56% of the
convicts were indigent, that 31% had only the strict necessities of
life, 10% were moderately well off, while 2% were well-to-do or rich;
while among the non-criminal population about 40% were rich or more or
less well-to-do, and the other 60% indigent or having only the
necessaries of life. But the figures for non-possessors become much
greater if we take only the number of those sentenced by the court of
assizes,—the real criminals.


Italy, 1887–1889 (Assizes). [601]

========================+=========+=========+========
       Condition.       |  1887.  |  1888.  |  1889.
------------------------+---------+---------+--------
                        |    %    |    %    |    %
Indigent                |  79.57  |  79.62  |  77.58
Having the necessaries  |   9.39  |  10.21  |  13.31
Passably well off       |   7.35  |   6.62  |   6.12
Well-to-do and rich     |   3.69  |   3.55  |   2.98
                        +---------+---------+--------
                        | 100.00  | 100.00  | 100.00
========================+=========+=========+========


The following figures give the economic condition of persons convicted
for different crimes:


Italy, 1889 (Assizes). [602]

==============================+====================================================
                              |To the 100 Convicted of the Crimes Given there were:
           Crimes.            +------------+------------+------------+-------------
                              | Indigent.  | Having the | Passably   | Well-to-do
                              |            |necessaries.| well off.  |  or rich.
------------------------------+------------+------------+------------+-------------
Infanticide                   |    88.1    |     7.1    |     4.8    |     0.0
Theft of every kind           |    81.5    |    13.4    |     3.3    |     1.7
Counterfeiting, etc.          |    80.3    |    10.4    |     7.7    |     1.6
Rebellion, cruelty, etc.      |    79.5    |    11.4    |     0.0    |     9.1
Homicide of every degree      |    79.0    |    10.8    |     6.8    |     3.4
Serious assaults              |    78.7    |    12.4    |     7.4    |     1.5
Highway robbery               |    77.8    |    17.5    |     4.0    |     0.7
Rape and other sexual offenses|    77.3    |    14.8    |     5.6    |     2.3
Extortion                     |    74.7    |    13.1    |     7.8    |     4.4
Forgery                       |    47.5    |    24.7    |    11.1    |    16.7
==============================+============+============+============+=============


Italy not being a rich country, it is evident that the headings
“passably well-off” and “well-to-do or rich” have been given a liberal
interpretation, otherwise they would never include almost 40% of the
population. But even taking account of this fact, these figures show
that the indigent, that is, the lower proletariat, and the proletariat
without work, form a much higher proportion of the criminal class than
of the population as a whole.

Other figures confirming these conclusions for Italy have been produced
by Dr. Colajanni (see Part I of this work). Further than these,
statistics concerning the financial condition of convicts are not
numerous so far as I know. Here are those that are known to me:


Austria, 1881–1899. [603]

=========+===============================================
         |                Condition (%).
 Years.  +-------------+--------------------+-----------
         |Without Money.|With a Little Money.|Well-to-do.
---------+--------------+--------------------+-----------
1881-1885|     89.1     |        10.4        |    0.3
1886-1890|     90.0     |         9.4        |    0.4
1891-1895|     89.6     |         9.9        |    0.4
  1896   |     86.7     |        13.0        |    0.3
  1897   |     86.0     |        13.5        |    0.5
  1898   |     85.9     |        13.7        |    0.4
  1899   |     86.7     |        13.0        |    0.3
=========+==============+====================+===========


The following figures give us the proportions of the different crimes:


Austria, 1899. [604]

=====================+===================================================
                     |   There were to the 100 Convicts Guilty of the
                     |                Crimes Mentioned:
       Crimes.       +----------+----------+--------+------+------+------
                     |Without Fortune.[605]|Little Fortune.| Well-to-do.
                     +----------+----------+--------+------+------+------
                     |   Men.   | Women.   |  Men.  |Women.| Men. |Women.
---------------------+----------+----------+--------+------+------+------
Robbery              |   96.6   |  100.0   |   3.4  |  0.0 | 0.0  | 0.0
Theft                |   92.0   |   94.7   |   7.8  |  5.3 | 0.2  | 0.0
Rape, etc.           |   91.2   |  100.0   |   8.6  |  0.0 | 0.2  | 0.0
Leze majesty, etc.   |   90.1   |   93.1   |   9.6  |  6.9 | 0.3  | 0.0
Threats              |   90.0   |   81.5   |   9.9  | 18.5 | 0.1  | 0.0
Rebellion, etc.      |   87.3   |   74.9   |  12.4  | 24.8 | 0.3  | 0.3
Crimes in general    |   86.4   |   88.4   |  13.2  | 11.4 | 0.4  | 0.2
Extortion            |   86.2   |   80.0   |  13.5  | 20.0 | 0.3  | 0.0
Serious assaults     |   79.0   |   70.2   |  30.6  | 29.8 | 0.4  | 0.0
Fraud                |   74.8   |   75.1   |  23.6  | 24.3 | 1.6  | 0.6
Murder, homicide     |   73.0   |   87.2   |  26.7  | 12.8 | 0.3  | 0.0
Infanticide, abortion|    0.0   |   90.8   |   0.0  |  9.2 | 0.0  | 0.0
=====================+==========+=======-==+========+======+======+======


I have not been able to procure the figures showing the financial
condition of the Austrian population. But it may be considered as
certain that there are more well-to-do persons in Austria than about 3%
of the population, and also that there are more persons with a little
money than the percentage of criminals shown under that heading.
Therefore, as in Italy, the poor there are more guilty of crime than
the well-to-do (and much more so of certain crimes). It is interesting
to note that well-to-do women are not guilty at all of most crimes.
[606]


Prussia, 1894–1897. [607]

===============================================================================================
                                 Among Recidivists were Found
-----------------------------------------------------------------------+-----------------------
                            With incomes of                            |
-----------------------+-----------------------+-----------------------+       Indigent.
 Less than 900 marks.  |  900 to 2,000 marks.  | 2,000 to 5,000 marks. |
----------+------------+-----------+-----------+-----------+-----------+-----------+-----------
   Men.   |   Women.   |   Men.    |   Women.  |   Men.    |   Women.  |   Men.    |  Women.
-------+--+------------+-------+---+-------+---+-------+---+-------+---+-------+---+-------+---
Number.| %|Number.| %  |Number.| % |Number.| % |Number.| % |Number.| % |Number.| % |Number.| %
-------+--+-------+----+-------+---+-------+---+-------+---+-------+---+-------+---+-------+---
13,931 |90| 2,424 |96.5| 1,424 |9.2|  66   |2.6|  46   |0.3|   2   |0.1|  74   |0.5|  18   |0.8
=======+==+=======+====+=======+===+=======+===+=======+===+=======+===+=======+===+=======+===


There were no rich persons then among the recidivists; no one with an
income of more than 5,000 marks. On the other hand, those of very
limited income are exceedingly numerous, especially among the women. It
is a pity that the first group was not further subdivided, for “less
than 900 marks” leaves the group still very large.

The following figures give a picture of the financial situation of the
Swiss criminals.


Switzerland, 1892–1896. [608]

=========================================
         There were Prisoners:
---------------------------+-------+-----
                           |Number.|  %
---------------------------+-------+-----
With fortune               |   589 |  5.0
With expectations          | 1,140 |  9.7
With neither               | 9,569 | 81.8
Condition unknown          |   406 |  3.5
                           +-------+-----
                           |11,704 |100
                           +=======+=====
Having a savings-bank book |   202 |  1.7
Without        ,,      ,,  | 9,608 | 82.1
Unknown                    | 1,894 | 16.1
                           +-------+-----
                           |11,704 |100
===========================+=======+=====


All the statistics cited [609] show then that the poor supply a very
great proportion of the convicts, in every case a greater proportion
than they bear to the population in general, and the well-to-do form
only a small part.

There are still other ways of inquiring what part the different classes
take in criminality. One consists in an examination of the statistics
of the intellectual development of the convicts, for the illiterate and
those who have received only a primary education belong, almost without
exception, to the classes without fortune. These statistics have
already been given, and they confirm entirely the conclusions to be
drawn from the figures for the financial condition of the convicts.

The third way of solving the problem is by a study of the statistics of
the occupations of those convicted. Here, however, great difficulties
present themselves. In the first place not all the criminal statistics
make the distinction between the employer and the workman in such and
such an occupation. And it is just this information that we need. In
the second place we need beside statistics for the occupation of the
criminals, others showing the occupations of the population in general,
and the two classified in the same way. Even in this case the picture
given by these statistics will not be exact, for there are among the
employers many persons who are not really independent (workers at home,
etc.), or persons who, while being employers, are, as far as their
plane of living is concerned, only the equal of the proletarian, and
not of the bourgeois.

Upon this question we have the following figures:


Germany, 1894–1896. [610]

======================+=============================================================================================================
      Groups          |             To 10,000 Persons Over 12 Years of Age in Each Group of Occupations there were:
        of            +-----+---------+---------+--------+--------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----
    Occupations.      |  A. |   B.    |   C.    |  D.    |  E.    | F.  | G.  | H.  |  I. |  J. |  K. |  L. | M.  | N.  |  O. |  P.
----------------------+-----+---------+---------+--------+--------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----
  I. Agriculture:     |     |         |         |        |        |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
     a. Independent   | 75.1|  7.1    |  0.2    |  1.5   |  1.7   | 0.21| 0.10| 19.1|  1.5|  2.9| 0.22| 14.1| 0.02|  2.3| 0.08| 0.03
     b. Workers       |142.1| 28.9    |  3.1    |  4.8   |  6.0   | 1.67| 0.18|  9.8|  3.1|  6.8| 0.31| 36.4| 0.05|  6.5| 0.36| 0.37
 II. Manufacturing:   |     |         |         |        |        |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
     a. Independent   |129.9|  7.1    |  0.5    |  5.1   |  5.4   | 1.20| 0.17| 27.8|  3.3|  5.3| 0.32| 17.5| 0.02|  3.2| 0.09| 0.05
     b. Workers       |234.5| 32.7    |  5.8    | 10.2   | 10.2   | 2.98| 0.20| 19.4| 13.1| 13.3| 0.32| 57.5| 0.06| 12.0| 0.19| 0.14
III. Commerce and     |     |         |         |        |        |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
       transportation:|     |         |         |        |        |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
     a. Independent   |275.5| 10.4    |  0.7    |  8.8   | 16.4   | 1.35| 0.11| 49.4|  5.9|  7.4| 0.59| 21.8| 0.04|  3.4| 0.10| 0.01
     b. Workers       |222.6| 35.2    |  6.7    | 22.0   | 18.3   | 2.22| 0.09| 20.8| 10.3|  8.8| 0.32| 26.3| 0.05|  6.1| 0.06| 0.05
 IV. Domestics        | 52.8|27.1[611]|2.02[611]|3.1[611]|4.0[611]| 0.06| 0.15|  2.4|  0.4|  0.8| 0.20|  1.4| 0.01|  0.6| 0.12| 0.31
  V. Public service   |     |         |         |        |        |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
     and lib. profess.| 79.3|  5.9    | 1.2     |  4.8   | 5.6    | 1.69| 0.06| 20.0|  2.0|  2.2| 0.14|  6.6| 0.01|  1.6| 0.02| 0.00
 VI. Population       |     |         |         |        |        |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
     over 12          |120.1| 19.2    | 2.5     |  5.2   | 5.4    | 1.17| 0.13| 14.7|  4.5|  5.5| 0.22| 22.3| 0.03|  4.6| 0.13| 0.09
======================+=====+=========+=========+========+========+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====

KEY TO COLUMN HEADINGS:

A. Crimes in General.      I. Violence and Threats against Public Functionaries.
B. Theft.                  J. Domiciliary Trespass.
C. Aggravated Theft.       K. Perjury.
D. Embezzlement.           L. Serious Assaults.
E. Fraud.                  M. Homicides.
F. Rape, etc.              N. Malicious Mischief.
G. Incest.                 O. Arson.
H. Insult.                 P. Infanticide.


Germany, 1896. [612]

======================+=======================================================================================================
      Groups          |      To 10,000 Persons Over 12 Years of Age and having Occupation there were to Each Group:
        of            +--------+-------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+------+-----+-----+-------+-----+-----+-----+-----
    Occupations.      |   A.   |   B.  |  C. |  D. |  E. | F.  | G.  | H.  |  I.  |  J. |  K. |   L.  | M.  | N.  |  O. |  P.
----------------------+--------+-------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+------+-----+-----+-------+-----+-----+-----+-----
Agriculture           | 1,208.7|  238.1| 26.2| 35.8| 1.2 | 1.1 | 54.1|  9.0| 12.1 |127.2| 84.1|  299.8| 24.6| 55.0| 2.8 |0.42
Manufacturing         | 2,144.3|  304.3| 58.4| 86.6| 2.3 | 2.6 | 97.9| 19.0| 26.3 |225.3|141.8|  496.1|105.3|120.0| 3.2 |0.51
Commerce and          |        |       |     |     |     |     |     |     |      |     |     |       |     |     |     |
  transportation      | 2,566.2|  276.9| 40.1|159.3| 1.2 | 6.3 |154.5| 50.5| 19.5 |353.4|126.3|  256.8| 84.8| 80.1| 4.0 |0.64
Workmen and           |        |       |     |     |     |     |     |     |      |     |     |       |     |           |
  day-laborers[613]   |10,402.6|2,622.7|439.3|514.7|20.8 |15.3 |459.7| 88.8|107.8 |829.8|669.5|1,679.5|664.2|439.5| 9.7 |1.60
Domestics             |   530.3|  305.7| 25.3| 29.4| 0.23| 0.45| 46.8|  9.2|  0.83| 24.8|  7.4|   13.4|  4.3| 10.0| 2.2 |0.08
Public service and    |        |       |     |     |     |     |     |     |      |     |     |       |     |     |     |
  liberal professions |   798.6|   70.7| 13.1| 48.9| 0.63| 1.6 | 65.3| 18.7|  17.1|193.0| 33.2|   70.8| 19.7| 21.4| 2.1 |0.13
Professors,           |        |       |     |     |     |     |     |     |      |     |     |       |     |     |     |
 physicians, employees|   418.6|   19.2|  1.7|  9.9| 0.00| 0.71| 19.8|  6.8|  12.4|120.0| 14.3|   25.8|  8.6|  7.8| 0.99|0.14
Persons of income,    |        |       |     |     |     |     |     |     |      |     |     |       |     |     |     |
  students, persons   |        |       |     |     |     |     |     |     |      |     |     |       |     |     |     |
  supported           |   224.5|   17.3| 0.71|  4.3| 0.00| 0.65|  9.2|  1.8|  4.6 | 65.7| 14.8|   30.6|  8.3| 12.7| 0.59|0.06
======================+========+=======+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+======+=====+=====+=======+=====+=====+=====+====

KEY TO COLUMN HEADINGS:

A. Crimes in General.    I. Rape upon Children, etc.
B. Theft.                J. Insult.
C. Aggravated Theft.     K. Assaults.
D. Embezzlement.         L. Serious Assaults.
E. Robbery.              M. Violence and Threats against Public Functionaries.
F. Extortion.            N. Domiciliary Trespass.
G. Fraud.                O. Perjury.
H. Forgery.              P. Homicide.


These statistics, probably the best upon the subject, tell the whole
story to those who know how to read the figures. They constitute a
proof of the enormous influence of the social factors in the etiology
of crime. It is impossible to maintain that the influence works the
other way, that the moral disposition influences the choice of a
profession. Dr. Prinzing rightly says in the article cited: “It is
quite impossible that those engaged in the three great groups of
occupations, agriculture, manufacturing, and commerce, are persons of
different kinds of moral traits. On the contrary, the supposition that
the moral endowment of each group is nearly the same is completely
justified by the movements that are continually going on under our own
eyes, through which the countryman becomes a city-dweller, and the man
who has grown up in the practice of agriculture, a workman or assistant
in manufacturing and commerce.” [614]


England and Wales, 1894–1900. [615]

=============+====+=========================================+======+==============
             |    |   Among the Prisoners Convicted there were:    |   Average.
Occupations. |    +------+------+------+------+------+------+------+-------+------
             |    | 1894.| 1895.| 1896.| 1897.| 1898.| 1899.| 1900.|Number.|  %
-------------+----+------+------+------+------+------+------+------+-------+------
Domestics    |{ M.|   948|   729|   832|   651|   662|   667|   604|    729|  0.7
             |{ W.| 1,876| 1,530| 1,417| 1,369| 1,424| 1,986| 2,042|  1,663|  3.9
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Workmen,     |{ M.|75,539|69,944|72,725|73,264|77,321|75,220|69,168| 73,311| 68.0
housekeepers,|{ W.|11,083|10,596|10,574|12,394|14,376|14,960|14,179| 12,594| 29.2
seamstresses |{   |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Factory      |{ M.| 3,763| 2,420| 3,212| 2,855| 3,019| 2,590| 2,331|  2,941|  2.7
      workers|{ W.| 3,755| 3,127| 2,926| 2,762| 3,086| 3,367| 3,498|  3,217|  7.5
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Mechanicians |{ M.|20,702|18,747|19,216|19,179|20,914|20,351|19,726| 19,870| 18.4
  and skilled|{ W.|   677|   646| 1,220| 1,342| 1,527| 1,348| 1,480|  1,177|  2.7
      workmen|{   |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Foremen,     |{ M.|    80|    75|    65|    64|    60|    75|    61|     68|  0.1
   inspectors|{ W.|     2|     3|     4|     5|     2|     1|     2|      2|  0.0
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Store and    |{ M.| 2,869| 2,652| 2,805| 2,506| 2,877| 2,677| 2,550|  2,705|  2.5
office clerks|{ W.|   125|    83|    77|    84|   102|   161|   237|    124|  0.3
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Merchants    |{ M.| 4,054| 4,045| 4,410| 3,984| 4,352| 4,052| 3,461|  4,056|  3.7
             |{ W.| 4,127| 4,004| 4,249| 4,087| 4,820| 4,513| 4,179|  4,282|  9.9
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Liberal      |{ M.|   239|   231|   208|   223|   194|   209|   204|    215|  0.2
  professions|{ W.|    24|    23|    34|    23|    33|    24|    28|     27|  0.1
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Soldiers,    |{   | 3,620| 3,338| 3,433| 3,227| 3,202| 3,082| 3,327|  3,318|  3.1
 sailors and |{   |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
      marines|{   |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Prostitutes  |    | 5,132| 5,105| 7,411| 6,746| 6,413| 6,092| 6,715|  6,230| 14.5
             |    |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |       |
Without      |{ M.| 1,369|   746|   644|   550|   518|   391|   320|    648|  0.6
   occupation|{ W.|15,067|14,910|13,494|13,606|13,361|12,888|12,745| 13,725| 31.9
-------------+----+------+------+------+------+------+------+------+-------+------
             |    |                                  Total  { Men  |107,861|100.00
             |    |                                         { Women| 43,041|100.00
=============+====+================================================+=======+======


According to the first table the workmen are implicated, in a much
greater degree than the independents, in all the crimes except that of
insult (which is explained by the fact that this crime is one of those
which are prosecuted only after complaint laid, and that working-men
decide to lay complaint much less quickly than the bourgeois). Certain
crimes, indeed, are more often committed by the independent merchants
than by the working-men of the same class, but here it is necessary to
remember that many of the small merchants are on the same plane of
living as the working-men. The liberal professions, on the contrary,
show very low figures, a fact which is to be plainly noticed in the
second table, where the attention is caught by the very low figures of
the group of students and person with incomes. The participation in all
crimes by unskilled workmen is very great, even if we allow for the
figures’ being exaggerated.

I have not been able to procure statistics concerning the occupations
of the whole population of England. Nevertheless, it seems to me to be
worth while to mention the figures concerning the occupations of the
criminals, for, considered by themselves, they show clearly that the
classes without means play a very large part in crime. At least 95% of
the men are in this condition, as well as at least 5% of the women (a
part of the merchants must be added in both cases) while of the 31.9%
without occupation it is certain that a large number are also poor.


France, 1898–1900. [616]

=======================================+============================
                                       | Number of Persons Accused
                                       | to 100,000 of Each Group.
    Groups of Occupations.             +---------+---------+--------
                                       |  1898.  |  1899.  |  1900.
---------------------------------------+---------+---------+--------
Agriculture                            |    8    |    9    |    8
Manufacturing                          |   20    |   22    |   24
Commerce                               |   29    |   33    |   27
Domestic service                       |   16    |   16    |   13
Liberal professions and public service |   15    |   15    |   15
=======================================+=========+=========+========


Since this table makes no distinction between independents and
dependents, it does not advance the matter much, and the only important
observation that can be drawn from it is that agriculture and the
liberal professions give the lowest figures. A clearer idea is given by
the following table:


France, 1890–1895. [617]

==============================+=======================================================================================
                              |            To the 100 Prisoners in Penitentiaries and Houses of Correction.
                              +----------------+--------------+-------------+-------------+-------------+-------------
          Occupations.        |      1890.     |    1891.     |    1892.    |    1893.    |    1894.    |    1895.
                              +------+---------+------+-------+------+------+------+------+------+------+------+------
                              | Men. | Women.  | Men. |Women. | Men. |Women.| Men. |Women.| Men. |Women.| Men. |Women.
------------------------------+------+---------+------+-------+------+------+------+------+------+------+------+------
Property owners, persons of   |      |         |      |       |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |
  income                      |  0.58|  1.10   |  0.62|  2.21 |  0.62|  0.99|  0.66|  1.45|  0.66|  1.78|  0.65|  2.07
Liberal professions           |  2.36|  1.03   |  2.92|  1.66 |  2.64|  1.42|  2.41|  1.90|  2.64|  1.62|  2.50|  1.33
Employees                     |  5.00|  0.55   |  5.40|  0.34 |  5.07|  0.36|  4.81|  0.30|  5.26|  0.62|  5.49|  1.33
Merchants, manufacturers      |  3.77|  4.47   |  3.25|  4.80 |  3.49|  4.35|  3.39|  3.81|  3.64|  4.71|  3.19|  5.72
Alimentary professions        |  3.12|  1.24   |  3.41|  0.92 |  3.53|  0.85|  3.60|  1.52|  4.31|  1.78|  4.27|  1.82
Workmen in shops and factories|  8.39| 13.14   |  8.93| 12.03 |  8.73| 12.17|  7.86| 15.16|  9.46| 16.08|  9.39| 15.34
Building and furnishing trades| 16.76|  0.21[#]| 16.09|0.28[#]| 17.11|  0.49| 17.68|  0.23| 17.51|  1.23| 17.92|  0.66
Agricultural and day laborers | 48.31| 62.45   | 48.85| 61.02 | 47.94| 63.17| 49.52| 56.44| 45.71| 56.03| 44.93| 54.15
Nomadic occupations           |  3.99|  4.68   |  3.89|  4.63 |  4.19|  4.77|  3.79|  4.72|  3.77|  4.79|  3.82|  4.48
Soldiers and sailors          |  2.41|  --     |  2.23|  --   |  2.29|  --  |  1.94|  --  |  1.75|  --  |  1.60|  --
Vagabonds and mendicants      |  1.48|  4.74[#]|  0.82|4.65[#]]  0.94|  4.77|  1.03|  5.71|  1.27|  4.95|  1.52|  5.14
Individuals in the care of    |      |         |      |       |      |      |      |      |      |      |      |
  their families              |  3.83|  6.39   |  --  |  7.46 |  3.45|  5.66|  3.31|  8.76|  4.02|  6.41|  4.72|  7.96
------------------------------+------+---------+------+-------+------+------+------+------+------+------+------+------
                              |100.00|100.00   |100.00|100.00 |100.00|100.00|100.00|100.00|100.00|100.00|100.00|100.00
==============================+======+=========+======+=======+======+======+======+======+======+======|======|======


Although there are no statistics of the occupations of the
corresponding non-criminal population, the figures are well worth
noting. We discover that the unskilled laborers form a large proportion
of the prisoners, in every case a larger proportion than they bear to
the population in general; and that the merchants and manufacturers
form a much smaller part of the prisoners than they do of the
population as a whole, for they certainly constitute more than 5.45%,
especially in France, a country where small industries still flourish.


Italy, 1891–1895. [620]

=======================================================+============================
                                                       |         Convicts.
                Groups of Occupations.                 +----------------------------
                                                       |Annual Average to 100,000 of
                                                       |Each Group of Occupations.
-------------------------------------------------------+----------------------------
Agriculture                                            |          1,009.03
Manufacturing, arts and trades                         |            855.78
Commerce, transport, navigation and fishing            |          1,677.46
Domestic service                                       |            410.96
Employees, liberal professions, capitalists, pensioners|            288.58
=======================================================+============================


These figures show that in Italy also the capitalists and liberal
professions furnish a figure for criminality below that of the other
groups. The same is true of the following table:


Italy, 1891–1895. [621]

==============================+================================================
                              |                   Convicts.
                              |Annual Average to the 100,000 of the Population.
    Groups of Professions.    +-----------------------+------------------------
                              |    Proprietors or     |       Dependents.
                              |      Managers.        |
------------------------------+-----------------------+------------------------
Agriculture                   |         307.43        |        1,368.99
Manufacturing, arts and trades|         678.56        |          861.57
Commerce                      |       1,278.11        |        1,585.03
==============================+=======================+========================


The following table is more detailed for certain occupations:


Italy, 1891–1895. [622]

==================================================+============================
                                                  |         Convicts.
                                                  +----------------------------
                                                  |Annual Average to 100,000 of
                                                  |        Population.
                   Occupations.                   +--------------+-------------
                                                  |Proprietors or| Dependents.
                                                  |  Managers.   |
                                                  +--------------+-------------
                                                  |             Men.
--------------------------------------------------+--------------+-------------
Building trade                                    |   1,654.52   |  1,895.18
                {textile, mechanical, }           |              |
Manufacturing   {chemical, alimentary,}           |     837.80   |  1,443.22
                {arts and trades      }           |              |
Shoemaking                                        |   1,080.95   |  2,254.63
Meat business                                     |   3,925.95   |  3,900.61
Cafés, etc.                                       |   1,542.12   |    914.68
Sale of food and fuel                             |   1,035.58   |  2,411.66
Other kinds of commerce                           |   1,649.80   |  1,383.12
Navigation, fishing                               |     259.11   |  1.769.94
--------------------------------------------------+--------------+-------------
                                                  |            Women.
--------------------------------------------------+--------------+-------------
Manufacturing {mines, building, tobacco, textile,}|     133.70   |    193.38
              {alimentary, arts and trades       }|              |
Seamstresses, dressmakers, milliners              |     285.00   |    138.15
Sale of food and fuel                             |     460.46   |    511.49
Other kinds of commerce                           |   2,403.88   |  3,113.34
==================================================+==============+=============


We have now arrived at the end of our observations upon occupations
among criminals. Other statistics are available, but either it is
impossible to compare them with statistics of the non-criminal
population, or they are without significance for some other reason. At
any rate it seems to me that those I have given are enough to show that
proportionately the non-possessors are more guilty of crime than the
possessors. [623]

The thesis set forth above is confirmed, then, in three different ways.
The question still remains to be answered, to what must we attribute
the greater criminality among the non-possessors?

As was remarked at the beginning of this section (on the egoistic
tendency of the present economic system, and its consequences), there
are three questions which present themselves in connection with the
etiology of crime; first, what is the origin of the criminal idea?
Second, what are the forces in man which prevent this idea from coming
to realization? Third, the occasion for committing the crime. For the
moment we shall concern ourselves with the second question only; and we
shall ask ourselves the question, is the explanation that these forces
are weaker with non-possessors than with others? It is very difficult,
if not impossible, to give an answer to this question, for it is very
complicated. In the first place it is necessary to prove that the
environment of the non-possessors arouses thoughts for which that of
the possessors offers no place. The circumstances in which the
well-to-do live are in general of such a nature that the moral force
has no need of offering combat, since the criminal thought does not
exist. For example, in economic offenses one of the principal
provocatives of criminal ideas is poverty, which is unknown to the
bourgeoisie. It follows that nothing definite can be said about the
relative force of the moral sentiments in these two groups of the
population in counteracting criminal ideas. Other examples could be
added, and I am of the opinion that this influence of the environment
will be by itself sufficient to explain the difference in the
criminality of the two groups.

It is impossible to decide with certainty whether, aside from the
above-mentioned influence of the environment, the present economic
system and its consequences have a harmful influence upon the social
sentiments that is stronger in the case of non-possessors than it is in
the case of possessors. It must be considered as certain (and the
figures which I shall give farther along also show it) that the
circumstances in which children and young people live among the
proletariat is a cause of their being much more demoralized than the
children of the bourgeoisie. The influences acting upon the adults of
the two classes differ so much in nature and intensity that it is
impossible to contrast their effects.

It is unnecessary to say that in what has preceded the possessing class
has been contrasted with the proletariat alone, and not with the lower
proletariat. It goes without saying that the environment in which the
latter live makes them the class most destitute of the moral sense in
the whole population.

c. Marriage. To form an idea as to whether there is a relation between
crime and marriage, and in this case, as to what its nature is, we must
have recourse to statistics. Almost all the criminal statistics give
information upon the civil status of criminals (England is the sole
exception, I believe).

We shall commence with:


Austria, 1881–1899. [624]

===================+========================================================
                   |                         Years.
      Status.      +----------+----------+----------+-----+-----+-----+-----
                   |1881-1885.|1886-1890.|1891-1895.|1896.|1897.|1898.|1899.
-------------------+----------+----------+----------+-----+-----+-----+-----
Unmarried          |   56.8   |   59.9   |   60.7   | 62.2| 62.9| 61.7| 61.3
Married            |   39.9   |   36.9   |   36.2   | 34.7| 34.1| 35.3| 35.3
Widowers and widows|    3.2   |    3.1   |    3.0   |  3.1|  3.0|  3.0|  3.3
===================+==========+==========+==========+=====+=====+=====+=====


Here the unmarried are more numerous than the married. It is different,
however, in a neighboring country:


Hungary, 1888. [625]

===================+=================================
                   |        To 100 Convicts.
                   +----------------+----------------
Status.            |      Men.      |     Women.
                   +--------+-------+--------+-------
                   |Assizes.| Corr. |Assizes.| Corr.
                   |        |Tribun.|        |Tribun.
-------------------+--------+-------+--------+-------
Unmarried          | 42.89  | 32.99 | 33.51  | 18.03
Married            | 54.66  | 62.31 | 53.08  | 69.29
Widowers and widows|  2.36  |  4.06 | 13.08  | 11.46
Divorced           |  0.09  |  0.64 |  0.33  |  1.22
===================+========+=======+========+=======


Here, then, the married persons far outnumber the unmarried. However,
neither of these tables has much value, for first, nothing shows that
from the total number of the unmarried those who have not yet reached
marriageable age has been subtracted, and second, the corresponding
figures for the non-criminal population are lacking, so that a
comparison of the two is impossible.

In these respects the following figures are better:


Italy, 1891–1895. [626]

====================+====================================
                    |Annual Average Number (of Criminals)
      Status.       |  to 100,000 of the Population in
                    |        Each Group over 14.
--------------------+------------------------------------
Unmarried           |               978.47
Married             |               622.27
Widowers and widows |               291.84
====================+====================================


But as the Hungarian figures have already shown it is necessary to make
a division for sexes, for first, women have a much lower figure for
criminality than men, and second, the whole population is not equally
divided between men and women.

The defects so far noted have been avoided in the following tables:


France, 1881–1900. [627]

====================+===============================================
                    |To 100,000 of the Same State of Life there were
                    |            accused at the Assizes:
      Status.       +-----------------------+-----------------------
                    |         Men.          |        Women.
                    +-----------+-----------+-----------+-----------
                    | 1881-1885.| 1896-1900.| 1881-1885.| 1896-1900.
--------------------+-----------+-----------+-----------+-----------
Unmarried           |    62     |    41     |     8     |     5
Married             |    18     |    12     |     3     |     2
Widowers and widows |    24     |    14     |     5     |     3
====================+===========+===========+===========+===========


Netherlands, 1899. [628]

==========================+===============================+=============================
                          |             Men.              |           Women.
                          +-------------------------------+-----------------------------
                          |  To 100 Men   |  To 100 Male  |   To 100   |     To 100
         Status.          |of Marriageable|  Convicts of  |  Women of  |Female Convicts
                          |      Age      | Marriageable  |Marriageable|of Marriageable
                          |  there were:  |Age there were:| Age there  |Age there were:
                          |               |               |   were:    |
--------------------------+---------------+---------------+------------+----------------
Unmarried                 |     34.8      |     59.1      |    36.2    |      36.7
Married                   |     58.8      |     36.7      |    52.4    |      52.6
Widowers, widows, divorced|      6.4      |      4.2      |    11.4    |      10.7
==========================+===============+===============+============+================


Switzerland, 1892–1896. [629]

===================+===========================+===========================
                   |           Men.            |          Women.
                   +---------------+-----------+---------------+-----------
      Status.      |   To 100 of   |  To 100   |   To 100 of   |  To 100
                   |Population Over| Prisoners |Population Over| Prisoners
                   |  12 Yrs. Old  |there were:|  12 Yrs. Old  |there were:
                   |  there were:  |           |  there were:  |
-------------------+---------------+-----------+---------------+-----------
Unmarried          |     49.3      |   64.0    |     45.7      |   48.5
Married            |     44.8      |   26.6    |     41.9      |   33.0
Widowers and widows|      5.5      |    5.7    |     11.7      |   11.6
Divorced           |      0.4      |    3.7    |      0.7      |    6.9
===================+===============+===========+===============+===========


These tables show that the unmarried men (but not the women) are in
general more criminal than the married. However it is necessary to be
careful as to this point. All these tables fail to connect civil status
with age, a fact which reduces their importance almost to nothing,
first because the tendency to crime differs much with age; and
secondly, because the percentage of married persons is not the same for
different ages. It is, therefore, necessary to compare the married and
the unmarried at the same age. The German statistics are the only ones
which furnish the necessary materials, and the conclusions to be drawn
from these are the only ones which give us certain information as to
the relation between crime and marriage. These statistics have served
as the basis for the two studies of Dr. Prinzing’s already quoted from
which we take the following tables.

First the relation between marriage and crime among men. But it must
first be remarked that married men are acquitted oftener than
bachelors, as a consequence of which the unmarried men are made, in the
tables, to seem more criminal than they are—as the following table
shows:


Germany, 1886–1890. [630]

========+=======================================================
        |Number Acquitted out of 100 Accused of Each Category of
        |                 Age and Civil Status.
  Age.  +------------------+----------------+-------------------
        |    Unmarried.    |    Married.    |    Widowers and
        |                  |                |      Divorced.
--------+------------------+----------------+-------------------
 18-21  |       15.0       |      20.7      |
 21-25  |       15.8       |      18.4      |
 25-30  |       15.9       |      20.1      |       16.1
 30-40  |       15.1       |      22.3      |       16.0
 40-50  |       13.4       |      23.7      |       15.2
 50-60  |       13.4       |      24.9      |       18.0
Over 60 |       14.2       |      28.1      |       22.3
========+==================+================+===================


Germany, 1888. [631]

Crimes in General.

=======+=======================================================
       |Number of Convicts to 100,000 Persons of Each Category.
Age.   +--------------+------------+-----------------+---------
       |  Unmarried.  |  Married.  |  Wid. and Div.  |  Total.
-------+--------------+------------+-----------------+---------
 18-21 |   2,994.5    |  5,413.0   |                 | 3,009.2
 21-25 |   3,107.0    |  3,566.3   |                 | 3,163.8
 25-30 |   2,950.9    |  2,504.7   |     4,273.7     | 2,746.7
 30-40 |   2,880.9    |  1,961.2   |     3,797.2     | 2,171.5
 40-50 |   2,205.7    |  1,487.8   |     2,626.3     | 1,599.8
 50-60 |   1,241.9    |  1,009.8   |     1,267.8     | 1,052.5
Over 60|     494.6    |    490.1   |       342.7     |   450.5
=======+==============+============+=================+=========


It appears then from this table, first, that in general the bachelors
commit more crimes than the married men; second, that the contrary is
true of the period between 18 and 25; third, that the criminality of
married men is very great.

The following figures have to do with some important economic crimes.
[632]


Simple Theft.

=======+==========+========+==========+======
       |          |        |Widowers, |
 Age.  |Unmarried.|Married.|Widows and|Total.
       |          |        |Divorced. |
-------+----------+--------+----------+------
 18-21 |  551.7   |1,418.3 |          | 555.3
 21-25 |  427.7   |  685.9 |  627.2   | 457.7
 25-30 |  382.6   |  412.6 |  572.1   | 398.5
 30-40 |  411.9   |  296.9 |  550.0   | 323.0
 40-50 |  365.0   |  216.2 |  420.0   | 237.4
 50-60 |  233.1   |  151.6 |  231.1   | 164.6
Over 60|  109.2   |   84.0 |   67.2   |  81.2
=======+==========+========+==========+======


It is, then, in the period between 18 and 30 that married persons are
more often guilty of theft than the unmarried; after 30 the parts are
changed, except that under the last two age-classes the widows,
widowers, and divorced persons show high figures.


Embezzlements. [633]

=======+==========+========+==========+======
       |          |        |Widowers, |
 Age.  |Unmarried.|Married.|Widows and|Total.
       |          |        |Divorced. |
-------+----------+--------+----------+------
 18-21 |  123.2   | 338.7  |          | 124.4
 21-25 |  131.6   | 163.6  |  295.6   | 135.5
 25-30 |  139.7   | 109.8  |  291.6   | 126.1
 30-40 |  161.8   |  86.1  |  279.6   | 103.4
 40-50 |  128.0   |  61.1  |  168.8   |  71.3
 50-60 |   66.2   |  37.7  |   71.3   |  42.7
Over 60|   28.3   |  16.6  |   13.9   |  16.7
=======+==========+========+==========+======


In this crime also there is a greater criminality among married persons
between 18 and 25 than among the unmarried, and the opposite for the
later periods. The situation is entirely different in the case of the
crime which follows: [634]


Fraudulent Bankruptcy.

=======+==========+========+==========+======
       |          |        |Widowers, |
 Age.  |Unmarried.|Married.|Widows and|Total.
       |          |        |Divorced. |
-------+----------+--------+----------+------
 18-21 |   0.3    |  33.9  |          | 0.3
 21-25 |   3.3    |  21.3  |          | 4.5
 25-30 |   3.9    |  14.8  |          | 9.8
 30-40 |   4.3    |   9.9  |   15.9   | 9.0
 40-50 |   2.2    |   6.6  |    7.2   | 6.2
 50-60 |   1.1    |   4.0  |    4.1   | 3.7
Over 60|   0.4    |   1.7  |    1.4   | 1.5
=======+==========+========+==========+======


Here we have a higher degree of criminality among the married persons
of all ages.

It is unnecessary to give the figures for all the economic crimes and
it will be enough simply to give the general results for the rest.
Unmarried persons are guilty of the following crimes more often than
married persons: aggravated theft (at all ages); robbery and extortion
(except between the ages of 21 and 25); fraud and criminal breach of
trust (except between the ages of 21 and 25); forgery (except between
21 and 25, and over 60); and counterfeiting. The following offenses are
more often committed by married persons than by unmarried: being
accessory to theft, and receiving stolen goods (except between 30 and
40); violation of secrets; usury; and procuration. It must be added
that widows, widowers and divorced persons show very high figures for
economic offenses.

As to sexual crimes we have the following figures: [635]


=======+====================================++====================================
       |              Incest.               ||    Debauching through Abuse of
       |                                    ||            Confidence.
       +----------+--------+---------+------++----------+--------+---------+------
 Age.  |Unmarried.|Married.| Widows  |      ||Unmarried.|Married.| Widows  |
       |          |        |   and   |Total.||          |        |   and   |Total.
       |          |        |Divorced.|      ||          |        |Divorced.|
-------+----------+--------+---------+------++----------+--------+---------+------
 18-21 |   0.7    |        |         | 0.7  ||   0.03   |        |         | 0.03
 21-25 |   0.8    |  1.4   |         | 0.9  ||   0.20   |  0.4   |         | 0.20
 25-30 |   1.0    |  0.9   |         | 1.0  ||   0.30   |  0.3   |         | 0.30
 30-40 |   1.0    |  1.4   |  22.7   | 1.7  ||   0.20   |  1.5   |   2.3   | 0.40
 40-50 |   0.9    |  1.7   |  26.3   | 2.5  ||   0.40   |  0.4   |   1.2   | 0.50
 50-60 |   0.8    |  1.2   |  12.4   | 2.1  ||   0.20   |  0.3   |   0.7   | 0.30
Over 60|   0.2    |  0.4   |   1.9   | 0.8  ||          |  0.1   |   0.1   | 0.10
=======+==========+========+=========+======++==========+========+=========+======


Consequently, as regards these crimes, the married persons are more
often guilty than the unmarried, but the widowers, widows and divorced
persons occupy the first rank.


=======+=======================================
       |            Rape, Etc.[636]
 Age.  +----------+--------+------------+------
       |Unmarried.|Married.|Widowers and|Total.
       |          |        | Divorced.  |
-------+----------+--------+------------+------
 21-25 |   26.3   |  24.1  |            | 26.1
 25-30 |   26.2   |  15.7  |            | 21.2
 30-40 |   39.7   |  12.8  |    61.4    | 18.6
 40-50 |   44.5   |   9.9  |    56.2    | 14.8
 50-60 |   36.8   |   8.4  |    28.3    | 12.3
 60-70 |   28.3   |   6.8  |    18.7    | 11.1
Over 70|   18.7   |   5.6  |    10.3    |  8.6
=======+==========+========+============+======


Here the unmarried persons are guilty oftener than those married, and
widowers and divorced persons oftenest of all. As for debauch contrary
to nature it is the unmarried persons who are the most often guilty.

Here, finally, are figures for the more important remaining crimes:


=======+======================================================
       |                    Rebellion.[637]
       +------------+----------+------------------+-----------
 Age.  |            |          | Widowers, Widows |
       | Unmarried. | Married. |  and Divorced.   |  Total.
-------+------------+----------+------------------+-----------
 18-21 |   130.5    |  211.7   |       --         |   130.8
 21-25 |   199.0    |  143.6   |       --         |   192.0
 25-30 |   228.2    |  113.8   |     258.0        |   174.2
 30-40 |   262.6    |   83.1   |     236.2        |   119.4
 40-50 |   206.6    |   55.6   |     160.4        |    73.6
 50-60 |    92.0    |   34.2   |      59.6        |    40.8
Over 60|    25.2    |   14.5   |      11.2        |    14.3
=======+============+==========+==================+============


===============================================================
       |                  Insults.[638]
       +------------+----------+------------------+------------
 Age.  |            |          |  Widowers and    |
       | Unmarried. | Married. |   Divorced.      |  Total.
-------+------------+----------+------------------+------------
 18-21 |    111.1   |  444.5   |      --          |   112.5
 21-25 |    173.3   |  279.0   |     448.0        |   186.7
 25-30 |    222.9   |  270.6   |     381.4        |   249.3
 30-40 |    277.4   |  316.2   |     377.3        |   312.8
 40-50 |    240.7   |  311.3   |     317.3        |   307.3
 50-60 |    158.1   |  237.7   |     187.5        |   229.4
Over 60|     66.4   |  122.9   |      66.6        |   103.7
=======+============+==========+==================+============


Here the married persons have the highest figures at all ages.


=======+=======================================================
       |                Assaults.[639]
 Age.  +------------+----------+------------------+------------
       | Unmarried. |  Married.|   Widowers and   |
       |            |          |     Divorced.    |  Total.
-------+------------+----------+------------------+------------
 18-21 |  1,084.2   | 1,778.2  |      --          |  1,087.3
 21-25 |  1,132.5   | 1,051.5  |   1,344.0        |  1,124.1
 25-30 |    904.6   |   692.9  |     964.7        |    803.3
 30-40 |    552.6   |   434.1  |     602.3        |    459.7
 40-50 |    262.9   |   268.1  |     316.1        |    269.6
 50-60 |    117.7   |   161.9  |     144.6        |    157.2
Over 60|     43.5   |    68.6  |      40.9        |     59.0
=======+============+==========+==================+============


The unmarried show in general higher figures than the married persons
(except for the period between 18 and 21).


=======+=========================================
       |       Murder and Homicide.[640]
       +-----------+---------+------------+------
 Age.  |Unmarried. |Married. |Widowers and|Total.
       |           |         |  Divorced. |
-------+-----------+---------+------------+------
 18-21 |    2.2    |         |            | 2.2
 21-25 |    3.1    |   2.1   |            | 3.0
 25-30 |    3.1    |   2.0   |            | 2.6
 30-40 |    3.3    |   1.4   |    13.6    | 1.9
 40-50 |    1.8    |   0.9   |     6.0    | 1.9
 50-60 |    0.8    |   0.5   |     2.1    | 0.7
Over 60|    0.2    |   0.3   |     0.2    | 0.3
=======+===========+=========+============+======


Here it is the widowers, widows and divorced persons who are most
involved, and then the unmarried.

For some other crimes we shall give only the results. Married persons
are more often guilty of the following crimes than the unmarried;
domiciliary trespass (except between 25 and 50); perjury (except
between 21 and 25, and between 30 and 40) and other offenses against
the obligation of taking oath; false accusation; unintentional homicide
(except between 25 and 30); offenses against personal liberty (except
between 30 and 50); and crimes and misdemeanors committed by public
officials.

For the following crimes, on the other hand, the unmarried hold the
first rank: offenses against public worship (except between 21 and 25);
malicious mischief (except between 18 and 21); and arson. It is to be
noted that for nearly all the above the widowers, widows and divorced
persons show very high figures.

After an examination of the results found it is impossible to say that
the married persons show absolutely a criminality less in degree than
that of the unmarried; there is a variation for offenses as well as for
ages. Only considered in general, the tendency to crime is less in the
case of the married than of the unmarried.

As the following figures prove the connection between crime and
marriage is quite different in the case of women. It is necessary,
however, to show the following table before giving figures in support
of this assertion.


Germany, 1886–1890. [641]

=======+=======================================================
       |Number of Acquittals to 100 Accused Persons of Each Age
 Age.  |                        Group.
       +----------------+--------------+-----------------------
       |   Unmarried.   |   Married.   |  Widowed and Divorced.
-------+----------------+--------------+-----------------------
 18-21 |      15.1      |     25.6     |
 21-25 |      16.8      |     24.5     |         24.1
 25-30 |      16.7      |     24.2     |         19.7
 30-40 |      17.3      |     23.4     |         19.6
 40-50 |      18.2      |     24.2     |         21.7
 50-60 |      18.2      |     25.8     |         24.4
Over 60|      19.8      |     27.0     |         27.7
=======+================+==============+=======================


As in the case of men there are, then, a greater percentage of
acquittals among the married than among the unmarried.


Germany, 1882–1893. [642]

Crimes in General.

=======+==========================================================
       |To 100,000 Persons of Each Age Group there were Sentenced:
 Age.  +------------------+----------------+----------------------
       |    Unmarried.    |    Married.    |     Widowed and
       |                  |                |      Divorced.
-------+------------------+----------------+----------------------
 18-21 |      415.2       |     602.5      |
 21-25 |      417.5       |     469.9      |        1339.3
 25-30 |      440.7       |     454.5      |        1149.2
 30-40 |      446.2       |     500.0      |        1029.9
 40-50 |      334.7       |     468.2      |         709.9
 50-60 |      221.5       |     299.5      |         369.2
Over 60|      102.2       |     133.4      |         111.2
=======+==================+================+======================


While married women of all ages lead the unmarried in general
criminality, the highest figures are shown by the widows and divorcées.

The following tables have to do with the more important crimes,
beginning with those affecting property: [643]


Simple Theft.

=======+==========+========+==========+======
 Age.  |Unmarried.|Married.|Widows and|Total.
       |          |        |Divorcées.|
-------+----------+--------+----------+------
 18-21 |  210.6   | 209.3  |          |210.6
 21-25 |  177.1   | 147.8  |  385.7   |169.3
 25-30 |  158.5   | 132.0  |  318.5   |144.0
 30-40 |  136.6   | 127.1  |  265.9   |135.1
 40-50 |   92.2   | 104.0  |  175.9   |111.6
 50-60 |   61.2   |  64.4  |   88.6   | 70.3
Over 60|   32.0   |  31.1  |   28.0   | 29.5
=======+==========+========+==========+======


The married women show, then, figures a little lower than those of the
unmarried women, except between 40 and 60, and the widows and divorcées
give the highest figures.


=======+===========================+===========================
       |       Embezzlement.       |  Receiving Stolen Goods.
 Age.  +------+----+--------+------+------+----+--------+------
       |Unmar.|Mar.|Wid. and|Total.|Unmar.|Mar.|Wid. and|Total.
       |      |    |  Div.  |      |      |    |  Div.  |
-------+------+----+--------+------+------+----+--------+------
 18-21 | 25.3 |35.2|        | 25.8 |  9.2 |33.7|        | 10.7
 21-25 | 25.9 |23.4|  92.8  | 25.4 | 10.6 |26.3|  48.2  | 15.3
 25-30 | 26.0 |20.3|  80.7  | 23.2 | 12.6 |23.9|  52.4  | 20.2
 30-40 | 25.3 |21.6|  63.4  | 24.2 | 17.2 |32.6|  61.3  | 31.4
 40-50 | 18.6 |18.3|  40.3  | 21.1 | 16.1 |36.4|  56.4  | 36.6
 50-60 | 11.0 |10.3|  17.2  | 12.2 | 11.4 |22.6|  29.6  | 23.3
Over 60|  4.4 | 4.3|   4.6  |  4.4 |  4.5 | 8.8|   7.4  |  7.6
=======+======+====+========+======+======+====+========+======


Under the head of “embezzlement” the unmarried women show figures a
little higher than those of the married women (except between 18 and
21); in the crime of receiving stolen goods the married women are more
guilty than the unmarried; while in both offenses it is the widows and
divorcées who lead.


Procuration.

=======+==========+========+=============+======
 Age.  |Unmarried.|Married.|Wid. and Div.|Total.
-------+----------+--------+-------------+------
 18-21 |    0.6   |   5.2  |             |  0.9
 21-25 |    2.1   |   8.2  |    33.8     |  3.9
 25-30 |    6.4   |  10.1  |    47.5     |  9.2
 30-40 |   10.9   |  11.7  |    47.3     | 13.2
 40-50 |    7.6   |   9.7  |    28.4     | 11.7
 50-60 |    3.5   |   4.5  |    10.4     |  5.9
Over 60|    1.1   |   1.8  |     2.5     |  2.2
=======+==========+========+=============+======


Here also the highest figures are found with the widows and divorcées
and the lowest with the unmarried women. In the following economic
offenses it is the married women who are oftenest guilty: aggravated
theft (except between 18 and 21 and after 60); fraudulent bankruptcy;
forgery (except between 25 and 50); and violation of secrets. We must
once more note that the widows and divorcées show very high figures.

As to sexual crime we have the following:


=======+=======================================
       |                Incest.
 Age.  +-----------+---------+----------+------
       |Unmarried. |Married. |Widows and|Total.
       |           |         |Divorcées.|
-------+-----------+---------+----------+------
 18-21 |    2.7    |   1.4   |          | 2.6
 21-25 |    2.1    |   0.6   |          | 1.7
 25-30 |    2.3    |   0.2   |   8.0    | 1.1
 30-40 |    2.5    |   0.2   |   6.2    | 0.8
 40-50 |    0.6    |   0.1   |   1.2    | 0.3
 50-60 |    0.1    |   0.1   |   0.6    | 0.2
Over 60|    0.1    |   0.02  |   0.1    | 0.07
=======+===========+=========+==========+======


Here the widows and divorcées are at the head and the married women
last. The other sexual crimes give figures for women too small to be of
any value for our purpose.

Certain of the crimes which remain show the following figures:


=======+=====================================
       |              Insults.
 Age.  +----------+--------+----------+------
       |Unmarried.|Married.|Widows and|Total.
       |          |        |Divorcées.|
-------+----------+--------+----------+------
 18-21 |   24.3   |  88.5  |          |  27.9
 21-25 |   34.9   |  85.7  |  157.1   |  50.0
 25-30 |   44.2   |  99.8  |  137.1   |  76.7
 30-40 |   57.3   | 116.8  |  138.4   | 108.1
 40-50 |   58.4   | 121.4  |  121.7   | 114.5
 50-60 |   43.6   |  84.8  |  77.1    |  78.5
Over 60|   22.4   |  38.3  |  26.7    |  30.2
=======+==========+========+==========+======


The highest figures are those for widows and divorcées (except over
50), and the lowest for the unmarried.


=======+=======================================
       |         Domiciliary Trespass.
       +-----------+---------+----------+------
 Age.  |Unmarried. |Married. |Widows and|Total.
       |           |         |Divorcées.|
-------+-----------+---------+----------+------
 18-21 |    5.4    |  16.9   |          |  6.0
 21-25 |    6.9    |  13.3   |   28.6   |  8.9
 25-30 |    8.6    |  15.2   |   28.2   | 13.0
 30-40 |   11.1    |  21.2   |   32.7   | 20.1
 40-50 |   10.6    |  23.9   |   27.2   | 22.8
 50-60 |    6.2    |  15.3   |   15.9   | 14.4
Over 60|    3.0    |   6.0   |    4.2   |  4.7
=======+===========+=========+==========+======


The highest figures are for the widows and divorcées, the lowest for
the unmarried.


=======+=======================================
       |               Assaults.
 Age.  +-----------+---------+----------+------
       |Unmarried. |Married. |Widows and|Total.
       |           |         |Divorcées.|
-------+-----------+---------+----------+------
 18-21 |   20.4    |  67.5   |          | 23.0
 21-25 |   24.9    |  61.1   |   96.4   | 35.7
 25-30 |   29.8    |  58.7   |   88.9   | 48.3
 30-40 |   29.9    |  61.0   |   70.2   | 56.4
 40-50 |   21.3    |  55.3   |   46.8   | 50.4
 50-60 |   13.9    |  33.9   |   25.7   | 29.5
Over 60|    7.0    |  14.2   |    8.6   | 10.4
=======+===========+=========+==========+======


Here the highest figures are those for the married women except between
the ages of 21 and 40 when they fall to the widows and divorcées.


=======+=====================================
       | Crimes against the Life of a Child.
 Age.  +----------+--------+----------+------
       |Unmarried.|Married.|Widows and|Total.
       |          |        |Divorcées.|
-------+----------+--------+----------+------
 18-21 |   5.6    |  4.3   |          | 5.5
 21-25 |   9.8    |  1.7   |    7.1   | 7.4
 25-30 |   9.3    |  1.4   |   16.1   | 4.5
 30-40 |   5.4    |  1.1   |   12.5   | 2.4
 40-50 |   1.3    |  0.8   |    3.4   | 1.2
 50-60 |   0.5    |  0.5   |    0.7   | 0.6
Over 60|   0.1    |  0.3   |    0.2   | 0.2
=======+==========+========+==========+======


In this regard the widows and divorcées show the greatest criminality,
the married women the lowest.

Finally, we may add the results for some other crimes. The married
women are more guilty than the unmarried in the following: rebellion
[644] (except between 21 and 40); violation of factory laws; crimes
against individual liberty; and malicious mischief (except between 25
and 40). In the following the unmarried women lead the married:
perjury, false accusation, homicide and murder (except for the ages
over 50), unintentional homicide (except after 50), and arson. It is to
be noted that the widows and divorcées are at the head.

The conclusion to be drawn is that the married woman commits more
crimes than the unmarried, but that this does not apply to all crimes
nor to all ages.



So much for the figures themselves; now for their explanation.

It is very difficult, in examining the influence of marriage upon
criminality, to separate the moral consequences from other factors. We
are mistaken, for example, if we attribute to the moral influence of
marriage the fact that married persons are less often guilty of the
great majority of economic crimes than the unmarried. The fact that
anyone marries is ordinarily an indication that he is in a material
situation more or less good. The danger that he will commit an economic
offense becomes, then, much less great than when he is in a less
comfortable condition. The correctness of this position is clearly
shown by the statistics given, according to which married men still
young give a higher figure than that furnished by the bachelors. The
reason is that proletarians marry while still young. The material cares
of these husbands are then much greater than later on when their
children have already left home, or are at least earning their own
living. [645] If we examine the figures for insults we shall see that
married men and women both are more guilty than the unmarried. It would
be very erroneous to conclude that marriage increases the tendency to
this offense. The explanation is to be found in the fact that when a
single dwelling (or barrack rather) is the common habitation of several
workmen’s families, living conditions easily become a permanent source
of disputes. In this case it is not marriage but bad housing conditions
which appear as a factor in the etiology of crime. If it were possible
to separate these conditions or these material consequences of marriage
from its moral consequences, the difference between the criminality of
the married and the unmarried would not appear very great. Especially
is this true if we keep sight of the fact that the bourgeoisie
generally marry at a more advanced age than the proletariat. This
brings it about that there are more of the bourgeois among the older
married people than among the younger; and since, from other causes,
the bourgeoisie commit fewer crimes than the proletariat, the influence
of marriage seems greater here than it really is.

As for the criminality of women it must be noted that the unmarried
women of the bourgeoisie represent a greater proportion of the whole
number of unmarried women than the women of this class do of women in
general. And since from other causes the criminality of the women of
this last class is very small, marriage seems to have a less favorable
effect than it really has.

As for the consequences of marriage upon morality, I believe they are
the following. In the first place marriage has a tendency to increase
the feeling of responsibility, especially if there are children. Then
when man and wife understand one another, when they are happy in their
union, no one will deny that marriage has a strong moral influence,
for, according to the proverb, happy people are not wicked. The proof
of this is that married men participate less than bachelors in the
crimes of rebellion, assault, homicide, murder, etc., while widowers
are more often guilty of them, becoming addicted to alcohol after the
death of their wives, or becoming demoralized in other ways. However,
it would be more accurate to speak of the moral influence of love than
of marriage in the sense of legal monogamy. Happy married couples do
not owe their happiness to the legal sanction. Without it their
happiness would be as great. On the other hand if the couple is
ill-assorted for one reason or another, then marriage has a very
demoralizing influence. Legal monogamy comes into play in such cases by
rendering difficult the separation of persons who do not understand
each other, or of whom one or the other conducts himself badly.

The great power of a man over his wife, as a consequence of his
economic preponderance, may equally be a demoralizing cause. It is
certain that there will always be abuse of power on the part of a
number of those whom social circumstances have clothed with a certain
authority. How many women there are who now have to endure the
coarseness and bad treatment of their husbands, but would not hesitate
to leave them if their economic dependence and the law did not prevent.
Holmes, the author of “Pictures and Problems from London Police
Courts”, who for years saw all the unfortunates who came before these
tribunals, says in this connection: “A good number of Englishmen seem
to think they have as perfect a right to thrash or kick their wives as
the American had to ‘lick his nigger.’ Yes, and some of these fellows
are completely astonished when a magistrate ventures to hold a
different opinion. I well remember a great hulking fellow, with a
leg-of-mutton fist, being charged with assaulting a policeman. After
all the evidence had been given, the magistrate inquired whether the
prisoner had been previously charged. ‘Yes, your worship, he was here
two months ago, charged with assaulting a female.’ As the prisoner
declared this was false, and indignantly denied that he had ever
assaulted a female, the gaoler brought in his book and proved the
conviction. The prisoner then looked up in astonishment, and said: ‘Oh,
why, it was only my own wife!’ Only their own wives; but how those
wives suffer! Is there any misery equal to theirs, any slavery to
compare with theirs? If so, I never heard of it. I have seen thousands
of them, and their existence is our shame and degradation.” [646]

Further it goes without saying that a marriage entered into for reasons
of self-interest is demoralizing.

Although the above consequences of marriage must be mentioned, that our
discussion may be as complete as possible, and although they may have a
certain importance for the etiology of crime, yet their influence is
not very great. There are causes of criminality much more important,
which may put those that have been named entirely in the shade. [647]



Before taking up the criminal consequences of the family, I am of the
opinion that this is the best place to fix our attention for a moment
upon the criminality of women. In treating above of the origin of
marriage as it exists today, we have at the same time spoken of the
social position of woman.

d. The criminality of women. In order to give an idea of its extent and
nature we must begin with some statistics.


Germany, 1886–1895. [648]

=======================================+=================================
                                       |To 100,000 Persons Over 12 of the
                                       | Same Sex, There was an Average
                Crimes.                | Number of Persons Sentenced of:
                                       +----------------+----------------
                                       |      Men.      |     Women.
---------------------------------------+----------------+----------------
Simple theft                           |     352.49     |     132.25
Aggravated theft                       |      57.95     |       7.19
Embezzlement                           |      80.97     |      18.25
Robbery and extortion                  |       2.44     |       0.10
Receiving stolen goods                 |      28.21     |      16.33
Fraud                                  |      88.06     |      19.50
Forgery                                |      18.78     |       3.75
Perjury                                |       6.83     |       2.31
Threats                                |      46.36     |       2.65
Procuration                            |       5.21     |       7.23
Rape, etc.                             |      20.63     |       0.15
Insults                                |     204.32     |      69.52
Domiciliary trespass                   |      90.38     |      12.25
Malicious mischief                     |      80.37     |       4.85
Arson                                  |       2.43     |       0.54
Violence and threats against officials |      77.45     |       5.90
Minor assaults                         |     118.30     |      12.71
Serious assaults                       |     256.86     |      25.99
Murder                                 |       0.56     |       0.13
Homicide                               |       0.75     |       0.15
Crimes in general                      |    1847.03     |     380.42
=======================================+================+================


This table shows that women have a general criminality from 4 to 5
times less than that of men. The figure for women exceeds that for men
in the case of one crime only, procuration; for the others it is
smaller, and for some very small (e.g. assaults, assassination, etc.).
The following table gives an idea still clearer and more detailed.


Germany, 1896. [649]

============================================+====================+===============
                                            | Number of Persons  |
                                            |Convicted to 100,000|   Number of
                  Crimes.                   |    of Same Sex.    |Women Convicted
                                            +---------+----------+  to Each 100
                                            |   Men.  |  Women.  | Men Convicted.
--------------------------------------------+---------+----------+---------------
Abandonment of children                     |    0.02 |    0.1   |     800.0
Abortion                                    |    0.4  |    1.7   |     437.3
Procuration                                 |    6.0  |    9.2   |     167.7
Receiving stolen goods (repeated recidivism)|    0.07 |    0.1   |     158.3
    ,,      ,,    ,,   (simple)             |   26.5  |   13.1   |      53.9
Simple theft                                |  274.6  |  100.8   |      40.1
Perjury                                     |    3.1  |    1.2   |      38.7
Insults                                     |  223.7  |   76.5   |      34.2
Simple theft (repeated recidivism)          |   51.7  |   14.4   |      30.5
Homicide                                    |    0.5  |    0.1   |      22.0
Arson                                       |    2.2  |    0.5   |      21.8
Embezzlement                                |   85.6  |   17.6   |      20.6
Fraud                                       |  101.7  |   20.4   |      20.1
Crimes in general                           | 2177.07 |  388.9   |      17.9
Extortion                                   |    3.0  |    0.4   |      14.3
Aggravated theft                            |   45.0  |    5.6   |      13.5
Domiciliary trespass                        |  103.8  |   12.3   |      11.8
Minor assaults                              |  138.3  |   15.4   |      11.1
Aggravated theft (repeated recidivism)      |   14.4  |    1.2   |       9.1
Serious assaults                            |  448.4  |   32.8   |       7.3
Violence, etc. against officials            |   88.3  |    5.6   |       6.3
Violence and threats                        |   60.7  |    3.6   |       5.9
Malicious mischief                          |   93.6  |    5.4   |       5.8
Robbery                                     |    2.4  |    0.07  |       2.9
Crimes against morals upon children         |   25.3  |    0.2   |       0.7
============================================+=========+==========+===============


The country upon which we are about to fix our attention is:


England and Wales, 1893–1900. [650]

======+=======================================================
      |   Number of Women to the 100 Persons Sentenced for:
Years.+-----------------------------+-------------------------
      |Offenses tried on Indictment.|Offenses tried Summarily.
------+-----------------------------+-------------------------
 1893 |            13.07            |          23.39
 1894 |            12.95            |          23.50
 1895 |            13.26            |          23.94
 1896 |            11.75            |          23.58
 1897 |            12.00            |          23.99
 1898 |            11.82            |          23.66
 1899 |            11.70            |          23.89
 1900 |            11.51            |          24.67
======+=============================+=========================


When we examine this table, as well as the one that follows, it must be
noted that the women constitute more than half of the population (51.5%
according to the census of 1901). [651]

The following table shows the relative proportion for the more
important groups of offenses:


England and Wales, 1893–1894. [652]

==========================================+=========================
                                          |   Number of Women to
                                          | 100 Persons Sentenced.
                Crimes.                   +-------------+-----------
                                          |    1893.    |    1894.
------------------------------------------+-------------+-----------
Abortion and failure to report birth      |     91      |     86
Kidnapping and cruelty to children        |     70      |     57
Counterfeiting, etc.                      |     18      |     21
Malicious mischief                        |     15      |     20
Crimes against property without violence  |     19      |     19
Other crimes                              |     16      |     16
Crimes of violence against persons        |     11      |     13
Robbery and extortion                     |     10      |     11
Forgery                                   |      9      |      8
Domiciliary trespass, etc.                |      3      |      4
Sexual crimes                             |      4      |      3
==========================================+=============+===========


These statistics show, then, that in England also the criminality of
women is not as great as that of men. However there is great divergence
in the crimes taken separately.


Austria, 1899. [653]

============================+==========================
                            | Of 100 Convicted of Each
                            |    Crime there were:
         Crimes.            +------------+-------------
                            |    Men.    |   Women.
----------------------------+------------+-------------
Abandonment of children     |     7.1    |    92.8
Abortion                    |    10.7    |    89.2
Murder                      |    69.6    |    30.3
Fraud                       |    79.1    |    20.8
Theft                       |    80.4    |    19.5
Defamation                  |    80.9    |    19.0
Arson                       |    85.2    |    14.7
Crimes in general           |    86.1    |    13.9
Rebellion                   |    89.5    |    10.4
Leze-majesty                |    91.6    |     8.3
Criminal breach of trust    |    93.4    |     6.5
Crime against religion      |    94.8    |     5.1
Robbery                     |    95.1    |     4.8
Serious assaults            |    95.8    |     4.1
Sexual crime                |    96.7    |     3.2
Malicious mischief          |    96.8    |     3.1
Homicide                    |    97.3    |     2.6
Blackmail                   |    97.4    |     2.5
============================+============+=============


In connection with this table we must note that, according to the
census of 1890, 51.6% of the population over 14 are women.


France, 1881–1900 (Persons accused). [654]

=========================+================+================+================+================
                         |   1881-1885.   |   1886-1890.   |   1891-1895.   |   1896-1900.
                         +-----------+----+-----------+----+-----------+----+-----------+----
                         |  Average  |    |  Average  |    |  Average  |    |  Average  |
                         |  Annual   | %  |  Annual   | %  |  Annual   | %  |  Annual   | %
                         |  Number.  |    |  Number.  |    |  Number.  |    |  Number.  |
-------------------------+-----------+----+-----------+----+-----------+----+-----------+----
Before the Assizes:      |           |    |           |    |           |    |           |
    Men                  |    3,767  | 86 |    3,589  | 85 |    3,389  | 84 |    2,900  | 85
    Women                |      615  | 14 |      646  | 15 |      631  | 16 |      500  | 15
-------------------------+-----------+----+-----------+----+-----------+----+-----------+----
Before the Correctional  |           |    |           |    |           |    |           |
  Tribunals:             |           |    |           |    |           |    |           |
    Men                  |  162,573  | 86 |  172,162  | 86 |  179,194  | 86 |  165,586  | 86
    Women                |   26,330  | 14 |   27,719  | 14 |   29,992  | 14 |   28,049  | 14
=========================+===========+====+===========+====+===========+====+===========+====


As the two following tables show, the part which women take in
different crimes varies greatly, as in the countries cited above.


France, 1900 (Assizes). [655]

===============================================+=============================
                                               | To 100 Accused there where:
           Crimes.                             +--------------+--------------
                                               |     Men.     |    Women.
-----------------------------------------------+--------------+--------------
Infanticide                                    |       5      |      95
Abortion                                       |      12      |      88
Domestic theft                                 |      82      |      18
Murder                                         |      84      |      16
Fraudulent bankruptcy                          |      84      |      16
Arson                                          |      84      |      16
Counterfeiting                                 |      85      |      15
Serious assault                                |      86      |      14
Crimes in general                              |      86      |      14
Homicide                                       |      90      |      10
Other aggravated thefts                        |      91      |       9
Parricide                                      |      92      |       8
Forgery                                        |      92      |       8
Concealment or false attribution of parentage  |      93      |       7
Rape and indecent assault upon children        |      98      |       2
Breach of trust                                |      98      |       2
Theft with violence                            |      98      |       2
===============================================+==============+==============


For the correctional tribunals the figures are as follows:


France, 1900 (Correctional Tribunals). [656]

================================+======================================
                                | To 100 Persons Arraigned there were:
           Offenses.            +------------------+-------------------
                                |       Men.       |      Women.
--------------------------------+------------------+-------------------
Concealment of parentage        |         5        |        95
Offenses against chastity       |        29        |        71
Adultery                        |        50        |        50
Defamation and insult           |        75        |        25
Theft                           |        80        |        20
Fraud                           |        83        |        17
Offenses against public decency |        85        |        15
All offenses                    |        87        |        13
Criminal breach of trust        |        88        |        12
Assaults                        |        89        |        11
Mendicity                       |        89        |        11
Domiciliary trespass            |        91        |         9
Rebellion                       |        92        |         8
Vagrancy                        |        95        |         5
================================+==================+===================


It is only in some few crimes that women play a larger part than men
(infanticide, abortion, concealment of parentage, offenses against
chastity—including procuration); in all others they play a smaller
part, and in some cases much smaller, than the men.

We turn now to Italy:


Italy, 1884–1895. [657]

=======+===========================================================================
       |                       Number of Women Convicted.
       +-----------------+-----------------+-----------------+---------------------
Years. | Justices of the |  Correctional   |    Assizes.     |        Total.
       |    Peace.       |    Tribunals.   |                 |
       +---------+-------+---------+-------+---------+-------+------------+--------
       | Number. |   %   | Number. |   %   | Number. |   %   | Number.    |   %
-------+---------+-------+---------+-------+---------+-------+------------+--------
 1884  |  46,683 | 18.31 |   --    |  --   |   304   |  6.00 |  --        |   --
 1885  |  48,063 | 17.58 |   --    |  --   |   304   |  5.91 |  --        |   --
 1886  |  51,199 | 18.23 |   --    |  --   |   297   |  6.38 |  --        |   --
 1887  |  45,598 | 17.58 |  4,690  |  9.30 |   265   |  5.11 | 50,553     |  16.05
 1888  |  49,125 | 17.38 |  4,482  |  8.56 |   290   |  5.81 | 53,897     |  15.86
 1889  |  53,690 | 18.38 |  4,910  |  9.08 |   272   |  5.68 | 58,872[658]|  16.78
 1890  |   --    |  --   |   --    |  --   |   --    |  --   | 23,984     |  18.29
 1891  |         |       |         |       |         |       | 26,182     |  18.23
 1892  |         |       |         |       |         |       | 25,638     |  17.21
 1893  |         |       |         |       |         |       | 22,959     |  16.21
 1894  |         |       |         |       |         |       | 26,274     |  17.34
 1895  |         |       |         |       |         |       | 28,502     |  16.96
=======+=========+=======+=========+=======+=========+=======+============+========


The following table shows us to what extent the women are guilty of the
different crimes:


Italy, 1891–1895. [659]

======================================================+==========================
                                                      |   To 100 Sentenced for
                                                      | Each Offense there were:
           Offenses.                                  +------------+-------------
                                                      |    Men.    |   Women.
------------------------------------------------------+------------+-------------
Infanticide                                           |    7.70    |   92.30
Procuration                                           |   19.11    |   80.89
Abortion                                              |   21.65    |   78.35
Defamation                                            |   53.70    |   46.30
Insults                                               |   54.78    |   45.22
Offenses against morals and order of the family       |   58.27    |   41.73
Abandonment of children, abuse of means of correction |   62.85    |   37.15
Simple theft                                          |   75.63    |   24.37
Fraud in commerce and industry                        |   79.46    |   20.54
Offenses in general                                   |   82.81    |   17.19
Minor assaults                                        |   83.32    |   16.68
Corruption of minors and offenses against decency     |   84.80    |   15.20
Fraud, etc.                                           |   85.74    |   14.26
Aggravated theft                                      |   88.77    |   11.23
Threats                                               |   90.68    |    9.32
Rebellion and insults to public officials             |   90.95    |    9.05
Forgery                                               |   92.49    |    7.51
Serious assaults                                      |   93.61    |    6.39
Murder                                                |   93.91    |    6.09
Counterfeit money                                     |   95.02    |    4.98
Homicide                                              |   96.74    |    3.26
Offenses against public order                         |   97.70    |    2.30
Robbery, etc.                                         |   97.77    |    2.23
Rape, etc.                                            |   99.04    |    0.96
======================================================+============+=============


According to the census of 1901 the population over 9 years old
consisted of 49.4% men and 50.6% women. [660]



Finally some figures for the Netherlands:


Netherlands, 1896–1900. [661]

========+====================================
        |         Number Sentenced.
        +-----------------+------------------
 Years. |         Men.    |       Women.
        +----------+------+----------+-------
        |  Number. |   %  |  Number. |   %
--------+----------+------+----------+-------
  1896  |  13,964  | 89.6 |   1,625  | 10.4
  1897  |  14,483  | 90.0 |   1,613  | 10.0
  1898  |  14,018  | 89.5 |   1,646  | 10.5
  1899  |  13,928  | 90.5 |   1,463  |  9.5
  1900  |  13,234  | 91.3 |   1,254  |  8.7
========+==========+======+==========+=======


Women participate in the different crimes in the following proportions:


Netherlands, 1901. [662]

================================================+==============================
                                                | To 100 Sentenced there were:
           Crimes.                              +--------------+---------------
                                                |     Men.     |    Women.
------------------------------------------------+--------------+---------------
Debauch of a minor (as principal or accessory)  |      6.2     |     93.8
Simple insults                                  |     64.9     |     35.1
Simple theft                                    |     79.0     |     21.0
Fraud                                           |     80.0     |     20.0
Offenses against public decency                 |     81.8     |     18.2
Homicide                                        |     89.5     |     10.5
Aggravated theft                                |     90.5     |      9.5
Embezzlement                                    |     91.1     |      8.9
Receiving stolen goods                          |     91.8     |      8.2
Forgery                                         |     92.1     |      7.9
Assault                                         |     93.5     |      6.5
Serious assault                                 |     94.7     |      5.3
Malicious mischief                              |     95.5     |      4.5
Mendicity and vagrancy                          |     96.5     |      3.5
Assaults upon officials                         |     97.3     |      2.7
Domiciliary trespass                            |     98.1     |      1.9
Rebellion                                       |     98.7     |      1.3
================================================+==============+===============


The whole population being divided in 1901 into 50.5% women and 49.5%
men, the figures given above make the criminality of woman appear a
little greater than it really is.



Here, then, are the facts, which may be reduced to this, that in all
the countries named the criminality of women is much less than that of
men. However, it is greater than we should suppose from the figures,
since almost all the figures (except those for France) have to do with
persons convicted, and acquittal is much more common in the case of
women than in that of men. We have already given the figures for
Germany in regard to this matter. In England the percentage of
convictions is 82% for men and 79% for women. [663]


In France the differences are still greater:


France, 1881–1890 (Assizes). [664]

=======+===================================================
       |         Percentage of Acquittals.
 Sex.  +------------+------------+------------+------------
       | 1881-1885. | 1886-1890. | 1891-1895. | 1896-1900.
-------+------------+------------+------------+------------
Men    |     25     |     25     |     26     |     28
Women  |     45     |     47     |     50     |     52
=======+============+============+============+============


1896–1900 (Correctional Tribunals). [665]

=======+================================================
       | Percentage of Acquittals to Each Age-category.
 Sex.  +---------------+---------------+----------------
       |   Under 16.   |   16 to 21.   |   Over 21.
-------+---------------+---------------+----------------
Men    |      57       |       6       |       5
Women  |      58       |       9       |       7
=======+===============+===============+================


These figures lead to the presumption that in other countries also
women are more apt to be acquitted than men.

Other reasons why the criminality of women seems smaller than it really
is are the following: As is shown by the statistics cited, the offenses
of which women are most often guilty, are also those which it is most
difficult to discover, namely those committed without violence. Then,
those who have been injured are less likely to bring a complaint
against a woman than against a man. [666] But even when we take account
of all these things, the criminality of women remains much smaller than
that of men. This may be explained as follows:

First. An examination of the tables shows that women participate less
in the crimes which require strength or courage. The first cause is to
be found in the fact, then, that the average woman of our time has less
strength and courage than the average man, and consequently commits on
the average fewer crimes than he.

Second. It is clear that women take small part in sexual crimes (for
procuration is not a sexual crime but an economic one), which is to be
explained by the fact that most sexual crimes cannot, from their
nature, be committed by women. Another reason is that the rôle of women
in the sexual life (and thus in the criminal sexual life) is rather
passive than active.

Third. The small part played by women in economic crimes committed
because of poverty or even of greed, is explained by prostitution,
which generally yields greater and more certain returns than crime, and
avoids the risk of prison.

Fourth. A comparison of the criminal statistics of different countries
has not much value for the different reasons already given (Pt. I, Ch.
II, sec. XIX). Only when the figures are very different may one draw a
conclusion from them. A comparison of the tables brings out the fact
that the criminality of women does not differ much in the countries
named. However, when we fix our attention upon the crimes and
misdemeanors more or less grave in the Italian statistics (assizes and
correctional tribunals) we discover that there is a considerable
difference between England, for example, on the one side, and Italy on
the other. While the former country shows about 12% (offenses tried on
indictment) and 23% (offenses tried summarily) of women among those
convicted, the figures are 5 to 6% (assizes) and about 9% (corr. trib.)
in the latter country. This difference shows that the direction in
which the principal reason for woman’s small part in crime must be
sought, is in her social position. This differs less from that of the
man in England than in Italy. However, there are figures much more
significant than those I have just cited. Between 1893 and 1899 the
percentage of convicts in prison in Scotland was between 36 and 37.
[667] In Denmark from 1876 to 1885 about 26% of the convicts were
women. [668] It is an incontestable fact that Denmark and Scotland are
countries where the social position of women approaches most closely
that of men. Let us set in opposition to this now a country like
Algeria where the life of woman is entirely different. It appears that
there between 1881 and 1900 3% of those arraigned before the assizes
were women, and 4% of those arraigned before the correctional
tribunals. [669]

An examination of the criminality of women in the different parts of
the same country, Germany for example, shows that the highest figures
for female criminality are furnished by the great cities and the
countries most developed economically.


Germany, 1897–1898. [670]

=============================+=========================================
                             | Percentage of Women among the Convicts.
    Cities or Countries.     +--------------------+--------------------
                             |       1897.        |       1898.
-----------------------------+--------------------+--------------------
Berlin                       |       27.8         |       27.6
Hamburg                      |       24.7         |       25.3
Saxony                       |       22.0         |       21.7
Prussia                      |       21.8         |       21.5
Germany as a whole           |       20.6         |       20.3
Bavaria                      |       18.6         |       18.6
Alsace-Lorraine              |       17.3         |       18.1
Wurtemberg                   |       16.7         |       15.8
Hesse                        |       15.2         |       14.4
Baden                        |       13.8         |       12.1
=============================+====================+====================


As regards England, Morrison says that of misdemeanors 25% are
committed by women in London (Metropolitan Police District), and 33% in
Manchester; while women commit only 10% of the misdemeanors in Surrey,
and about 14% in Lancashire. [671] The high percentages come then in
the places where the social position of woman is most nearly equal to
that of man.

Dr. H. Hoegel gives the following table for Austria. As the author says
it proves that the country where the woman takes the greatest part in
the economic life gives the highest figures for female criminality.

As to the movement of the criminality of women the data that I have
given, and others that I have at my disposal, are not significant
enough to lead to a definite conclusion. In England it has been made
out that there is a small diminution of serious crimes and a slight
increase of minor offenses, though the period of observation is very
short. Between 1881 and 1900 the relative criminality of men and women
remained constant. In Italy there was between 1890 and 1895 a slight
increase in the absolute number, and a slight, but fluctuating,
diminution in the relative number. In the Netherlands the proportions
remained pretty constant from 1896 to 1901.


Austria, 1889–1893. [672]

======================+====================================+=======================
                      |         Number of Women to         | Number of Convictions
       Country.       +--------------------+---------------+  for Crime to 10,000
                      | 100 of Population. | 100 Convicts. |    of Population.
----------------------+--------------------+---------------+-----------------------
Moravia               |        52.5        |     18.0      |         15.9
Silesia               |        52.5        |     17.8      |         17.8
Salzburg              |        50.9        |     17.6      |         17.6
Bohemia               |        52.0        |     17.2      |          8.9
Lower Austria         |        51.4        |     16.7      |         14.1
Upper Austria         |        50.9        |     16.1      |         13.9
Austria               |        51.4        |     14.9      |         12.6
Carinthia             |        51.6        |     14.7      |         18.5
Galicia               |        51.0        |     13.7      |      13.7-10.4[673]
Tyrol and Vorarlberg  |        51.4        |     13.5      |      10.5-12.0[674]
Styria                |        50.7        |     12.9      |         17.3
Bukowina              |        50.0        |     11.8      |         13.3
Littoral of Trieste   |        50.2        |      8.8      |         14.2
Carniola              |        52.5        |      7.5      |         19.5
Dalmatia              |        50.0        |      6.8      |         13.9
======================+====================+===============+=======================


The following are the figures for Germany and Austria:


Germany, 1888–1900. [675]

=======+=================================+=================
       |        Number Convicted.        |    Number of
Years. +---------------------------------+ Women Convicted
       | To the 100,000 | To the 100,000 | to Each 100 Men
       |  Men over 12.  | Women over 12. |   Convicted.
-------+----------------+----------------+-----------------
 1888  |   1,821.7      |     358.0      |      19.7
 1894  |   2,164.3      |     374.9      |      18.7
 1896  |   2,177.7      |     388.9      |      17.9
 1898  |     --         |      --        |      19.5
 1900  |     --         |      --        |      19.3
=======+================+================+=================


There was, then, an increase in the criminality of women, but a smaller
increase than that of men (except in 1898).


Austria, 1881–1899. [676]

Percentage of Persons Convicted who were Women.

===========+============+============+=======+=======+=======+======
1881-1885. | 1886-1890. | 1891-1895. | 1896. | 1897. | 1898. | 1899.
-----------+------------+------------+-------+-------+-------+------
   14.8    |    14.6    |    14.7    | 14.1  | 14.4  | 13.5  | 13.9
===========+============+============+=======+=======+=======+======


Here, then, there was a slight but fluctuating diminution in the
criminality of women in proportion to that of men.

It must be conceded that the figures given do not contribute much to
the support of the thesis that it is especially the social position of
women which is the cause of their being less criminal. This position
has been modified during the years to which the figures given refer.
Women participate much more than formerly in the whole economic and
social life. One would accordingly naturally look for a great increase
in the criminality of women. Nevertheless these figures cannot, it
seems to me, be used to refute the thesis in question, for the
following reasons:

In the first place the figures given cover a short period only. They do
not show very much, therefore; for, notwithstanding the continual
increase of the importance of the rôle of woman in the economic life,
the modification of her position in the whole social life is not made
so quickly that one can expect much of an increase in female
criminality in the criminal statistics of the last few years. [677]

In the second place, most of the figures give the ratio of the crimes
of women to those of men; they do not then show whether the decrease in
the percentage is due to a decrease in the criminality of women, or
rather to an increase in that of men. This latter is the case, for
example, in Germany. [678]

In the third place the statistics at my disposal are not sufficiently
detailed with regard to the movement of the criminality of women, so
that it is impossible to tell whether there are changes in the
qualitative character of the crimes even though its quantitative
character remains about the same. [679]

A very conclusive proof of the thesis that the social position of woman
is what explains her lower criminality, is as follows. The difference
in the manner of life of the two sexes decreases as we descend the
social scale. If the social position of woman is then an important
determinant of her lower criminality, the figures ought to show that
the criminality of men differs more from that of women in the
well-to-do classes than in classes less privileged. Now the figures
already given (pp. 482 ff.) upon the intellectual development of
criminals confirm our hypothesis completely. Just so the tables upon
the financial situation of criminals (see pp. 493, 494); in Austria,
for example, 0.2% of the women convicted in 1899 came from the
well-to-do classes, and 0.4% of the men. There were no well-to-do women
at all among those convicted of the graver crimes. Just so again, in
the table of Prussian recidivists the women form 4% of the well-to-do
convicts and 14% of the poor convicts.

Finally the figures for the influence of marriage upon criminality show
(see p. 513 ff.) that the criminality of widows is very great. This
proves that the smaller criminality of woman is not to be sought in
innate qualities, but rather in the social environment. For widows are
generally forced to come into contact with the economic and social life
of the world more than other women.

We have still to explain how social position is a cause of a lower
degree of criminality. As to economic offenses, it must be remarked
that the small part that woman plays in the economic life has the
result that the desire to be enriched at some one else’s expense is
less aroused in her than it is in man, and that the opportunity to
accomplish the desire is presented to her less often than to him. As to
crimes committed for vengeance etc., since women live more retired
lives they enter less quickly into conflict with others, and hence are
less in danger of committing such crimes. Then the fact that women are
less addicted to alcohol must be taken into account. The almost wholly
negligible participation of women in political life explains why they
are almost never guilty of political crimes, a kind of crime rare
enough in any case.

After the long detour that we have made (in order to comprehend what
follows), we come now at last to the subject which especially concerns
us in this section, the influence of the economic and social life upon
the social sentiments of women.

It results from this examination that, on the one hand, women feel
generally less than men the direct harmful influences of the present
economic system, and those of alcoholism; that the influence, very
significant for criminality, of the environment in which she passes her
youth, acts as strongly upon her as upon a man; and that militarism has
no influence upon her, nor has prostitution itself upon the majority of
the sex.

Then woman has lived for ages in a state of oppression injurious to the
development of the social instincts, which forces her to have recourse
to lying and hypocrisy, those two defensive weapons of the oppressed.
Just so also her retired life has been an obstacle to the development
of her feeling of solidarity with reference to persons outside of the
family.

In looking the whole field over I see nothing to justify the opinion
that the less criminal character of women indicates a higher morality,
whether innate or acquired. The consequences of her manner of life, in
so far as they are harmful to the formation of character, are probably
counterbalanced by those which are favorable. Her smaller criminality
is like the health of a hothouse plant; it is due not to innate
qualities, but to the hothouse which protects it from harmful
influences. If the life of women were like that of men their
criminality would hardly differ at all as to quantity, though perhaps
somewhat as to quality. [680]

e. The family. Here we have to take up the question of how far the
family in which the criminal has been raised has contributed to make
him such. It will be well to begin with some theoretical observations
upon the question, what is the effect of moral education upon a child
(in the larger sense of moral surroundings), and how far does this
education in the end affect the adult?

It is unnecessary for us to tarry long upon this. The facts which we
shall cite below are more convincing than all the theoretical
observations, and they show clearly how great this influence is.
Nevertheless some brief observations are necessary. It is not far from
the truth, it seems to me, to say that the power of moral education
upon the character, and that of intellectual education upon the
intelligence, are equal. The thesis has been maintained that the
intellectual capacities of all men are equal, and that education is the
sole cause of the great differences which exist. No reasonable person
would maintain this theory; men differ enormously in their innate
intellectual capacities; some have great intellectual power, others
have very little, while between the two extremes is found the general
average. What now is the rôle that education has to play?

Those who have small intellectual capacity naturally never become
superior men, even if their education is the best possible; though by
virtue of proper education they might become fairly useful. Those who
have great intellectual capacity also need education (though less so
than the run of mankind), for otherwise their faculties will remain
dormant. Darwin would never have made his great discovery if he had
been born and reared in the slums of a great city and had learned
nothing (even supposing that, with his poor health, he had not
succumbed to such an environment). His acquaintances would have
doubtless thought him intelligent, but the scientific world would never
have heard of him.

It must be much the same with the moral faculty. We are not born with
moral precepts in our heads, but only with a greater or less
predisposition to become moral. If this predisposition, even though it
be very strong, is not cultivated, there is no question of morality.

The child, even more than the man, is an imitator, and responds to
suggestion in everything, but especially in morals. If we put the
question: how does it happen that there are honest persons? the answer
must be: largely because in their youth they have become accustomed to
be honest. [681] In his “Descent of Man”, Darwin says: ... “Habit in
the individual would ... play a very important part in guiding the
conduct of each member; for the social instinct, together with
sympathy, is like any other instinct, greatly strengthened by habit,
and so consequently would be obedience to the wishes and judgment of
the community.” [682]

A great proportion of the whole number of criminals have become such
through the evil example of those about them, or have even been
deliberately trained to crime. Even those who are endowed with great
innate moral capacities cannot withdraw themselves from these
influences. One of the men most competent to speak on this subject, M.
Raux, director of one of the penitentiary districts in France, and
author of one of the best books upon juvenile criminality says, after
speaking of the miserable environment in which young criminals are
brought up: “Let no one attempt to tell us after these revelations that
the child, born in surroundings which asphyxiate him morally, can
escape from vice. No nature would resist such demoralizing agencies. In
order to convince ourselves of the truth of this it would only be
necessary to try an experiment, which, it if were possible, would not
fail to be conclusive.

“The method would be to transport some children of the middle or
wealthy class, neither of which furnish any inmates to our
reformatories, into families considered as types of those from which
our young delinquents come, and to substitute for them in their former
homes the children of poor families. This double substitution would
have immediate effects. Little time would be needed, very little, we
are convinced, for the former group of children to lose all trace of
their early education and to become thoroughly bad characters. As to
the other group, a moral movement in the other direction would be
produced in them, but much more slowly. Vices are like diseases, they
take hold quickly, and let go with difficulty. There would long remain
to the second group a taste for vagabondage and gross pleasures. But
when even these habits and impressions of childhood are painfully
eradicated, well-being, advice, and care would always keep the child
away from the possibility of theft, and after a certain time of
probation passed in the bosom of well-to-do and respectable families
the public would certainly regard our subjects, grown to be men, as
upright and worthy of all confidence. Thus we should have transformed
children of good character into malefactors, and of the malefactor we
should have made an honest man.

“This experiment, which no good family would consent to try for fear of
the result, would prove on the one hand, that any child placed in the
living conditions of most of our young delinquents would inevitably
become vicious and criminal, and on the other that if circumstances
easily make a malefactor of a child well brought-up, it is much more
difficult to transform a bad character into an honest man.” [683]

In consequence of what we have just said we may put two questions;
first, do all those who are brought up in such an environment
inevitably become criminals; second, is there, then, no difference as
to morality between two persons of whom one is born with a strong and
the other with a weak moral disposition (supposing that both live in
the same unfavorable moral environment)?

The answer to the first question must be that there may be sometimes
those who succeed notwithstanding the very bad surroundings of their
youth. (As we have seen, an expert like Raux denies this possibility.)
But such cases are very rare and prove nothing against the theory of
environment, for it may readily happen that such persons fall in with a
better environment (at school, for example) which puts them on the
right track, if they have a strong moral disposition by nature.

To the second question the answer must be made that one endowed with a
strong moral disposition, but raised in unfavorable surroundings, will
perhaps become criminal, and yet need not be as bad as another with a
weak moral disposition, raised in a like environment.

There are criminals and criminals. Anyone who has given himself the
trouble of reading the biographies of great criminals knows that all
have not been entirely corrupted. It is with morals as with
intelligence; in unfavorable circumstances Darwin would not have become
a genius, but even in such environment he would nevertheless have been
recognized as intelligent; so a child with great moral capacity would
not become an honest man when brought up in the company of thieves and
assassins, but in his own circle would have been considered as a good
boy.

Beside very bad environments there are the great mass of those that are
neither the one thing nor the other, in which the children neither have
bad examples, nor are, properly speaking, deserted, but in which,
nevertheless, they do not receive an education positively good. What is
the influence of such environments? They are absolutely insufficient
for children with little moral disposition. These have need of a strong
and well-taught guide, without which they run much danger of leaving,
sooner or later, the straight path. It is evident that an education
such as that in question, is insufficient for the great middle class.
The future lot of these young people will depend especially upon the
circumstances in which chance shall place them. The surroundings spoken
of will be enough for those who have great moral capacities, in the
sense not that a better environment would not have had a better effect
upon them but in the sense that they are more susceptible to the good
than to the evil influences and—except in rare circumstances—they will
cause less trouble to their fellows.

Finally, how far does the effect of a good education extend? What can a
good education do for a person born with weak social instincts? This is
the well-known controversy. For no one denies that those who are
endowed with strong social instincts, as well as those who have them
only in moderation, and who constitute the great majority, do not
become bad when they are brought up in a good environment.

It will perhaps be impossible to give a decisive answer to this
question. For, since we cannot make experiments with living persons, we
cannot get sure results. And then an education really good is so great
a rarity that the number of cases where children with little moral
disposition are excellently brought up is certainly very small. [684]

We may consider it as certain that children not well endowed will never
become very altruistic even if brought up under the best conditions
imaginable. But on the other hand no one would doubt that a favorable
environment would develop, however little, their weak social instincts
(for no one is wholly without such instincts). For the moment we cannot
decide how far this influence may extend.

After this introduction we come to the organization of education in
present-day society. Before stating the facts we must sum up what has
been said above (see Ch. I., Sec. III, B, of this part). The
organization of our present social system charges the legitimate
parents of the child with his support and education. Most authors who
treat of the family wax so enthusiastic that they lose all critical
sense. They note that there are parents who love their children,
perform all their duties towards them, etc., and they wish to make
themselves believe that this is the general rule. But the subject must
be considered in cold blood. Certainly it would be ridiculous to deny
the social importance of the family; we may even say without hesitation
that without the family our present society could not exist. But all
this would not be a reason for not seeing its defects.

Are there not many who are bad, even aside from criminals? Is not the
majority of mankind made up of those weak in character? Are there not
many alcoholics? Are there not persons who do not love their children
at all? Are not the persons numerous who have little patience and tact
to guide children, or who are lacking in other pedagogic qualities? Is
it not true that nearly everyone is ignorant of psychological and
pedagogical principles? And have not most men their whole time taken up
with the struggle for existence, so that they are not able to concern
themselves with the education of their children?

These are the questions that we must ask ourselves; and the answer to
all of them is categorically: yes. And have not all these persons
offspring? Most certainly. Then the results may be imagined. It will be
of the highest importance to know how many children receive an
education that is really good. I do not know of any statistics covering
any very great number of children. But it will not be far from the
truth to infer that the following figures are applicable, not simply to
a limited number, but in general to all children. These figures are
given by Ferriani: [685]

To each 100 children between 8 and 12 years of age:


              Good education                    5
              Education fair                   10
                 ,,     superficial            20
                 ,,     partially neglected    17
                 ,,     entirely    ,,         42
                 ,,     bad                     6
                                              ---
                                              100


One of the characteristics of our present education is that it makes
children egoistic. It is to be expected. The organization of society
obliges men to be egoistic, and “like father, like son.” An apparent
morality is the consequence. Children are taught that they ought to do
or leave undone this or that, not because it is needful to help their
fellows or not to injure them, but because it will be advantageous to
them to act morally, or because otherwise they will be punished. It is
unnecessary to say that brought up in such a manner, the individual
will not recoil from crime because of any moral restraint, when the
opportunity presents itself of making a profit, or when the risk of
being punished is not great.

As to education among the well-to-do classes, there it is especially
egoistic. The children—speaking of course in a general way—are brought
up with the idea that they must succeed, no matter how; the aim of life
is presented to them as getting money and shining in the world. Such
principles are incompatible with a really moral education, and the
education of this class aims only at an apparent morality instead of a
real one. [686]

Whatever may be the defects of this education, it is at least an
education; the children are watched, prevented from getting into bad
society, etc. The consequence is that the children of the well-to-do
almost never get into the courts. This sad monopoly is reserved for the
children of the poor. [687] This is not to say that the defects of
education among the well-to-do classes are not among the causes of the
criminality to be met with in the adults of these classes. When a poor
devil appears in court it will often happen that his counsel in
defending him will draw attention to the fact that the environment in
which his client has grown up is one of the causes of his fall; but it
does not often happen that the advocate makes a similar appeal when his
client is from the well-to-do. It is generally believed that nothing is
wanting in the moral education of one who has not known poverty, and
has not been neglected; but this is a mistake. There can be no doubt
that one of the factors of criminality among the bourgeoisie is bad
education.

The figures of the following tables show that it is almost exclusively
the children of the poor who are guilty of crime.


England and Scotland.

According to the English law the parents of children placed in a
“Reformatory” or an “Industrial School” must, if they are able,
contribute toward their children’s expenses. The following table shows
the assessments due in 1882 (in shillings per week). [688]


===================+==========+==========+=========+=========+=========+=========+========+========
                   |          |          |  Less   |    1    |    2    |    3    |   4    |   5
                   |  Total.  |  Exempt. |  than   |  Shill. |  Shill. |  Shill. | Shill. | Shill.
                   |          |          |    1    |   and   |   and   |   and   |  and   |
                   |          |          |  Shill. |  More.  |  More.  |  More.  | More.  |
-------------------+----------+----------+---------+---------+---------+---------+--------+--------
Reformatories      |          |          |         |         |         |         |        |
  Absolute numbers |  6,601   |  3,858   |  257    | 1,818   |   573   |   66    |  15    |  14
  Percentage       |    100.0 |     58.5 |    3.9  |    27.5 |     8.7 |    1.0  |   0.2  |   0.2
Industrial Schools |          |          |         |         |         |         |        |
  Absolute numbers | 17,641   | 10,406   |  600    | 3,904   | 2,316   |  301    |  67    |  20
  Percentage       |    100.0 |     59.1 |    3.4  |    22.2 |    13.1 |    1.7  |   0.4  |   0.1
===================+==========+==========+=========+=========+=========+=========+========+========


A little less than 60% of the parents, then, were unable to make any
contribution, 25 to 30% of them were able to pay less than two
shillings, while the remaining 10 or 15% were working people not at all
well-to-do. [689]


France.[689]

The French “statistique pénitentiaire” gives information with regard to
the financial condition of the parents of the children received into
the “Etablissements d’éducation correctionnelle.” The following figures
covering the years 1878 to 1882 [690] will give a sufficiently accurate
notion, as figures for a longer period would lead to the same results.


================+============+===========+===========+===========+===========+============
                |            |           |           |           |           | 1878-1882
    Children    |    1878.   |   1879.   |   1880.   |   1881.   |   1882.   |  Average
   Belonging    |            |           |           |           |           | Percentage.
   to Parents   +-----+------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+------
                |Boys.|Girls.|  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G.
----------------+-----+------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+------
Well-to-do      |   81|    32|   75|   60|   61|    3|   50|    4|   43|    5|  0.9|  1.2
Living by their |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  own labor     |5,874| 1,254|5,799|1,177|5,800|1,224|5,455|1,154|5,300|1,090| 79.3| 68.7
Mendicants,     |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  vagabonds,    |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  prostitutes   |  923|   421|  956|  433|  809|  429|  726|  395|  697|  349| 11.5| 23.6
Unknown,        |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  disappeared,  |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  deceased      |  707|   133|  684|  138|  545|  102|  546|   84|  486|  101|  8.3|  6.5
----------------+-----+------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+------
    Total       |7,585| 1,840|7,514|1,808|7,215|1,758|6,777|1,637|6,527|1,545|100.0|100.0
================+=====+======+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+======


After 1882 the penitentiary statistics no longer mention the financial
condition of the parents, but their occupation. The results confirm
those that we have just cited.


France, 1890–1895. [691]

================+============+===========+===========+===========+===========+===========+============
                |            |           |           |           |           |           | 1890-1895
    Children    |    1890.   |   1891.   |   1892.   |   1893.   |   1894.   |   1895.   |  Average
   Belonging    |            |           |           |           |           |           | Percentage.
   to Parents   +-----+------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+------
                |Boys.|Girls.|  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G.
----------------+-----+------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+------
Property owners |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  or possessing |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  incomes       |   29|     2|   36|    1|   36|    1|   36|    2|   34|    2|   29|    0|  0.6|  0.1
Practicing      |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  liberal       |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  professions   |   31|     2|   28|    0|   31|    0|   30|    0|   42|   17|   46|    0|  0.8|  0.0
Agricultural    |1,000|   125|1,192|  105|1,199|  101|1,252|  138|  893|  102|  929|  115| 20.8| 10.0
Industrial      |1,252|   193|1,186|  179|1,059|  163|1,237|  240|1,304|  300|1,317|  304| 23.7| 20.1
Miscellaneous   |2,084|   572|1,937|  493|2,130|  413|1,866|  373|2,199|  311|2,120|  327| 39.8| 36.4
Mendicants,     |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  vagabonds,    |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  prostitutes   |  391|   201|  434|  224|  423|  287|  440|  294|  403|  286|  333|  300|  7.8| 23.3
Unknown or      |     |      |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  disappeared   |  364|    91|  342|  133|  347|  136|  374|  129|  325|   95|  263|  106|  6.5| 10.1
----------------+-----+------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+------
    Total       |5,151| 1,186|5,155|1,135|5,225|1,101|5,235|1,176|5,200|1,131|5,037|1,152|100.0|100.0
================+=====+======+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+======


These figures show clearly that it is only an insignificant number of
young criminals who come from the well-to-do classes. [692]

I have been able to procure only a few data from other countries; their
results, however, are identical with those for England and France.


Italy.

Of the 2,000 young criminals examined by Ferriani, there were 1,758, or
87.9%, coming from families where a profound poverty reigned, and only
148 (7.4%) from families that had never known poverty. [693]


Prussia.

77.8% of the children received in the correctional educational
institutions during the year 1901–02 came from very poor families.
[694]

It is then the poorest classes that furnish the greatest number of
juvenile criminals.



We come now to education among the proletariat. Here we meet first,
insufficiency of the pecuniary means which education requires; second,
bad housing conditions, which oblige the children to pass a great part
of the day in the street; third, the total absence of pedagogical
ideas; fourth, the absence during the greater part of the day of the
father of the family, and in many cases even of the mother. The number
of married women who work away from home is continually increasing. In
1882 there were in Germany, for example, 507,784 married working-women,
and by 1895 this figure had risen to 807,172—an increase of 299,388
(59%) in 13 years. In 1882 17.3% of the working-women were married; in
1895 21.5%. [695] There are no official figures but Braun [696]
calculates that in Germany there are 500,000 children under 14 years of
age, whose mothers are working-women. In Austria 44.6% of the
working-women are married, and in France 20.6%. [697] We have seen
above (pp. 409 ff.) that juvenile criminality is increasing. This is
explained in part by the increase in the labor of married women, from
which it results that an increasing number of children are brought up
without the proper care.

Among the working classes there is no question of education properly
speaking. We can consider the children as fortunate if their parents do
not set them a bad example, are not continually engaging in disputes,
and are not given to alcohol. It is plain that all this does not make
up a proper education; and yet how many children there are who do not
have even so much of an education as this! [698]

In the lower proletariat the situation is naturally worse. Not only is
there a total lack of care and surveillance, but children are even
brought up to crime.

Up to this point we have supposed the parents to be living. From the
present organization of society it follows that the condition of the
children of the poor becomes very bad as soon as the parents or even
one of them dies. Often private or public charity intervenes, but
generally the community does nothing for the orphan.

As a last consequence of the present system it must be noted that
children born of illegitimate unions are in a still more precarious
situation, since it is only the mother who has to protect them.

The community (in this case the state) concerns itself little with the
education of children; it makes education compulsory (at least in some
countries) and deprives parents of the charge of their children when
they neglect them too much (this again in some countries only).



Now we come to the facts. They prove that the surroundings in which
many children live are an important factor in the etiology of crime.
The figures at my disposal are not as numerous as I could wish, but
official statistics are not yet as full as is desirable for
sociological purposes.

In reading the statistics which follow we must not lose sight of the
fact that when it is stated that a certain percentage of children were
brought up in a bad environment, it does not follow that all the others
had a good education. The figures record only the very grave cases, as,
for example, where the parents have been convicted, or the children
entirely abandoned, etc. It is easier to prove, in making an
investigation into the condition of a family, that the children do not
receive a good education than it is to prove the contrary. Raux says
that 36% of the parents of the juvenile criminals whom he had examined
had a good reputation. The author adds, however, that this figure is
too high for the following reason: “For certain officials charged with
furnishing information on this point, every man who, without being
absolutely irreproachable, has not been complained against, is a person
of good character. So we have been made to add to the list of those of
good reputation certain families where the father, drunken, idle, and
unchaste, sets a very bad example to his son.” [699]

Some readers will see in what follows only a tiresome mass of
figures—quite wrongly, for those who know how to read the figures find
in them a language much more convincing and more shocking than that
which can be expressed in words.

Before beginning, the following remark must be made. We shall give, as
far as possible, the percentages of criminals born of illegitimate
unions together with the percentages of illegitimate births in general.
We shall see that with some exceptions, even so, the percentage for
criminals is much greater than that for the population in general.
However, to make the comparisons exact it is necessary to know the
percentage of illegitimate persons among the population of an age to
commit crime, and not among the newly born. This percentage is very
much less, because, first, the mortality among illegitimate children is
especially great, second, because a considerable number are
legitimated. In general the percentage of illegitimate persons among
the adult population is unknown. From researches by Neumann (“Die
jugendlichen Berliner unehelicher Herkunft”) and Spann (“Untersuchungen
über die uneheliche Bevölkerung in Frankfurt a/M.”), it appears that
3.6 times fewer illegitimate children in proportion, than legitimate,
reach the age of 20 years! [700]


Austria, 1883–1889. [701]

The following figures have to do with illegitimacy among the criminals
imprisoned in the years 1883 and 1884.


========+======================================+======================================
        |                1883.                 |                1884.
        +-------------+------------------------+-------------+------------------------
  Sex.  |    Total    |     Illegitimate.      |    Total    |     Illegitimate.
        |  Number of  +-----------+------------+  Number of  +-----------+------------
        |  Criminals  | Absolute  |   To 100   |  Criminals  | Absolute  |   To 100
        | Imprisoned. |  Number.  | Prisoners. | Imprisoned. |  Number.  | Prisoners.
--------+-------------+-----------+------------+-------------+-----------+------------
Men     |    4,988    |    595    |    11.9    |    4,512    |    626    |    13.8
Women   |      781    |    149    |    19.0    |      751    |    156    |    20.7
        +-------------+-----------+------------+-------------+-----------+------------
  Total |    5,769    |    746    |    12.9    |    5,263    |    782    |    14.8
        +-------------+-----------+------------+-------------+-----------+------------
        |                                Recidivists.
        +-------------+-----------+------------+-------------+-----------+------------
Men     |    2,719    |    392    |    14.4    |    2,353    |    366    |    15.5
Women   |      425    |     93    |    21.8    |      365    |     97    |    26.5
        +-------------+-----------+------------+-------------+-----------+------------
  Total |    3,144    |    485    |    15.4    |    2,718    |    463    |    17.0
========+=============+===========+============+=============+===========+============


For the years 1896 and 1899 I have the following data, bearing upon the
persons convicted of crime during those years. [702]


========+======================================+======================================
        |                1896.                 |                1897
        +-------------+------------------------+-------------+------------------------
  Sex.  |             |     Illegitimate.      |             |     Illegitimate.
        |    Total    +-----------+------------+    Total    +-----------+------------
        |  Convicted. | Absolute  |   To 100   |  Convicted. | Absolute  |   To 100
        |             |  Number.  | Convicted. |             |  Number.  | Convicted.
--------+-------------+-----------+------------+-------------+-----------+------------
Men     |   24,833    |   2,095   |     8.4    |    28,984   |   2,838   |     9.7
Women   |    4,065    |     621   |    15.2    |     4,679   |     642   |    13.7
--------+-------------+-----------+------------+-------------+-----------+------------
  Total |   28,898    |   2,716   |     9.3    |    33,663   |   3,480   |    10.3
========+=============+===========+============+=============+===========+============


In order to be able to make a comparison we must have the figures for
illegitimate births in the population in general. For Austria they are
very high: in the period 1876–1880 13.84% of the children born living
were illegitimate, and in the period 1887–1891 14.67%. [703] During the
period between 1883 and 1892 the general mortality of children under a
year old was 24.9% as against 30.3% for illegitimate children. [704]


Baden, 1887–1891. [705]

In 1887 correctional education (Zwangserziehung) was introduced into
the Grand Duchy of Baden. The family conditions of the children
received between 1887 and 1891 were as follows:


========+===========================================================
        |             To Each 100 Children there were:
Years.  +-----------------------------------------------------------
        | Illegitimate. | Full Orphans. | Motherless. | Fatherless.
--------+---------------+---------------+-------------+-------------
 1887   |     18.5      |      3.3      |     21.8    |    24.3
 1888   |     17.0      |      4.7      |     16.2    |    30.2
 1889   |     15.9      |      5.0      |     16.5    |    30.6
 1890   |     15.0      |      4.8      |     16.6    |    32.8
 1891   |     15.6      |      4.1      |     17.7    |    32.6
========+===============+===============+=============+=============



England and Scotland, 1887–1899.

With regard to the children received into the “Industrial Schools”
during the years 1887 to 1891 there are the following data: 5% were
illegitimate, while for the same period 4.52% of all children born
living were illegitimate. [706] Here we must take into consideration
the greater mortality among illegitimate children. There are no recent
data, but in England in 1875 this mortality was twice as great as that
of legitimate children, and in some countries it is four times as
great.

4% were full orphans; 34% half orphans, 20% being fatherless and 14%
motherless; 6% had been abandoned by their parents; and 2% were the
children of habitual criminals. 51%, therefore, were living under
unfavorable conditions. For the pupils of the “Reformatories” in the
same period this percentage was 53. [707]

The following figures indicate also the relative numbers for the two
sexes:


Industrial Schools, 1891. [708]

=============================================+===============+===============
                                             |     Boys.     |     Girls.
                                             +-------+-------+-------+-------
                                             |Number.|   %   |Number.|   %
---------------------------------------------+-------+-------+-------+-------
Illegitimate                                 |   233 |   6.8 |  108  |  11.6
Full orphans                                 |   115 |   3.4 |   65  |   6.7
Fatherless only                              |   532 |  15.6 |  181  |  18.6
Motherless only                              |   535 |  15.7 |  171  |  17.6
Abandoned by parents                         |   193 |   5.7 |   76  |   7.8
One or both parents perverted or criminal    |   118 |   3.5 |   53  |   5.5
Parents living and able to care for children | 1,681 |  49.3 |  317  |  32.7
---------------------------------------------+-------+-------+-------+-------
   Total                                     | 3,407 | 100.0 |  971  | 100.0
=============================================+=======+=======+=======+=======


It is interesting to note that with girls the influence of bad family
surroundings is worse than it is with boys, more than two thirds living
under abnormal circumstances.

However, confining ourselves to figures for the period 1887–1891, 49%
and 47% of the children in the two classes of institutions respectively
came from normal families. In what follows we see what their education
was; different competent witnesses before the “Royal Commission on
Reformatory and Industrial Schools” affirmed that the environment from
which these children came was very unfavorable. The most important
testimony was that of Mr. Macdonald, one of the officers who receive
the contributions of the parents to the support of their children in
the “Industrial Schools.” According to him only 6% of the children came
from homes favorable to their moral education. In Manchester 68% of the
parents of children in the industrial schools had a bad reputation;
14.7% were of doubtful character; and only 17% conducted themselves
well. [709]

Of 1,209 juvenile delinquents in the English prisons (1898–99) 90
(7.4%) had had no education; 512 (42.3%) had had very little; 496 (41%)
a fair education; and of 111 (9.1%) only could it be said that their
education was good. 211 (17.4%) were without father or mother; 183
(15.1%) had bad homes; 198 (16.3%) had none at all; and 30 (2.4%) slept
in night-lodgings. [710]

If the environment in which the young criminals have lived is the cause
of their fall, a considerable portion of them ought to return to the
right way as a result of the education given in the schools in
question. If this is not the case with all, this proves nothing against
the influence of environment, for the impressions received by the child
in the surroundings in which he has lived before his conviction are too
strong to be effaced by a comparatively brief stay in an educational
institution (even if these reform-schools were perfect). Finally, after
they are set at liberty environment may once more contribute to
recidivism. The following figures show the facts in the case: [711]


======+================================================================================
      |                        To Each 100 Released there were:
      +---------------------------------------++---------------------------------------
Years.|                 Boys.                 ||                 Girls.
      +---------------------------------------++---------------------------------------
      |  Good  |Doubtful|Recidivists.|Conduct ||  Good  |Doubtful|Recidivists.|Conduct
      |Conduct.|Conduct.|            |Unknown.||Conduct.|Conduct.|            |Unknown.
------+--------+--------+------------+--------++--------+--------+------------+--------
                                a. Reformatory Schools.
------+--------+--------+------------+--------++--------+--------+------------+--------
1882  |  76    |   3    |     14     |   7    ||   72   |    7   |      6     |   15
1883  |  76    |   3    |     14     |   7    ||   69   |    9   |      8     |   14
1884  |  78    |   2    |     14     |   6    ||   70   |    9   |      6     |   15
1885  |  79    |   2    |     14     |   5    ||   72   |    9   |      6     |   13
1886  |  77    |   3    |     14     |   6    ||   73   |   11   |      5     |   11
1887  |  78    |   2    |     14     |   6    ||   75   |   10   |      5     |   10
1888  |  76    |   1    |     17     |   6    ||   75   |    9   |      6     |   10
1889  |  74    |   2    |     18     |   6    ||   76   |    9   |      6     |    9
1890  |  78    |   2    |     14     |   6    ||   73   |   10   |      7     |   10
1891  |  78    |   2    |     14     |   6    ||   76   |    8   |      5     |   11
------+--------+--------+------------+--------++--------+--------+------------+--------
                                 b. Industrial Schools.
------+--------+--------+------------+--------++--------+--------+------------+--------
1882  |  81    |   4    |      5     |   10   ||   79   |    7   |      1     |   13
1883  |  80    |   4    |      5     |   11   ||   79   |    7   |      2     |   12
1884  |  81    |   4    |      5     |   10   ||   80   |    7   |      2     |   11
1885  |  81    |   3    |      5     |   11   ||   81   |    7   |      2     |   10
1886  |  82.5  |   3    |    4.5     |   10   ||   83   |    8   |      1     |    8
1887  |  83.3  |   3    |      5     |    9   ||   84   |    7   |      1     |    8
1888  |  83    |   3    |      5     |    9   ||   81   |    8   |      1     |   10
1889  |  83    |   3    |      5     |    9   ||   82   |    8   |      1     |    9
1890  |  84    |   2    |      5     |    9   ||   83   |    7   |      1     |    8
1891  |  85.5  |   2    |    4.5     |    8   ||   84   |    7   |      1     |    8
======+========+========+============+========++========+========+============+========


The percentage of those who conduct themselves well is considerable,
therefore, and indicates how great the influence of an unfavorable
environment upon these children has been. [712]


France, 1890–1895. [713]

The following important data concern the children in the
“établissements d’éducation correctionnelle”:


=======================+===========+===========+===========+===========+===========+===========+=============
                       |           |           |           |           |           |           |  1890-1895
    Condition as to    |   1890.   |   1891.   |   1892.   |   1893.   |   1894.   |   1895.   |   Average
       Family.         |           |           |           |           |           |           | Percentage.
                       +-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-------
                       |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G. |  B. |  G.
-----------------------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-------
Illegitimate           |  693|  236|  669|  238|  654|  277|  635|  295|  589|  289|  535|  395| 2.1 | 25.1
Half orphans           |1,676|  432|1,641|  419|1,753|  418|1,634|  410|1,690|  428|1,492|  452| 1.7 | 37.1
Full orphans           |  384|  152|  310|  172|  323|  203|  333|  212|  324|  236|  271|  225| 6.2 | 17.4
Parents:               |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  Convicted one or     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
    more times         |  977|  412|  875|  443|  864|  570|  922|  566|  853|  481|  801|  488| 7.0 | 43.0
Mendicants, vagabonds, |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |     |
  or prostitutes       |  391|  201|  434|  224|  423|  287|  444|  294|  403|  286|  333|  300| 7.8 | 43.0
Unknown or disappeared |  364|   91|  342|  135|  347|  136|  374|  129|  325|   95|  263|  106| 6.5 | 10.0
Total of juvenile      +-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+     |
  delinquents          |5,151|1,186|5,155|1,135|5,225|1,101|5,235|1,176|5,200|1,131|5,037|1,152|     |
=======================+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+=======


Out of 100 children born living 8.41 were illegitimate (1887–1891),
[714] while the mortality in the first year of life rose to 28.8% of
the illegitimate children, and only to 16.7% of the legitimate. [715]

The figures given above constitute a crushing accusation against
present conditions. If we suppose that the number of persons born of
illegitimate unions who have attained the age at which it is physically
possible to commit a crime are 6% of the whole population (a figure
which is certainly rather too low than too high), it follows that a
natural son runs twice as much danger of becoming a criminal as he
would if legitimate, and that this danger is even four times as great
in the case of a natural daughter. The other data are striking,
especially those which deal with girls. There were 54% who were orphans
or half-orphans; 43% had criminal parents; 33% had parents who were
vagabonds or prostitutes, or who had deserted their children! [716]

As the official statistics furnish no other data, we will pass on to
some of those given by private individuals. In the work already more
than once quoted, Raux gives the following table, based upon careful
researches and dealing with 385 juvenile prisoners received in the
“Quartier correctionnel” at Lyons, to which the juvenile delinquents
guilty of grave crimes are sent: [717]


=====================================================================
                           Juvenile Prisoners.
-------------------------------------------------+-----------+-------
Under normal surveillance                        |  51    51 |  13%
 ,,   weak       ,,                              |  90}      |
 ,,   impotent   ,,                              |  44}  158 |  41%
 ,,   brutal     ,,                              |  24}      |
Morally abandoned                                |  98 } 145 |  38%
Completely  ,,                                   |  47 }     |
Excited to crime by the example of parents       |  15}   31 |
Having committed crime under the instigation     |  16}      |   8%
  and with the complicity of parents             |           |
                                                 +-----------+-------
      Total                                      | 385   385 | 100%
=================================================+===========+=======


Only 13% among them enjoyed a normal education (and who could say how
far it was really good?), while 87% had an education insufficient or
bad. The author arrives at the following conclusion: “... the
population of the ‘quartier correctionnel’ of Lyons, more unfortunate
than guilty, has been recruited for more than 16 years from families
the majority of which bore within themselves, by reason of the vices of
their constitution, the principle of disintegration; whose morality was
detestable or very doubtful, and whose means of subsistence were
insufficient or totally lacking.

“It is to these different causes that the young delinquents owe first
their deplorable antecedents, then their recklessness at the moment of
the crime, their perversity, their corruption, and finally, their
arrest.” [718]

The opinion of M. Grosmolard, of great value because of the competence
of the author, who has been attached to the penal institutions of
Lyons, is entirely in accord with what has just been quoted. After
having spoken of the strong influence of poverty upon juvenile
criminality, Grosmolard continues thus: “Besides material poverty, and
as an auxiliary to this factor, we find the moral poverty of the home,
manifested by the disorganization of the family. Whether it is due to
the misconduct of the father or of the mother, or of both, the
disruption, whether private through separation of the couple, or
officialized by divorce, has no less deplorable consequences for the
children. There is always the depressing spectacle of domestic
disputes, the abandonment of the home, the weakening of parental
discipline.” [719]

Concerning 400 children in a parental school in Paris we have the
following figures: [720]


  There were:
    Natural children                                          11.25%
    Half orphans                                              35.00%
    Full orphans                                              10.00%
    Children whose parents had disappeared or been convicted  13.25%
    Whose parents had separated or been divorced              16.25%
    Coming from a normal family                               14.25%
                                                             -------
                                                             100.00%


These results agree, therefore, with those of the official statistics
and of Raux. The normal families were those which did not present any
of the external marks of demoralization, and it is more than probable
that their “morality”, in many cases was only apparent.

Out of 600 families from which juvenile criminals had issued, studied
by Dr. L. Albanel, 303 (50.5%) had been disorganized by death, divorce,
desertion, etc. In 268 (44.6%) families the fathers and mothers worked
away from home and the children were entirely neglected; 291 children
(48.5%) were confided to persons outside of the family; and 41 (6.8%)
were brought up by their grandparents, etc. [721]

Finally, there is the following fact about the children undergoing
correction in Paris during the period 1874–1878: nearly 68% of them
received visits from no one at all, not even from their parents. What
complete misery! Out of 100 children 68 in whom no one was interested,
not even when they were in prison. [722]

The results obtained by correctional education (probably no more
perfect in France than elsewhere) prove the correctness of what has
been advanced. If the thesis that the environment is the cause of the
criminality of minors is true, the conduct of most of those set free
ought to be good. Here are the results obtained in the “Quartier
correctionnel” of Lyons: [723]


        101 discharged prisoners led a good life, i.e.   60%
         20 conducted themselves passably, i.e.          12%
         24 were put down as bad, i.e.                   14%
         24 disappeared (died, etc.), i.e.               14%
        ---                                             ----
        169 discharged prisoners                        100%


As I have already remarked, the fact that all do not lead good lives
proves nothing against the theory of environment, for it is quite
possible that earlier evil influences have not been eliminated in a
comparatively short detention. To prove how strong an influence the
environment exercises anew upon discharged prisoners, let us look at
the following figures, which also have to do with the pupils of the
Lyons “Quartier correctionnel”: [724]


=======================================+===========+==============
   Discharged Inmates whose Parents:   | Reformed. | Recidivists.
---------------------------------------+-----------+--------------
Had a good reputation                  |    83%    |      5%
 ,,   doubtful  ,,                     |    52%    |     16%
 ,,   bad       ,,                     |    37%    |     16%
 ,, been convicted                     |    50%    |     29%
=======================================+===========+==============


Ireland, 1891.

Among the children subjected to correctional education in 1891 there
were: 1.2% of illegitimate birth; 8.1% who had lost their parents;
16.2% without father; 19.3% without mother; and 0.6% who had been
abandoned or whose parents were unknown. [725] 43.6%, then, were
entirely or partially orphaned. These figures have no great value since
they relate to so small a number (160).


Italy, 1885–1889.

With regard to illegitimacy among criminals I have data for the years
1885, 1886, and 1889. In these years there were among those convicted
at the assizes 2.35%, 2.25%, and 2.21% respectively, of illegitimate
birth. [726] The number of natural children in general in the years
1872–1889 was about 7%; [727] the mortality among children in general
in the first year was 19%, and that among the illegitimate children 26%
(these percentages are the averages for the years 1884–1893). [728]
Italy is an exception, therefore to the rule, good everywhere else,
that a larger proportion of criminals than of the general population
are illegitimate.

In his “Entartete Mütter”, Ferriani says that more than 25% of the 806
juvenile criminals examined by him had become such because of the
depravity of their families. [729] In his “Minderjährige Verbrecher” he
gives the following results from an examination of 2,000 juvenile
criminals: 207 (10.3%) came from families of which one or more members
had been convicted; 53 (2.6%) from families entirely demoralized; 701
(35.0%) from families of bad reputation; and 169 (8.4%) from families
with a doubtful reputation—all together 56.3%; while 896 (44.8%) had
been corrupted by bad examples. [730]

Dr. A. Marro gives the following figures: [731] of 507 criminals
examined by him there were:


         19 ( 3.6%)   whose father or mother was a criminal
         98 (13.4%)   who had a criminal brother or sister
        115 (22.6%)   whose father was immoral or violent
         56 (11.0%)    ,,   mother ,,    ,,    ,,   ,,
        209 (41.0%)    ,,   father was alcoholic
         26 ( 5.1%)    ,,   mother ,, ,,
        120 (24.1%)   had lost their father before the age of 16
         90 (18.1%)   ,,   ,,   ,,   mother   ,,   ,,  ,,  ,, ,,
     and 36 (7.0%)    were orphans before the age of 16.



Netherlands, 1896–1901.

The data concerning the Netherlands are limited to the following: [732]


Percentage of Persons of Illegitimate Birth.

=======+========================++========================
       |         Convicts.      ||     Recidivists.
Years. +------+--------+--------++------+--------+--------
       | Men. | Women. | Total. || Men. | Women. | Total.
-------+------+--------+--------++------+--------+--------
 1896  | 1.5  |  3.4   |  1.7   ||  2.2 |  6.8   |  2.4
 1897  | 1.3  |  2.3   |  1.6   ||  1.9 |  3.5   |  2.0
 1898  | 1.3  |  1.9   |  1.3   ||  1.6 |  1.6   |  1.6
 1899  | 1.5  |  2.2   |  1.6   ||  2.0 |  2.2   |  2.2
 1900  | 1.8  |  2.0   |  2.0   ||  1.9 |  1.4   |  1.9
 1901  | 1.3  |  1.9   |  1.9   ||  1.5 |  2.8   |  1.6
=======+======+========+========++======+========+========


In the period 1887–1891 the number of illegitimate children to 100 born
living was 3.2 [733]; the mortality among illegitimate children during
their first year rose to 26.6% as against 17.5% among children in
general (1885–1893). [734] It is not possible to calculate for the
population in general the number of individuals born of illegitimate
unions and arrived at the age at which they are capable of committing
crime, but it is certain that the mortality is greater among
illegitimate children at each age than among legitimate children, and
that the number of children legitimated is very considerable. The
percentage of illegitimates to the whole population, then, is much
smaller than 3.2. It is consequently probable that in Holland also
illegitimate children are more likely to become criminals than
legitimate children.

As to juvenile criminals there are the following figures to be gathered
from the criminal statistics for the years from 1899 to 1901:


======+===================================================================
      |                   To 100 of Each Category.
      +---------------------------------+---------------------------------
Years.|             Boys.               |             Girls.
      +----------+---------+------------+----------+---------+------------
      |  Illeg.  |  Orph.  | Half-Orph. |  Illeg.  |  Orph.  | Half-Orph.
------+----------+---------+------------+----------+---------+------------
 1899 |   0.5    |   0.8   |    18.8    |   4.3    |   2.2   |    27.2
 1900 |   3.5    |   0.1   |    18.3    |   3.0    |   1.5   |    29.6
 1901 |   2.5    |   0.8   |    15.0    |   1.5    |   1.5   |    19.6
======+==========+=========+============+==========+=========+============



New York (State), 1875–1897.

Dugdale gives the following figures in “The Jukes.” They deal with 233
criminals imprisoned in New York in 1875. 40.77% were orphans; 46.78%
had been neglected in their youth; 17.16% were descended from criminal
families, and 42.49% from intemperate families. [735]

The following very interesting figures are taken from the annual
reports of the Elmira Reformatory.


=====+============================================================================
     |                        To Each 100 Prisoners.
     +------------------+------------------------------+-------------------------
     |Parents Alcoholic.|Character of Home Environment.| Length of Stay at Home.
     +------------------+----------+---------+---------+--------------------------
Year.|        |         |          |         |         |       Left Home.
     |Plainly.|Probably.|Positively|  Fair.  |  Good.  +------+-------+-----------
     |        |         |   Bad.   |         |         |Before|Between|Soon after
     |        |         |          |         |         |  10. | 10 and|the Age of
     |        |         |          |         |         |      |  14.  |   14.
-----+--------+---------+----------+---------+---------+------+-------+-----------
1881 |  33.8  |  18.0   |   47.7   |   44.0  |    8.3  |  5.4 |  7.6  |   22.5
1882 |  35.1  |  16.0   |   48.1   |   41.1  |   10.8  |  5.0 |  7.3  |   22.7
1883 |  35.6  |  14.1   |   49.3   |   39.1  |   11.6  |  5.2 |  7.0  |   23.6
1884 |  35.9  |  13.3   |   50.0   |   39.2  |   10.8  |  4.4 |  6.8  |   25.0
1885 |  36.4  |  12.8   |   50.6   |   38.9  |   10.5  |  4.9 |  6.8  |   25.5
1886 |  37.5  |  12.0   |   52.4   |   37.4  |   10.2  |  4.6 |  6.4  |   25.5
1888 |  38.4  |  10.9   |   52.1   |   38.9  |    9.0  |  5.2 |  6.3  |   29.5
1889 |  38.7  |  11.1   |   51.8   |   39.9  |    8.3  |  5.2 |  6.2  |   30.8
1890 |  38.4  |  11.4   |   52.0   |   40.4  |    7.6  |  4.7 |  5.8  |   29.5
1891 |  38.4  |  13.0   |   52.6   |   39.8  |    7.6  |  4.5 |  5.9  |   30.7
1892 |  38.3  |  13.1   |   54.1   |   38.3  |    7.6  |  4.1 |  5.8  |   32.0
1893 |  37.8  |  12.7   |   50.3   |   40.0  |    9.7  |  3.8 |  6.1  |   32.6
1894 |  37.5  |  12.1   |   49.0   |   40.6  |   10.4  |  3.8 |  6.1  |   31.8
1896 |  37.5  |  11.3   |   47.0   |   41.3  |   11.7  |  3.6 |  6.7  |   33.0
1897 |  37.6  |  51.7?  |   46.7   |   41.1  |   12.2  |  3.7 |  6.3  |   34.2
=====+========+=========+==========+=========+=========+======+=======+===========


In round numbers then: 50% of the criminals come from a corrupt
environment, and only 10% from a good environment; 40% had left home
before the age of 15; and further, 40 to 45% had alcoholic parents.
[736]


Norway, 1897–1900. [737]

The following figures deal with illegitimacy of birth among the
prisoners in Norway.


==========+==================================================
          |  Persons of Illegitimate Birth to 100 Prisoners
  Years.  |                of Each Category.
          +----------------+----------------+----------------
          |      Men.      |     Women.     |     Total.
----------+----------------+----------------+----------------
1897-1898 |      12.7      |      14.7      |     13.0
1898-1899 |      11.8      |      17.2      |     12.6
1899-1900 |       --       |       --       |     12.0
==========+================+================+================


During the years 1887–1891, out of 100 living births 7.33 were
illegitimate, [738] while the mortality of natural children in the
first year was 15.3% and that of children in general 9.5%. [739]
Persons of illegitimate birth formed a much greater proportion of the
prisoners than of the population in general.


Prussia, 1891–1900. [740]

===========================================================
  To 100 Prisoners Born of Illegitimate Unions there were:
-----------------+-----------------+-----------------------
  In Houses of   | In Correctional |  In Institutions for
   Detention.    |    Prisons.     |Correctional Education.
  (1891-1900).   |  (1896-1900).   |     (1895-1900).
--------+--------+--------+--------+-----------+-----------
  Men.  | Women. |  Men.  | Women. |    Men.   |   Women.
--------+--------+--------+--------+-----------+-----------
   8.5  |  10.2  |   8.3  |  12.5  |    11.6   |    15.1
========+========+========+========+===========+===========


In the years 1887–1891 there were 7.81 illegitimate children out of
each 100 living births; 35.7% of the illegitimate children died in the
first year as against 20.8% of children in general (1884–1893). [741]
In Prussia also, then, the influence of illegitimacy upon criminality
is very marked.

The following table gives the figures for 18,049 recidivists in
Prussian houses of detention in the years 1894–1897. [742]


====================================================================
                                              |Absolute|
                                              |Numbers.|     %
----------------------------------------------|--------|------------
Of illegitimate birth                         |  2,218 |        11.2
                                              |        |
Had lost father before age of 14              |  3,230 | 17.8 }
 ,,  ,,  mother   ,,    ,, ,, ,,              |  2,116 | 11.7 } 35.1
 ,,  ,,  both     ,,    ,, ,, ,,              |  1,027 |  5.6 }
                                              |        |
 ,,  ,,  father after   ,, ,, ,, but before 18|  1,183 |  6.5 }
 ,,  ,,  mother after the age of 14 but       |        |      }
           before 18                          |    880 |  4.8 } 12.2
 ,,  ,,  both after the age of 14 but before  |        |      }
           before 18                          |    167 |  0.9 }
 ,, committed their first crime before the    |        |
           age of 14                          |  1,150 |  6.3 }
 ,, committed their first crime between the   |        |      } 33.6
           ages of 14 and 18                  |  4,936 | 27.3 }
====================================================================


Consequently 47.3% had lost one or both parents before reaching the age
of 18; 11.2% were of illegitimate birth—a total, therefore, of 58.5%
brought up under abnormal home surroundings. And what was the
environment under which the other 41.5% had lived? The table gives no
answer to this question, but we may imagine it on the basis of the
figures given above.


Switzerland, 1892–1896.

Among the 14,612 persons confined in the Swiss prisons during the years
1892–1896 there were 1,359 of illegitimate birth—1,044 men (8.5%) and
315 women (13.9%). [743] In the period 1871–1890 there were only 5
illegitimate births to the 100, while the mortality during the first
year was 24.0 to the 100 natural children as against 16.4 to the 100
children in general. [744] The influence of illegitimate birth upon
criminality, therefore, is very great in Switzerland; an illegitimate
child is at least three times as likely to become a criminal as a
legitimate child.

As regards the education of criminals, 22% of the women and 17% of the
men had been brought up by persons outside of the family. The following
table bears upon the others, i.e. those who were brought up at home:
[745]


============+=======================================
            |       Number of Prisoners.
            +------------+------------+------------
 Education. |    Men.    |  Women.    |Illegitimate.
            +------------+----------- +-------------
            | Total.  %  | Total.  %  |      %
------------+------------+------------+-------------
Good        | 4,696   57 |   586   44 |     37.6
Defective   | 3,096   37 |   619   46 |     47.6
Bad         |   481    6 |   141   10 |     14.8
------------+------------+------------+-------------
  Total     | 8,273  100 | 1,346  100 |    100.0
============+============+============+=============


These figures show that the education of a very great number of
criminals was very insufficient, and especially so in the case of
illegitimate children.

The following table, dealing with the canton of Berne, gives still
further details. [746]


============================+========================================================
                            |To 100 Convicts of Each Category the Education had been:
  Categories of Convicts.   +-------------+--------------+-------------+-------------
                            |    Good.    |  Defective.  |    Bad.     |  Not known.
----------------------------+-------------+--------------+-------------+-------------
Legitimate                  |    33.0     |     54.0     |    11.0     |     2.0
Illegitimate                |     8.4     |     63.4     |    25.3     |     2.8
Brought up at home          |    38.0     |     11.0     |    49.0     |     2.0
  ,,    ,, in another family|     9.0     |     17.0     |    73.0     |     1.0
  ,,    ,, ,, an institution|    16.0     |     19.0     |    53.0     |    13.0
============================+=============+==============+=============+=============


The figures concerning the bad education of illegitimate persons are
very striking, as well as those brought up in families other than their
own; of the latter only 9% had received a good education even as that
term is used in the table.


Wurtemberg, 1877–1888.

The following figures have to do with 3,181 criminals in prison in
Wurtemberg during the years mentioned:

Out of 100 in each group there were the following number of
illegitimate births:


                All prisoners                27.0
                Habitual criminals           30.6
                Occasional criminals         17.4
                Thieves                      32.4
                Swindlers                    23.1
                Sexual criminals             21.0
                Perjurers                    13.0
                Incendiaries                 12.9


Between 1876 and 1885 there were 8.76% of illegitimate births in the
general population; and while the general mortality of children in
their first year was 26.1% (1884–1893) that of illegitimate children
was 32%. [747] The influence of illegitimacy is very strong here,
therefore.

To 100 persons of each category the following were brought up outside
of their own family:


                Prisoners in general         16.0
                Habitual criminals           19.3
                Occasional criminals          7.6
                Thieves                      20.9
                Incendiaries                 11.0
                Swindlers                    10.8
                Sexual criminals              9.4
                Perjurers                     6.0


To 100 persons of each category there were the following one or both of
whose parents had led an immoral or criminal life:


                Prisoners in general         43.7
                Sexual criminals             51.7
                Thieves                      47.3
                Swindlers                    34.8
                Incendiaries                 31.0
                Perjurers                    23.0


Finally it must be mentioned that 16.2% of 1,714 in the detention
prison had alcoholic parents.



We are now at the end of our statistical data and also of our
observations upon the environment in which criminals are brought up;
for it seems to me superfluous to make further comments: the great
influence of environment is indubitable.

Tomel and Rollet close their work “Enfants en prison” with these words,
which I make my own, and which are as applicable to adult as to
juvenile criminals: “Has society done everything that it ought to spare
children the prison? We believe that with ourselves [the reader] will
answer, ‘No!’ Each child to whom we refuse protection will become a
delinquent. It is a wolf that we are preparing for the sheep-fold. If
tomorrow he makes his fellows pay his own arrears of injustice, if he
steals, if he kills, he will not say, ‘I commit a crime’; he will say,
‘I make reprisals.’” [748]



f. Prostitution. Prostitution has a special importance for the etiology
of sexual offenses and of procuration. However, it is not with this
that we are concerned at present, but with the correlation between
prostitution and criminality in general, in the sense, that is, that
prostitution has a demoralizing effect upon the women who practice it
and upon the men who have intercourse with them.

Let us begin with the effect upon the prostitutes themselves. And as
with all observations upon the relation between certain social
phenomena and criminality, these must be preceded by statistical data.

How large a quota do prostitutes contribute to crime? This is a hard
question to answer, because, first, most criminal statistics make no
mention of the occupation of prostitute; second, when the statistics do
mention prostitution they do not give the real truth, since the facts
will often be concealed by the woman interested; third, the extent of
prostitution is almost unknown, so that it is impossible to make the
necessary calculations.

The following figures give us some information on the subject.


Austria, 1896–1898.

It is to the study of Dr. A. Baumgarten “Die Beziehungen der
Prostitution zum Verbrechen”, that I owe the following figures (which,
I believe, bear wholly upon Vienna). In the years 1896–98 there were 34
annually convicted out of a total of 2,400 prostitutes, or 1.4%, not
counting those who were punished for infraction of the regulations
covering prostitution. [749] The author thinks this degree of
criminality very small. I venture to be of a different opinion. If we
note that criminal statistics, those of Germany, for example, show that
there are annually only 0.3 women over 12 years of age convicted to the
100, we shall see that the part that prostitutes take in crime must be
called more than a small one.


England, 1836–1900.

The English penitentiary statistics show whether the female prisoners
are prostitutes or not. As we have seen above (p. 499) the percentage
of prostitutes rose in the period between 1894–1900 to 15% of the
total. The figures bearing upon earlier years, however, show a much
higher percentage; in the years 1836–1854 25.2% of the women convicted
(in London) were prostitutes [750]; in the years 1858–1862 prostitutes
made up 24.7% of the women arrested. [751]

However, when we examine these exceptionally high figures, we must not
forget that, according to the “Vagrant Act”, the fact of being a
prostitute itself is a misdemeanor; a part of these women, therefore,
were convicted for this and not for having committed some other
offense. The following figure however, where this circumstance is
excluded, also shows a great criminality upon the part of prostitutes,
and gains added weight from the fact that many persons would not care
to make complaint for fear of scandal: to each 100 persons of both
sexes convicted in London between 1843 and 1854 of “theft from the
person”, there were 36.0 prostitutes. [752]


France, 1890–1895.

In citing the figures upon the occupations of the prisoners (1890–1895)
we showed (p. 501) that about 5% were prostitutes. Compared with that
given in the corresponding statistics for England this percentage is
small. It must, however, be taken into consideration that a great
number of occasional prostitutes figure in the penitentiary statistics
under the head of another occupation.


Germany, 1885.

For this country I have been able to find only the following. Among the
2,900 women imprisoned in the 16 great German prisons there were found
in 1885 500 (17.2%) who had already been punished for professional
prostitution. [753] Although there are no positive data upon the extent
of prostitution, it is nevertheless certain that much less than 17.2%
of women in general are prostitutes. The figure cited shows that
prostitutes take a relatively large part in crime.


Italy, 1891–1895.

1,949 (1.5%) out of 126,717 women convicted in the years 1891–1895 were
prostitutes. [754] Here also it must be taken into account that this
number is made up only of prostitutes by occupation, and that those who
follow it as an auxiliary calling are grouped under other occupations.
Also, L. Ferriani, in his “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, concludes that of
the 460 young female criminals studied by him, 243 (52.8%) were
prostitutes. [755]

What data I have been able to secure do not prove—but render
exceedingly probable—the assertion that prostitutes show a high degree
of criminality. In my opinion this phenomenon is to be explained as
follows.

First. From its nature the profession opens a vast field for committing
economic offenses.

Second. Prostitution has a very demoralizing effect upon those that
practice it. Those who have not sufficiently taken account of the real
causes of prostitution consider this a confusing of cause and effect,
and believe that it is the demoralization which causes prostitution. In
reasoning thus they forget that part of the prostitutes are forced by
poverty to take up this profession, and that in such cases there is no
need of supposing demoralization. Whatever may be the case with regard
to the rest, the profession would increase the demoralization already
existing.

All the authors who have taken up the question are agreed that this is
really the case. It is impossible to imagine a more degrading situation
than that of a prostitute. A woman who is continually forced to act in
opposition to her feelings, who is obliged to enter into intimate
relations with the first comer however abject he may be, who has become
unaccustomed to all work, and who is despised, inevitably loses all
respect for herself and falls lower and lower. [756]

A second bond of connection between criminality and prostitution is
that it makes possible a category of persons who constitute a permanent
danger to society, namely the “protectors.” The unregistered
prostitutes need a man who will look after them, and to whom they may
attach themselves in their forlorn condition. In exchange for this
protection the prostitute gives up a large part of her earnings. In
examining the biographies of great criminals we see that a large number
of them have belonged to this category. It is evident that only
demoralized persons can lead such a life, but that this life in its
turn increases their demoralization. [757]

In the third place, prostitution has a demoralizing effect upon the men
who come into contact with the prostitutes. We cannot lay it to chance
that it is shown in many criminal procedures that guilty persons have
had relations with the world of prostitution. This world includes only
a relatively small number of persons; but the men who frequent it are
numerous, and the demoralization which ensues is prejudicial to
society. This demoralization is easily explained, as Dr. Lux shows in
his “Sozialpolitisches Handbuch”, in these words: “The venality of the
delights of love debases the pleasure; the man learns to see in woman
only a means of satisfying his lust; all higher regard for woman is
lost to him, his thoughts become frivolous and cynical, his character
continually more vulgar. Whoever has an opportunity to come to know the
young men of the large cities, must, unless he is already tainted with
their opinions himself, be shocked at the brutality and coarseness of
their thought and speech. The whole conversational material of our
gilded youth consists of filth and obscenities; they boast of things
that a decent man would blush to be charged with. The young man is
demoralized and depraved by association with prostitutes, of whose
standard of morality he must beware lest he stifle in it every nobler
feeling.” [758]



g. Alcoholism. Here we have to take up but a single one of the ways in
which alcoholism is connected with criminality. For while acute
alcohol-poisoning enters into the etiology of sexual offenses and those
committed in revenge, etc., it has almost no relation to the largest of
the classes, namely economic crimes. Acute alcoholism, therefore, has
no place among our general observations. With chronic alcoholism it is
otherwise; for the man who is subject to this undergoes a general
demoralization by which he is predisposed to crime even when he is not
drunk. The manner in which this demoralization takes place is not a
question within the province of sociology; it is sufficient for us that
this consequence of chronic alcoholism is universally recognized. [759]

To show the influence of chronic alcoholism upon criminality we can use
only the direct statistical method; that is to say, we must find the
number of chronic alcoholics among criminals, and then place beside
this the number among the non-criminal population, in order that we may
compare them. If the latter figures are lacking, a comparison is
impossible. However, as we shall see, the percentage of chronic
alcoholics is so great among the criminals, that we can affirm that
among the non-criminals the percentage is very small. Consequently the
influence of chronic alcoholism, whether greater or less, is
indubitably proved. Here are the statistics which we have at our
disposal.


Belgium, 1874–1900.

M. Masoin tells us that out of 2,588 convicts (sentenced for 5 years at
least) who entered the central institution at Louvain between 1874 and
1895, there were 1,157 (44.7%) addicted to drunkenness. Out of 216
sentenced to hard labor for life there were 118 (54.6%), and out of 202
sentenced to death 121 (60%). [760]

In the prison of Mons Dr. Morel shows that out of 325 recidivists 181
(53.9%) were given to alcoholic excesses. [761]

It appears from the “Statistique Judiciaire de la Belgique” of 1900,
that in 1898, out of 19,169 recidivists (men) there were 5,976 (31.2%)
who had already been convicted of breaking the law against drunkenness,
and out of 22,904 non-recidivists (men) 1,984 (8.7%). Among the women
the figures were 8% (recidivists) and 1.1% (non-recidivists). [762]


Denmark, 1871–1897.

Out of 2,982 prisoners received between 1871 and 1880 in the prison at
Vridslöselille, 797 (27%) were drunkards. The penitentiary statistics
show us that during the years 1891–1897, among the non-recidivists
16.3% of the men were drunkards, and 4.6% of the women. [763]


England and Wales, 1858–1897.

The following figures are taken from the police statistics [764]:


=======+===========+================================================
       |           |   Of whom there were Habitual Drinkers:[765]
       |           +---------------+---------------+----------------
       |Number of  |       Men.    |       Women.  |       Total.
Years. | Persons   +---------+-----+---------+-----+----------+-----
       |Prosecuted.| Absolute|     | Absolute|     | Absolute |
       |           | Number. |  %  | Number. |  %  | Number.  |  %
-------+-----------+---------+-----+---------+-----+----------+-----
1858   |  434,492  |  13,553 | 3.7 |   4,130 | 4.5 |  17,683  | 4.1
1859   |  419,929  |  18,440 | 5.6 |   5,303 | 5.9 |  23,743  | 5.7
1860   |  409,780  |  19,471 | 6.0 |   5,210 | 6.0 |  24,681  | 6.0
1861   |  421,891  |  19,475 | 5.8 |   4,960 | 5.7 |  24,425  | 5.8
1862   |  438,228  |  20,830 | 6.0 |   5,209 | 5.8 |  26,039  | 5.9
1894   |  689,761  |  19,224 | 3.3 |   6,557 | 5.3 |  25,781  | 3.6
1895   |  687,075  |  16,268 | 2.8 |   5,695 | 4.7 |  21,963  | 3.1
1896   |  728,374  |  17,308 | 2.8 |   6,015 | 4.7 |  23,323  | 3.2
1897   |  757,485  |  17,012 | 2.7 |   6,084 | 4.6 |  23,096  | 3.0
=======+===========+=========+=====+=========+=====+==========+=====


These figures have no great value; they represent the number of
habitual drinkers to be less than it really is. The statistics cited
divide all persons prosecuted into eight groups (habitual criminals,
prostitutes, vagrants, etc.) and under the heading of habitual drinkers
only those alcoholics figure who are not included under other headings.
If a vagrant, for example, is also a habitual drinker, he will be
counted among the vagrants and not among the habitual drinkers; hence
this latter group is much larger than the figures would indicate. [766]


France.

At the penitentiary Congress in Brussels (1900), M. V. Marambat, well
known for his studies on the relation between criminality and
alcoholism, gave the following figures: [767]


=======================================+=========+==========+======
     Crimes and Misdemeanors.          |Number of|Number of |
                                       |Convicts.|Drunkards.|   %
-------------------------------------- +---------+----------+------
Murder, assault, and other crimes of   |         |          |
  violence                             |    787  |    649   | 82.4
Malicious mischief, etc.               |    433  |    344   | 79.4
Theft and other economic offenses      |  3,359  |  2,156   | 64.2
Arson                                  |     42  |     26   | 61.9
Rape and other sexual offenses         |    683  |    352   | 51.5
Other offenses                         |     18  |      9   | 50.0
                                       +---------+----------+------
    Total                              |  5,322  |  3,536   | 66.4
=======================================+=========+==========+======


At the same congress Dr. Malgat reported the following results of an
investigation made by him in the prison at Nice: [768]


=======================================+=========+==========+======
             Offenses.                 | Entered.| Drinkers.|   %
---------------------------------------+---------+----------+------
Insults and violence to public officers|    138  |     91   | 65.9
Theft                                  |    579  |    357   | 61.6
Obtaining money under false pretenses  |     56  |     34   | 60.7
Assaults                               |    275  |    160   | 58.1
Vagrancy                               |    346  |    196   | 56.6
Indecent assault                       |     52  |     29   | 55.7
Homicide                               |     33  |     18   | 54.5
Expelled offenders                     |    175  |     95   | 54.2
Breach of trust                        |     63  |     33   | 52.3
Other offenses                         |    133  |     80   | 60.1
                                       +---------+----------+------
    Total                              |  1,850  |  1,093   | 56.3
=======================================+=========+==========+======


Germany.

An inquiry made by Dr. A. Baer with regard to the inmates of the German
prisons, in the period after 1870, gives the following results: [769]


=======+==========+============================================
       |          |         Number of Drinkers.
       | Number   +--------------+--------------+--------------
       |   of     |  In General. |  Occasional. |    Habitual.
       |Prisoners.+--------------+--------------+--------------
       |          |Absolute.|  % |Absolute.|  % |Absolute.|  %
-------+----------+---------+----+---------+----+---------+----
Men    |  30,041  | 13,199  |43.9|  7,071  |23.5|  6,128  |20.4
Women  |   2,796  |    507  |18.1|    198  | 7.1|    309  |11.0
       +----------+---------+----+---------+----+---------+----
Total  |  32,837  | 13,706  |41.7|  7,269  |22.1|  6,437  |19.6
=======+==========+=========+====+=========+====+=========+====


For the different crimes and misdemeanors the figures are as follows:
[770]


=================+=========+===============+==============================
                 |         |               |Among the Drinkers there were:
  Crimes and     | Number  |   Drinkers.   +---------------+--------------
  Misdemeanors.  |   of    |               |  Occasional.  |  Habitual.
                 |Prisoners+--------+------+--------+------+--------+-----
                 | (Men).  |Absolute|      |Absolute|      |Absolute|
                 |         |Number. |   %  |Number. |   %  |Number. |   %
-----------------+---------+--------+------+--------+------+--------+-----
                                A. Houses of Correction.
-----------------+---------+--------+------+--------+------+--------+-----
Assaults         |    773  |   575  | 74.5 |   418  | 72.7 |   157  | 27.3
Robbery, etc.    |    898  |   618  | 68.8 |   353  | 57.1 |   265  | 42.9
Homicide         |    348  |   220  | 63.2 |   129  | 58.6 |    91  | 41.4
Rape, etc.       |    954  |   575  | 60.2 |   352  | 61.2 |   223  | 38.8
Theft            | 10,033  | 5,212  | 51.9 | 2,513  | 48.2 | 2,699  | 51.8
Attempted        |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  homicide       |    252  |   128  | 50.8 |    78  | 60.9 |    50  | 39.1
Arson            |    804  |   383  | 47.6 |   184  | 48.0 |   199  | 52.0
Murder           |    514  |   237  | 46.1 |   139  | 58.6 |    98  | 41.4
Various crimes   |  1,689  |   712  | 42.2 |   358  | 50.2 |   354  | 49.8
Perjury          |    590  |   157  | 26.6 |    82  | 52.2 |    75  | 47.8
-----------------+---------+--------+------+--------+------+--------+-----
                                B. Houses of Detention.
-----------------+---------+--------+------+--------+------+--------+-----
Offenses         |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  against morals |    200  |   154  | 77.0 |   113  | 73.3 |    41  | 26.7
Rebellion        |    652  |   489  | 76.5 |   445  | 89.0 |    54  | 11.0
Assaults         |  1,130  |   716  | 63.4 |   581  | 81.1 |   135  | 18.9
Robbery          |     48  |    28  | 58.3 |    16  | 57.0 |    12  | 43.0
Domiciliary      |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  trespass       |    411  |   223  | 54.2 |   210  | 94.2 |    13  |  5.8
Disturbance of   |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  public peace   |     34  |    18  | 52.9 |    12  | 66.6 |     6  | 33.3
Various          |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  misdemeanors   |    826  |   433  | 52.4 |   306  | 70.7 |   127  | 29.3
Arson            |     23  |    11  | 48.0 |     5  | 45.4 |     6  | 54.6
Theft            |  3,282  | 1,048  | 32.0 |   666  | 63.5 |   382  | 36.5
Obtaining        |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  money under    |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  false          |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  pretenses,     |         |        |      |        |      |        |
  forgery, embez.|    786  |   194  | 24.7 |   111  | 57.2 |    83  | 42.8
=================+=========+========+======+========+======+========+=====


Out of a total of 359 vagabonds and mendicants Dr. Bonhoeffer found 281
(78.2 %) alcoholics. [771]


Italy.

Out of a total of 507 criminals examined by him Dr. Marro found 379
(74.7%) addicted to excess in alcohol, and only eight (1.5%) abstainers
or “unknown.” [772]


Netherlands, 1900–1901.

It was only in 1900 that the criminal statistics mentioned for the
first time the number of habitual drunkards among the convicts. Here
are the results:


======================================+=======================
                                      |Percentage of Habitual
     Crimes and Misdemeanors.         |  Drunkards in Each
                                      |     Category.
--------------------------------------+-----------------------
Obtaining money under false pretenses |        16
Crimes against the public authority   |        13
Mendicity and vagabondage             |        10
Crimes of violence                    |        10
Crimes against morals                 |        10
All crimes                            |         8.31
Assault                               |         7
Theft                                 |         7
Receiving stolen goods                |          .5
Poaching                              |         3
======================================+=======================


Among the recidivists the drunkards formed 11.6%.

The data for 1901 are more detailed and also more worthy of confidence.


======================================+=======================
                                      |Percentage of Habitual
     Crimes and Misdemeanors.         |  Drunkards in Each
                                      |     Category.
--------------------------------------+-----------------------
Mendicity and vagabondage             |        26.51
Rebellion                             |        21.16
Embezzlement                          |        19.20
Obtaining money under false pretenses |        18.26
Serious assaults                      |        16.94
Malicious mischief                    |        16.59
Insult to public official             |        16.10
Disturbing the public peace           |        14.33
Simple theft                          |        11.61
Sexual offenses                       |        10.84
Assaults                              |        10.87
Insults                               |         9.96
Aggravated theft                      |         8.84
Poaching                              |         1.46
All crimes                            |        13.00
======================================+=======================


Of the recidivists 21.96% were habitual drunkards. [773]


New York (State), 1869–1870.

In his “Dangerous Classes of New York”, C. L. Brace states that in
1870, out of 49,423 criminals in the prisons of New York City there
were 30,507 (61.6%) habitual drunkards, and 893 (81.6%) of the 1,093
prisoners in the Albany penitentiary in the years 1869–70 likewise were
drunkards. [774]

R. L. Dugdale gives the following figures for the 233 criminals
examined by him: [775]


======================================+=======================
                                      |Percentage of Habitual
           Crimes.                    |     Drunkards.
--------------------------------------+-----------------------
Theft from the person                 |        55.00
Robbery                               |        47.36
Crimes against persons                |        40.47
Theft                                 |        39.28
All crimes                            |        39.05
Crimes against property               |        38.74
Burglary                              |        33.33
======================================+=======================


Prussia, 1894–1897.

Out of 18,049 recidivists in the houses of correction in the years
1849–1897, there were 4,930 (27.3%) habitual drunkards, of whom 4,473
(28.7%) were men, and 457 (18.2%) were women. [776]


Sweden, 1887–1897.

Out of 27,452 inmates in the prisons during the years 1887–1897 there
were 3,273 (11.9%) addicted to drink, of whom 3,101 (12.7%) were men
and 99 (3.2%) women. [777] These figures, however, are below the
reality, since only those are counted as alcoholics who were drunk at
the time they committed the crime. When we take into consideration that
the number of criminals who were in a state of intoxication when they
committed their crimes was 52.6%, we may be certain that a considerable
number of them were habitual drunkards.


Switzerland, 1892–1896.

On the 1st of January, 1892, there were 2,201 persons in the 35
penitentiaries; 1,816 men and 385 women. Among these there were 880
drunkards (39.9%); 762 (42%) men, and 118 (31%) women. [778]

In the years 1892–1896, the Swiss criminal statistics give alcoholism
as the cause of crime in 23.1% of the cases. [779] This figure,
however, has no great value; not only are the statistics concerning
alcoholism as a cause little worthy of confidence, as the author of
them confesses (indeed, it is impossible to speak of “the cause” of a
criminal act, since there are always several); but further there is no
distinction made between acute and chronic alcoholism.


Wurtemberg, 1887–1888.

Among the 3,181 prisoners examined by Sichart in the years 1887–1888,
there were 939 (29.5%) habitual drunkards. The figures for some of the
more important crimes are as follows: [780]


=====================================+==============
                                     |Percentage of
               Crimes.               | Drunkards in
                                     |Each Category.
-------------------------------------+--------------
Crimes against morals                |     36.3
Arson                                |     34.2
Theft                                |     28.0
Obtaining money under false pretenses|     25.7
Perjury                              |     24.0
=====================================+==============


The data given above show sufficiently, it seems to me, what the
relation is between chronic alcoholism and criminality. Notwithstanding
their divergences the percentages in the different countries are
generally very high, and in every case much higher than among the
non-criminal population. The danger that these statistics are based
upon inaccurate data is not great, since the culprit has every reason
to pretend that his act has been committed in a state of intoxication,
in order that he may be less severely punished, and not that he is a
chronic alcoholic.

There still remains the question as to what is the degree of influence
which chronic alcoholism has upon crime. We should be exaggerating if
we were to declare (as is sometimes done by total abstainers) that
whenever a criminal is an habitual alcoholic, alcoholism is one of the
principal causes of his crime. It is evident that in many cases it is
only an accidental phenomenon. Nevertheless, the figures given above
agree with the thesis that chronic alcoholism is a demoralizing agent
and as such belongs to the etiology of crime. Its influence naturally
cannot be exactly expressed in figures. [781]



h. Militarism. Although the influence of militarism upon criminality
may not be an important factor in comparison with some others, it is
still necessary to speak of it here briefly, and under two heads: its
influence in time of peace, and its influence in time of war.

First, the influence of militarism in time of peace. The army is
recruited in great part among those who do not volunteer, in other
words among persons who have not the least taste for the military life
and only serve for fear of incurring severe penalties. Then a great
number of the volunteers have become soldiers only from necessity,
because they could not find a place for themselves anywhere else.
Finally one class of volunteers have enlisted very young, for a long
term of service, perhaps at the instance of their parents, or drawn by
the brilliant uniform, or other means of advertising peculiar to the
army. It is unnecessary to add that for the last two classes the
military service is often a deception, which makes them regret having
engaged in it.

The first source of demoralization in an army is to be found in its
composition. When you bring together a number of men, uneducated for
the most part, with nothing to unite them but constraint, and when
there are already certain bad elements among them, the demoralizing
influence makes itself felt at once. No moral bond unites these men,
but on the contrary a vague irritation begins to spread. And this
demoralization is not counteracted by that great moral force, work; a
great part of the time among the soldiers is passed in forced idleness,
and the rest in learning things in which they have little interest, if
indeed they do not feel an aversion to them.

It is naturally only by a discipline of iron that order can be
maintained and the recruits taught their trade. As soon as a man is
debased by excessive discipline to the rôle of a machine, his moral
qualities deteriorate; the state of things thus created brings it about
that the great power given to superiors often degenerates into a thirst
for domination, and renders the subordinates servile, and yet of the
opinion that anything is right for them so long as they are not found
out. [782]

Since most soldiers are only under arms for a short time, the
consequences named are not of great importance for them, but those
consequences nevertheless exist for the professional soldier. The best
known set of statistics upon the criminality among soldiers is that of
Hausner, [783] who shows that it is 25 times as great as the
criminality of civilians. These figures, however, have little value,
because among the civilians are counted not simply the men of military
age, but the whole population. Further, a statistical comparison of
military and civil criminality will always meet with great
difficulties, for, first, there are offenses of which only soldiers can
be guilty; second, the number of the soldiers is not constant even in
any one year. Although we cannot, therefore, express in figures the
harmful influences of militarism, it exists, nevertheless. But even if
we had the figures and they were to show—supposing a most improbable
case—that criminality was no greater among soldiers than in civil life,
even this would not contradict the evil influence of military life,
since repression and the fear of punishment are greater among soldiers
than among civilians, and abject poverty, one of the powerful factors
in economic criminality, is totally lacking in the army. [784]

The question may be raised as to whether the disadvantages spoken of
above are inseparable from every form of organization of the army. The
answer must be that this is the case in part only. The harmful
consequences will partially disappear when the army is adapted to the
democratic spirit, and the service remains limited to the time strictly
necessary to make a good soldier; but the fact that the great mass of
which the army is composed has no sympathy with its aim and end but
remains in service only by constraint, will continue to exist. This
latter circumstance will disappear only in the country where the army
is exclusively for the purposes of defense, to repulse an enemy that
wishes to destroy democratic institutions.

We come now to the influence of war itself. That which, at ordinary
times, is one of the gravest crimes, homicide, is commanded in war;
ravages and burnings are the order of the day. It is inevitable that
those who are driven to commit such acts, lose little by little their
respect for the lives and property of their fellows. War arouses a
spirit of violence, not only in those who take part in it, but in the
whole population.

Happily wars are neither so numerous nor so long continued as formerly,
so that the consequences have no longer so wide a scope.

Statistical research into the influence of war upon criminality is very
difficult, for criminality diminishes in time of war in an abnormal
fashion, first, because a great part of the male population of the age
most disposed to crime is under arms; second, the repression of crime
being less vigorous makes the degree of criminality appear smaller than
it really is, which explains why the figures for the criminality of
women and juveniles are less.

We often hear that war has also a good moral influence, since the whole
nation is then animated with a single ideal. This is true only in the
very rare cases where a war is really popular, in place of being the
means of procuring material profits for a small minority, while the
great majority remain indifferent. It goes without saying that even in
these exceptional cases, the harmful consequences to the participants
still remain. [785]

We have examined the tendencies of the present economic system and of
its consequences. Before concluding we must treat of the effect of



i. The penalty. The present codes give prominence to three kinds of
penalties: fines, different kinds of imprisonment, and capital
punishment. We naturally do not have to say anything of the first of
these, since there can be no question raised as to its effect upon the
person upon whom the fine is laid. All that we can say is that this
penalty fails of its object since no account is taken of the financial
condition of the person sentenced to it, and it follows that while the
punishment involved is only trifling for the rich, it constitutes a
heavy burden for the poor. Often a fine for a poor man who cannot pay
is simply a sentence to a short imprisonment.

The death penalty also naturally is outside of our present discussion.
I would simply observe that among the numerous arguments against this
penalty it must be noted that it has no intimidating effect upon those
who are present, as one would suppose, but on the contrary a
demoralizing influence; besides which the attention of the ignorant
class is drawn to the crime and the perpetrator of it. Those who are
condemned to death have almost all been present at executions. Out of a
total of 511 of whom we have information, there were only 15 (about 3%)
who had never witnessed an execution. [786]

In investigating the influence of punishment upon morality it is
imprisonment alone, therefore, which must be taken into consideration,
so much the more since even in the case of minor crimes it is almost
always inflicted, while capital punishment is either altogether
abolished, as in some countries, or else rarely pronounced and still
more rarely executed.

The following table shows how many times imprisonment is inflicted in
comparison with other forms of punishment.


Germany, 1882–1895. [787]

=================+=============================================
                 | Penalties to Each 1,000 Persons Sentenced.
                 +------+------------+------+------------------
     Years.      |Death.|Imprisonment|Fines.|Public Admonition.
                 |      |(All kinds.)|      |
-----------------+------+------------+------+------------------
1882             | 0.3  |   736.3    | 253  |        10
1883-87 } annual | 0.2  |   697.4    | 291  |        11
1888-92 } average| 0.1  |   660.2    | 323  |        17
1893             | 0.1  |   619.2    | 363  |        18
1894             | 0.1  |   607.2    | 375  |        18
1895             | 0.1  |   595.2    | 386  |        19
=================+======+============+======+==================


60% to 70% of the sentences, then, were deprivation of liberty. What is
the effect of this? The answer to this question must be found in the
statistics of recidivism. Here are the results for certain countries of
Europe, which probably are not much different from those of other
countries.


Germany, 1882–1900. [788]

======+==============+==========================================
      |              |To 100,000 of the Population over 12 there
      |  Numbers of  |    were Recidivists who were Convicted
Years.|Recidivists to+-------+--------+-------------+-----------
      |100 Convicts. | Once. | Twice. |3 to 5 Times.|6 Times and
      |              |       |        |             |   Over.
------+--------------+-------+--------+-------------+-----------
 1882 |     24.9     |  115  |   56   |      64     |    23
 1883 |     25.8     |  119  |   59   |      69     |    20
 1884 |     26.3     |  127  |   63   |      72     |    22
 1885 |     27.4     |  127  |   63   |      75     |    26
 1886 |     28.0     |  129  |   65   |      79     |    30
 1887 |     28.8     |  131  |   66   |      81     |    34
 1888 |     29.3     |  127  |   65   |      80     |    35
 1889 |     31.2     |  142  |   71   |      87     |    40
 1890 |     32.7     |  150  |   76   |      93     |    43
 1891 |     34.0     |  158  |   79   |      99     |    47
 1892 |     34.7     |  169  |   87   |     107     |    54
 1893 |     35.2     |  171  |   88   |     111     |    57
 1894 |     36.9     |  181  |   93   |     120     |    65
 1895 |     37.9     |  184  |   96   |     124     |    69
 1896 |     38.8     |  183  |   96   |     129     |    75
 1897 |     39.6     |  186  |   99   |     129     |    78
 1898 |     40.1     |  189  |  100   |     133     |    83
 1899 |     40.8     |  187  |  100   |     133     |    85
 1900 |     41.2     |  180  |   96   |     131     |    86
======+==============+=======+========+=============+===========


Recidivism has regularly increased, then: a little more than 65% in 18
years.

It is present in different crimes in very various degrees. For the
following crimes it is very great.


Germany, 1882–1895. [789]

===============================+===================================================
                               |Number of Recidivists having undergone Imprisonment
                               |            to Each 100 Convicts in the
            Crimes.            |                       Years
                               +-------------+-------------+-------------+---------
                               |    1882.    |    1886.    |    1890.    |  1895.
-------------------------------+-------------+-------------+-------------+---------
Leze-majesty                   |    40.7     |    41.3     |    43.2     |  52.8
Rebellion                      |    31.8     |    41.3     |    46.8     |  52.7
Robbery and blackmail          |    44.4     |    45.6     |    51.5     |  50.9
False accusation               |    34.8     |    37.1     |    42.1     |  48.3
Crimes of fraud                |    32.9     |    38.9     |    42.9     |  45.4
Crimes against personal liberty|    26.6     |    32.3     |    37.8     |  42.8
Theft and embezzlement         |    32.1     |    35.2     |    37.2     |  40.4
Crimes against morals          |    24.1     |    31.3     |    35.9     |  38.3
Counterfeiting                 |    28.5     |    31.1     |    35.1     |  38.2
===============================+=============+=============+=============+=========


The following figures give a picture of recidivism in


England and Wales, 1871–1900. [790]

=======+===============+======================================================
       |               |Percentage among Convicts of Recidivists who have been
       |  Percentage   |                      Convicted
Years. |of Recidivists +----------+----------+----------+----------+----------
       |among Convicts.|  Once.   |  2 to 5  | 6 to 10  | 11 to 20 | Over 20
       |               |          |  Times.  |  Times.  |  Times.  |  Times.
-------+---------------+----------+----------+----------+----------+----------
1871-77|     40        |          |          |          |          |
1880-92|     48        |          |          |          |          |
1894   |     54.5      |   15.2   |   18.3   |   7.7    |   6.2    |   6.9
1895   |     55.5      |   15.7   |   18.0   |   8.9    |   6.9    |   5.9
1896   |     57.3      |   14.8   |   19.1   |   9.0    |   7.7    |   6.6
1897   |     57.6      |   18.9   |   19.0   |   8.8    |   7.6    |   7.1
1898   |     59.9      |   16.2   |   20.0   |   8.9    |   7.5    |   7.1
1899   |     60.2      |   16.4   |   19.9   |   9.2    |   7.6    |   7.0
1900   |     59.3      |   15.8   |   19.2   |   9.2    |   7.7    |   7.4
=======+===============+==========+==========+==========+==========+==========


Here also, then, as in Germany there is a great increase in recidivism;
72% in 29 years.

For some offenses recidivism is more common than for others, as the
following figures show.


England and Wales, 1899–1900. [791]

(Assizes and Quarter Sessions.)

======+===============================================================
      |Number of Recidivists to 100 Persons Convicted of the Following
      |                            Crimes.
Years.+--------+---------+---------+---------+---------------+--------
      | Crimes | Crimes  | Crimes  |         |               |
      |against |against  |against  |         |    Forgery    |
      |Persons.|Property |Property |Malicious|      and      | Other
      |        |  with   | without |Mischief.|Counterfeiting.|Crimes.
      |        |Violence.|Violence.|         |               |
------+--------+---------+---------+---------+---------------+--------
 1894 |  32.1  |  67.3   |  64.1   |  42.5   |     41.1      |  27.9
 1895 |  35.2  |  67.3   |  66.1   |  51.8   |     38.5      |  24.4
 1896 |  36.1  |  67.2   |  66.3   |  44.3   |     37.4      |  25.0
 1897 |  38.0  |  68.7   |  66.4   |  51.1   |     40.0      |  28.1
 1898 |  39.3  |  68.1   |  68.3   |  56.0   |     43.2      |  32.4
 1899 |  37.7  |  69.9   |  67.4   |  58.3   |     40.0      |  35.2
 1900 |  39.7  |  71.0   |  68.9   |  59.4   |     40.9      |  29.8
======+========+=========+=========+=========+===============+========


The following table has to do with


Austria, 1866–1899. [792]

=========+==========================================================================
         |                        Percentage of Convicts Who
         +------------------+------------------+------+----------------+------------
 Years.  |Had been convicted|Had been convicted|      |Had been already|    Were
         |     of Crime     |     of Crime     |Total.|   convicted    |Recidivists.
         |   Once Before.   |  Several Times.  |      |of a Misdemeanor|
         |                  |                  |      |       or       |
         |                  |                  |      | Contravention. |
---------+------------------+------------------+------+----------------+------------
1866-1870|       11.9       |       15.5       | 27.4 |      17.5      |    44.9
1871-1875|       11.6       |       14.2       | 25.8 |      17.9      |    43.7
1876-1880|       10.9       |       14.6       | 25.5 |      22.2      |    47.7
1881-1885|       10.6       |       14.2       | 24.8 |      25.2      |    50.0
1886-1890|       10.9       |       12.9       | 23.8 |      27.9      |    51.7
1891-1895|       11.1       |       12.5       | 23.6 |      28.9      |    52.5
1896     |       12.5       |       10.7       | 23.2 |      31.5      |    54.7
1897     |       12.7       |       10.6       | 23.3 |      30.4      |    53.8
1898     |       12.5       |        9.9       | 22.4 |      29.1      |    51.5
1899     |       12.4       |       10.1       | 22.5 |      29.8      |    52.4
=========+==================+==================+======+================+============


This table has only a little value for the problem of recidivism; it
bears only upon those convicted of crime and leaves out of account
those convicted of misdemeanors; and in the last two columns are
included persons convicted of contraventions, who ought not to figure
in statistics of recidivism.

The following figures have much greater value.


France, 1850–1900. [793]

=============+==============================
             |Percentage of Recidivists in
             |  Each Group of Convicts.
             +--------+--------------+------
  Years.     |Assizes.| Correctional |Total.
             |        |  Tribunals.  |
-------------+--------+--------------+------
 1850-1855   |   33   |      --      |  --
 1856-1860   |   36   |      --      |  31
 1861-1865   |   38   |      --      |  34
 1866-1870   |   41   |      --      |  38
 1871-1875   |   47   |      --      |  42
 1876-1880   |   48   |      --      |  44
 1881-1885   |   52   |      44      |  44
 1886-1890   |   56   |      47      |  47
 1891-1895   |   57   |      46      |  46
 1896-1900   |   57   |      46      |  46
=============+========+==============+======


Here, then, is a steady increase, checked only in the last 15 years by
the law of May 27th, 1885, upon recidivism.

The following table shows recidivism for certain offenses. [794]


========================================+=====================================
                                        |  Percentage of Recidivists among
Crimes and Misdemeanors.                |              Convicts.
                                        +--------+--------+--------+----------
                                        |1881-85.|1886-90.|1891-95.|1896-1900.
----------------------------------------+--------+--------+--------+----------
Drunkenness                             |   81   |   79   |   79   |    86
Vagabondage                             |   73   |   78   |   79   |    82
Mendicity                               |   72   |   77   |   75   |    80
Assaults upon parents, etc.             |   69   |   63   |   55   |    80
Aggravated theft                        |   73   |   77   |   79   |    79
Counterfeiting                          |   50   |   54   |   57   |    55
Insults and violence to public officials|   48   |   50   |   51   |    51
Obtaining money under false pretenses   |   51   |   50   |   51   |    50
Homicide                                |   42   |   50   |   52   |    50
Murder                                  |   46   |   44   |   44   |    48
Arson                                   |   53   |   50   |   52   |    46
Theft                                   |   47   |   51   |   47   |    46
Serious assaults                        |   40   |   35   |   42   |    46
Domestic theft                          |   47   |   45   |   42   |    44
Forgery                                 |   37   |   43   |   46   |    44
Fraudulent bankruptcy                   |   33   |   26   |   31   |    44
Misdemeanor connected with fishing      |   35   |   39   |   39   |    41
Breach of trust                         |   41   |   43   |   41   |    39
Offenses connected with hunting         |   26   |   32   |   34   |    38
Minor assaults                          |   32   |   36   |   35   |    35
Offenses against morals                 |   31   |   30   |   32   |    31
Maltreatment of children                |   32   |   25   |   21   |    25
Infanticide                             |    7   |    6   |    8   |     7
========================================+========+========+========+==========


Here are the figures for


Italy, 1876–1889. [795]

========+=========================
        |Percentage of Recidivists
        |  among those arraigned
        |         Before.
 Years. +----------+--------------
        | Assizes. | Correctional
        |          | tribunals.
--------+----------+--------------
 1876   |   10.4   |      --
 1877   |   11.2   |      --
 1878   |   13.2   |      --
 1879   |   20.7   |      --
 1880   |   21.5   |      --
 1881   |   26.5   |     20.2
 1882   |   28.8   |     21.1
 1883   |   29.4   |     22.6
 1884   |   32.8   |     23.6
 1885   |   34.7   |     27.6
 1886   |   34.0   |     27.8
 1887   |   36.0   |     32.2
 1888   |   32.2   |     30.6
 1889   |   36.3   |     32.3
========+==========+==============


In Italy also, then, there is a constant increase of recidivism (except
in 1888).


In conclusion, here are the figures for the


Netherlands, 1896–1901. [796]

========+=========+============+============+========================
        |         |            |            | Percentage of Convicts
        |         |            | Percentage | who had been Convicted.
 Years. |Convicts.|Recidivists.|     of     +-------+-------+--------
        |         |            |Recidivists.|       |2 to 5 |6 times
        |         |            |            | Once. |times. |or more.
--------+---------+------------+------------+-------+-------+--------
 1896   |  17,205 |   5,097    |     29.6   | 17.1  |  10.3 |   2.2
 1897   |  16,832 |   5,566    |     33.0   | 19.6  |  11.6 |   1.8
 1898   |  16,368 |   5,997    |     36.6   | 21.2  |  13.2 |   2.2
 1899   |  15,631 |   6,092    |     38.9   | 20.7  |  15.4 |   2.8
 1900   |  15,169 |   6,048    |     39.8   | 20.3  |  16.2 |   3.3
========+=========+============+============+=======+=======+========


The imperfection of the present mode of combating crime is shown even
by the evidence of the statistics we have given. It would be hard to
imagine a more complete fiasco; in place of a decrease there has been
an increase of recidivism; in place of making men better, the prison
makes them worse.

Here is in brief the explanation of the fact. As we have already
observed above in treating of the definition of crime, one of the
important elements in the present system of punishment consists, for
many people, in the desire to satisfy their revengeful feelings excited
by the crime. Those who realize that the punishment must be especially
aimed at the improvement of the criminal form only a small minority.
The present forms of punishment and the manner in which they are
inflicted are little if at all in accord with this latter point of
view. At present the penalty is not much more than an evil inflicted
upon the criminal to satisfy the vengeance of a great part of mankind,
and at the same time to make it impossible for the criminal to do harm,
either for a time or else forever, and finally to terrify him and other
men into not committing crimes. So long as punishment has this
characteristic, so long as it does not aim at the improvement of the
criminal, so long will it fail to effect a decrease in crime, but will
rather bring an increase, as the facts prove. No one, not even the most
dangerous criminal is morally improved in the slightest degree by
vengeance wreaked upon him. Vengeance engenders only vengeance and no
other feeling. We can expect to see good results from punishment only
if the criminal, from the manner in which he is treated, perceives that
those who have him in charge wish him well, are trying to improve him,
and that his act was wicked and intolerable.

There are two types of imprisonment; imprisonment in common, and in
separate cells. It is very easy to understand that a term of
imprisonment served in common has disastrous consequences for the
prisoner. It is because of this system that the prison has had the name
of a school of crime, which would be a good joke if the facts were less
serious. All kinds of criminals, young and old, those sentenced for
minor offenses, [797] and those guilty of grave crimes, criminals
against property and criminals against persons, all find themselves
massed together, so that instead of leaving prison bettered, almost
every one leaves it worse than he went in. No work is done, or at least
only stupefying labors; a real trade is neither practiced nor learned.
[798]

The disadvantages of this system have led to the cellular plan by which
the contagious influences of the prison are gotten rid of. Much was
hoped for from the change, but the statistics of recidivism show the
hope to have been ill-founded; separate confinement improves the
prisoner no more than the older type. This fact is not difficult to
explain. Starting from the false theory that man has a free will, the
non-determinists have believed, and unhappily still believe, that the
criminal left to himself and to his own reflections will repent. As
Sacker in “Der Rückfall” judiciously remarks, the criminal must not be
left to his thoughts—if he has any—but must be given new ideas. It is
unnecessary to remark that it is not life in a cell that will give them
to him.

Man is a social being; without life among his fellows he is like an
animal out of its element. How can he become better if he lives alone.
The cell stupefies him, isolation and monotony make him a machine,
which later will not be fit for a free life. I do not know a better
description of the consequences of separate confinement than that given
by the competent author of “Pictures and Problems from London Police
Courts”, Th. Holmes. He says: “How is it that a man’s facial expression
changes during a long detention? How is it that his voice becomes hard
and unnatural? How is it that his eyes become shifty, cunning, and
wild? It is no fault of the prison officials; they cannot help these
things; from the governor downward they are not to blame. It is not
because of hard work. From conversation with, and knowledge of, such
men, I gather that some of them at any rate would be thankful for more
work. It is the system that does it, the long-continued,
soul-and-mind-destroying monotony, the long, silent nights in which for
hours men lie awake thinking, thinking, thinking, driven in upon
themselves and to be their own selves’ only companion. No interchange
of ideas is possible, no sound of human voices comes to call forth
their own, and their own vocal organs rust. Nor does returning day
bring change, nothing but the same duties, performed in the same way,
at the same hour, and the same food, in the same quantities, served in
the same demoralizing way. They become strangers to the usages of
civilized society, and devour their food even as the beasts, but not
with the wild beast’s relish. To the use of knife and fork they become
strangers; to a knowledge of their own lineaments they become
strangers; to high thoughts, amiable words, courtesy, love of truth,
and all that makes a man they become strangers, for these virtues
cannot dwell with senseless monotony. But if these things die of
atrophy, other but less desirable qualities are developed. A low
cunning takes their place; the wits are sharpened to deceive or to gain
small ends; hypocrisy is developed, and men come out of prison hating
it, loathing it, but less fitted to perform the duties of life than
when they entered it.” [799]

Read further the opinion of Dostoievsky: “I am firmly convinced that
the boasted cellular system pursues but a false, if specious, aim. It
sucks the vital power out of a man, enervates his mind, weakens and
cows him, and finally presents the desiccated mummy of a man made half
mad, as a picture of reformation and repentance.” [800]

It would be possible to fill these pages with the well-supported
opinions of those who regard the cellular system as “an aberration of
the 19th century” (Ferri). [801]

To sum up then, we come to the conclusion that the system of
imprisonment is not in a condition to arrest the tide of criminality,
but further that it is even one of the causes of the increase of crime,
since it makes the prisoners still worse. It may be that in consequence
of what I have just said the reader will remark that there is no other
expedient possible than imprisonment, whether in common or cellular.
Although the question of the treatment of the criminal as it ought to
be is not one of those with which we are at present occupied, I shall
nevertheless say a few words on the subject.

It is possible to practice a third system, which takes its origin from
the idea that the crime does not proceed from the free will, but from
causes which it will be necessary to try to remove, in place of
inflicting a useless punishment. It is to the credit of the State of
New York that it should be the first to put in practice this sort of a
system of combating crime (in the Elmira Reformatory). An effort is
made to make a man of the criminal, to turn him into a strong and sound
individual; he is taught a trade, his mind is elevated, his feeling of
honor revived, in short, everything is done that is necessary to
stimulate the development of what is human in the man. And the results
prove that those who are following this method are surely on the right
road. [802]

There is only one objection to this system; that many persons who have
not committed crime lead a life which in various ways is worse than
that of the criminals so treated. However, this very sound objection
does not condemn the system, but rather the present organization of
society, which obliges a great number of persons to drag out a
miserable existence. The question of crime and the social question are
inseparable; he who examines the first without the second will not do
much toward solving it.



j. Imitation. Before concluding we must give our attention to one more
factor: imitation. We have already pointed this out in speaking of the
moral education of the young, but it is also of importance with adults
(e.g. the influence of the press, etc.; see above, C., a., in this
chapter), though not to so great an extent. When society shows very
egoistic tendencies imitation strengthens these considerably; when we
see persons with whom we have to do, always acting in an egoistic
manner, our anti-egoistic forces weaken little by little and we end by
doing as the others do. [803] In the crime of mobs imitation plays an
important part.

The proofs to support the power of imitation in the etiology of crime
are to be found in the biographies of most great criminals; bad example
plays generally a preponderant rôle in the drama of life. I know only a
single set of statistics giving exact information of the atmosphere in
which criminals have lived, and so furnishing an idea of the influence
of imitation. It is that furnished by the “Elmira Reformatory”.
According to the “Twenty-second Yearbook” (1897) the character of the
people with whom the inmates had associated was as follows: [804]


=========================+==========================
                         |       Prisoners.
Character of Associates. +------------------+-------
                         | Absolute Number. |    %
-------------------------+------------------+-------
Positively bad           |       4,511      |  54.2
Less bad                 |       3,614      |  43.4
Doubtful                 |          81      |   1.4
Good                     |         113      |   1.0
                         +------------------+-------
  Total                  |       8,319      | 100.0
=========================+==================+=======


A second proof of the influence of the contagion of crime is found in
the fact that the criminality in the cities, where people come more
into contact with each other, is in general greater than that in the
country. Although it is evident that we cannot impute this exclusively
to imitation (it is due, among other things, in part to the great
differences of fortune found in the cities), it still plays an
important part. [805] The following figures give a picture of the
criminality in the large cities and in the country. [806]


England and Wales, 1894–1898.

======================+===========================================================
                      |        Crimes Known to the Police, to the 100,000
                      |                   of the Population.
                      +---------------+---------------+---------------------------
                      |All Indictable |Crimes Against |  Crimes Against Persons.
    Districts.        |   Offenses.   |   Property.   +-------------+-------------
                      |               |               |  Crimes of  |   Sexual
                      |               |               |  Violence.  |   Crimes.
                      +-------+-------+-------+-------+------+------+------+------
                      |  1894.|  1898.|  1894.|  1898.| 1894.| 1898.| 1894.| 1898.
----------------------+-------+-------+-------+-------+------+------+------+------
London                | 416.77| 391.56| 386.24| 358.90| 11.95| 10.63|  5.93|  5.72
Mining districts      | 234.33| 230.84| 214.32| 211.07|  8.39|  7.19|  8.11|  7.89
Manufacturing cities  | 351.84| 325.93| 332.48| 306.21|  6.66|  6.74|  4.43|  4.00
Sea-ports             | 643.60| 611.10| 597.91| 575.60| 22.54| 16.72|  8.44|  5.95
Watering places, etc. | 265.70| 302.25| 250.37| 283.34|  4.38|  5.93|  4.14|  6.16
Agricultural districts|       |       |       |       |      |      |      |
    divided into:     |       |       |       |       |      |      |      |
  1st. Eastern        | 128.20| 120.23| 119.06| 107.84|  3.76|  3.22|  3.63|  5.45
  2nd. South-eastern  | 182.97| 195.86| 163.52| 176.55|  5.29|  6.22|  8.10|  8.70
  3rd. Around London  | 202.13| 198.07| 185.97| 181.41|  4.29|  4.94|  6.53|  6.32
England and Wales     | 296.70| 284.20| 275.93| 262.83|  7.28|  7.39|  6.09|  5.94
======================+=======+=======+=======+=======+======+======+======+======


The following table [807] relates to


Bavaria, 1883–1897.

=============================+==================================================
                             | Number of Convicts to 10,000 of the Population
                             |             over 12 Years of Age.
                             +----------------+----------------+----------------
        Crimes.              |   1883-1887.   |   1888-1892.   |   1893-1897.
                             +-------+--------+-------+--------+-------+--------
                             | City. |Country.| City. |Country.| City. |Country.
-----------------------------|-------+--------+-------+--------+-------+--------
Assault                      |  19.9 |  27.7  |  19.9 |  31.2  |  22.4 |  32.8
Theft                        |  37.4 |  26.6  |  39.7 |  26.1  |  37.3 |  25.9
Fraud                        |  10.2 |   5.0  |  12.1 |   6.9  |  12.5 |   6.9
Violence and threats against |       |        |       |        |       |
  public officials           |   4.7 |   2.7  |   4.5 |   2.4  |   4.9 |   2.6
All crimes                   | 137.1 | 114.0  | 133.7 | 119.6  | 139.4 | 123.1
=============================+=======+========+=======+========+=======+========


As in England the criminality in the cities is in general greater than
in the country.

We find the same picture in the figures for


France, 1881–1900. [808]

=============+==============================
 Residence.  |Number of Persons Arraigned to
             |  100,000 of the Population.
             +---------------+--------------
             |   1881-1885.  |   1896-1900.
-------------+---------------+--------------
Urban        |     15.4      |     11.1
Rural        |      7.8      |      5.4
=============+===============+==============


The following table gives figures for certain important crimes. [809]


==================+=================================
                  |Percentage of Persons Arraigned.
                  +----------------+----------------
Crimes.           |Living in Rural |Living in Urban
                  |   Communes.    |   Communes.
                  +--------+-------+----------------
                  |  1881. | 1900. | 1881. | 1900.
------------------+--------+-------+-------+--------
Murder            |    64  |   50  |   36  |   50
Homicide          |    58  |   54  |   42  |   46
Assaults          |    50  |   56  |   50  |   44
Indecent assaults |    55  |   53  |   45  |   47
Forgery           |    37  |   37  |   63  |   63
Breach of trust   |    35  |   14  |   65  |   86
Arson             |    77  |   74  |   23  |   26
Theft             |    33  |   21  |   67  |   79
==================+========+=======+=======+========


In studying the preceding table it must be noted that in the two
periods 34% and 39% of the population respectively were urban.


Netherlands, 1901. [810]

======================+==============================================+==================
  Places where the    |      Percentage of Convicts who had          | Percentage of
Offense was Committed.|    Committed their Crimes in the Groups      |Whole Population
                      |          of Communes Designated.             | Living in the
                      |                                              |Groups Designated.
                      +------+----------+---------+------------------+------------------
                      |Total.|Rebellion.| Simple  |Simple |Aggravated|
                      |      |          |Assaults.|Theft. |  Theft.  |
----------------------+------+----------+---------+-------+----------+------------------
Communes of more than |      |          |         |       |          |
  20,000 inhabitants  | 38.3 |   45.3   |   21.2  |  41.7 |   50.4   |      36.8
Communes of less than |      |          |         |       |          |
  20,000 inhabitants  | 61.7 |   54.7   |   78.8  |  58.3 |   49.6   |      63.2
======================+======+==========+=========+=======+==========+==================


An examination of the statistics given shows that except for a few
offenses the cities are more criminal than the country. [811] However,
it must not be forgotten that the cities have proportionately a greater
number of inhabitants at the age at which there is the greatest
tendency to crime, and that the figures therefore give the criminality
of the cities as a little greater than it is. On the other hand there
is a greater proportion of crimes that are not prosecuted, or whose
authors remain undiscovered. The English statistics, which do not speak
of the persons arraigned or convicted, but of the crimes known to the
police, are better in this regard.

It is unnecessary to treat more fully of the rôle of imitation in the
etiology of crime; no one will deny it. As I have already noted, in
Part I, in my criticism of the theory of Tarde, imitation is not an
independent factor, but dependent upon others. In our present society,
with its pronounced egoistic tendencies, imitation strengthens these,
as it would strengthen the altruistic tendencies produced by another
form of society. Man does not imitate that which is egoistic simply,
but also that which is altruistic. It is only as a consequence of the
predominance of egoism in our present society that the error is made of
supposing the effect of imitation to be necessarily evil.



k. Conclusions. In recapitulating now the egoistic tendencies of the
present economic system and of its consequences, we see clearly that
they are very strong. Because of these tendencies the social instinct
of man is not greatly developed; they have weakened the moral force in
man which combats the inclination towards egoistic acts, and hence
towards the crimes which are one form of these acts. To mention only
the most important things, in a society in which, as in ours, the
economic interests of all are in eternal conflict among themselves,
compassion for the misfortunes of others inevitably becomes blunted,
and a great part of morality consequently disappears. The slight value
that is attached to the opinion of others is also a consequence of the
strife of economic interests, for we can be responsive to that opinion
only when we do not see adversaries in our fellows.

The fluctuations of the mind of the person in whom the criminal idea is
born may be compared with the oscillations of a balance; and it is upon
sociology that must devolve the task of examining the forces which
throw a weight on one side or the other. When the organization of
society influences men in an altruistic way there is then a
considerable force which can prevent the balance from inclining towards
the egoistic side. In our present society, the organization of which
does not exert an altruistic influence, this force is very weak, or
does not exist at all. Since, however, in every society, man must
abstain from a number of egoistic acts, substitutes have been devised
to take the place of the weak or wanting social sentiments. The hope of
reward (whether terrestrial or celestial) and the fear of being
punished (whether by man or God) are charged with the duty of keeping
men in order. As believers themselves know very well, most men are not
very responsive to divine rewards and punishments—heaven and hell are
too far off. Is it not believers who are the strongest partisans of
rewards and punishments here below for human acts? However, this
expedient is only a very insufficient one. We know too well that the
rewards are very often lacking, and the punishments as well. This is
why many persons take the risk of committing the crime they have
planned.

The present environment exercises an egoistic influence upon all men.
We all participate, for example, in exchange, which, as we have seen,
is a great egoistic factor; and other similar factors could be named
that act upon all. On the other hand there are other egoistic factors
which exercise their influence only upon some of us.

Let us compare two totally different environments in which an
individual grows up. Let us place him first in the slums of a great
city; his father is alcoholic, his mother a prostitute; he has never
attended school, passing his time in vagabondage up to the day when,
still young, he has been committed to prison, where his education in
crime is completed. Now let us suppose this same individual to have
grown up in a healthy environment, where neither poverty nor extreme
riches exercised their pernicious influence. He has been brought up by
rational and loving parents, his mind has been developed, he has found
later a good career, in which the greed of gold has not been aroused in
him. We shall then have before us two extremes, between which a great
many degrees are to be found. The environment is a very important cause
of the great diversity among men. However, it is not the only one; we
still must give our attention for a moment to:




D. Individual Differences.

Men differ in height, in strength, in weight, in intellectual capacity,
in everything, in short. Apparently no regularity is to be seen in
their diversity. If, for example, we look at a crowd with reference to
the heights of the individuals composing it, there seems to be no
regularity about them. However, this is only in appearance. By placing
all the persons in a line according to their height, and drawing a line
at the top of their heads we shall always get a curve differing little
from the one below (the greater the number of persons, the lower the
point A, the higher the point D, and the more nearly horizontal the
line BC).


[Illustration]


The irregularity is, then, only apparent; there is regularity in this
sense, that the persons of average height predominate very greatly in
number, and that the very short and very tall persons form minorities.
This regularity in the individual differences, discovered by Quetelet,
has been recognized as a universal law, applicable to everything
living. The scientist named has demonstrated this not only for the
height of the human body, but also for its weight, strength, quickness,
etc.

Galton has proved the existence of this law for the intellectual
capacity of man, and a number of other scientists have done the same
for the animal and vegetable kingdoms. [812] Hence, “uniformity in
variability” for all living nature must be considered as a universal
law.

The same thing must be true for men’s moral qualities. In ranking any
number of persons according to the intensity of their innate social
sentiments (supposing it were possible to apply a measure to these), we
should find that here also the law in question held good; with the
great majority the social sentiments would have only a moderate
intensity, while there would be one small minority in which they would
be weak, and another in which they would be very strong. We have no
need to revert to the influence of the environment, for we have seen
that it gives to all an egoistic or altruistic impulse, differing
naturally according to the individual. [813] Supposing that the
environment were the same for all, there would still be great
differences between men as to the intensity of their social sentiments.

What is now the importance of this fact for the etiology of crime? In
my opinion, the answer to this question will not be different from
those which have been given to analogous questions when we were
treating of the etiology of prostitution and alcoholism (pp. 407, 408
and 428), namely, that in every society, everywhere and always, an
individual, according as his social sentiments are weaker or stronger
than another’s, runs more or less risk than he of becoming a criminal,
supposing the environment of the two to be the same in effect. The man
who, according to the intensity of his social sentiments, would be
placed in the line between A and B, would run more danger of becoming a
criminal than the man who belonged between C and D. This point is of
great importance for anyone who is investigating why the first falls
into crime and not the latter. But it has little weight for criminal
sociology, which concerns itself, not with definite persons, but only
with general social facts.

The evidence that individuals differ quantitatively always and
everywhere does not give the explanation of the problems whose solution
sociology seeks, although they must be taken into account. The task
that is incumbent upon it is to explain why individuals who, as a
consequence of their innate qualities, run more danger than others of
becoming criminals, actually become so. He who is born with weak social
instincts runs more danger of becoming a criminal. But the certainty
that he will become such does not exist—that depends upon the
environment.

To sum up; I am of the opinion that individual differences are of great
importance for one who is studying an individual by himself, but that
they do not belong to the domain of the etiology of criminality.




E. The Classification of Crime.

Before proceeding to the treatment of crimes separately, it is
necessary to divide them into some main groups. It is a grave error
(committed, however, by many criminologists) not to take account of the
very different nature of crimes, if one is concerned with their
etiology. It is, to be sure, permissible to treat conjointly moral
forces which may prevent the execution of criminal ideas and which
apply to all crimes. I have done so in the preceding pages. But we
cannot treat the origin of the criminal idea itself in this same way.
There are criminals and criminals. There are enormous differences
between a professional thief, and a man who has been guilty of assault
and battery in a state of intoxication, just as there are between a
ravisher and a political criminal. And anyone who does not take account
of these differences must necessarily limit himself to certain
generalities.

I propose to treat of crimes divided into four categories in accordance
with the motives which led their authors to commit them. Three of these
categories form quite definite units, while the fourth is more
heterogeneous.

The first is composed of crimes that have an economic aim (economic
crimes). The greater part of the so-called crimes against property,
such as theft, embezzlement, etc., belong to this category, but not
all, for malicious mischief, for example, is generally dictated by a
desire for vengeance. On the other hand some crimes against the person,
like procuration, the object of which is economic and not sexual,
belong here. As for crimes against the state, we must add
counterfeiting to this category. Then there are other crimes that may
be committed either for economic or non-economic reasons; for example,
murder (for the purpose of robbery or for revenge), perjury (for the
profit of winning a civil suit, or to prevent the conviction of a
friend), arson (to get the insurance money, or for revenge), etc.

It may be urged here that, notwithstanding the similarity of their
motives the crimes of any class still present many differences. This is
true in part, and I have accordingly subdivided them. But on the other
hand these differences are not very great from the standpoint of
criminal sociology. For the jurist the difference between
counterfeiting bank-notes, burning a house to get the insurance, and
procuration is very important; but for sociology it is much less so. A
man who knows how to make counterfeit bank-notes, will commit this
crime, whenever he wishes for any reason to enrich himself in a
dishonest fashion, but he will become neither an incendiary nor a
procurer. A former prostitute, on the contrary, will not think of
making bank-notes, but will become a procuress. The kind of economic
crime committed by the person who has a mind to commit such a crime,
depends principally upon chance (occupation etc.).

The second category includes sexual crimes, and the fourth political
crimes—two categories quite distinct therefore.

The other misdemeanors and crimes form the third category, and are more
or less heterogeneous. The principal motive of these crimes is
vengeance. Among them are insults, malicious mischief, assaults,
homicide, etc. Other motives are: the fear of shame (infanticide,
which, however, may also be committed for economic reasons); then fear
of falling into the hands of justice (perjury, rebellion); and some
others beside. [814]

Finally, to give a picture of the quantitative proportions of the
principal crimes, I add here some figures upon criminality in some of
the countries of Europe. These figures may at the same time serve to
show to those who are not acquainted with criminal statistics, how
regular a course crime has from one year to another.

It is crimes of vengeance, therefore, which form the largest group,
then come economic crimes, and then sexual and political crimes, both
with low figures. If we do not count the very minor offense of insult
in the third group, the first and third groups will be nearly of the
same size. There are, then, almost no political crimes in England. As
in Germany, sexual crimes are very rare, and it is the economic crimes
and those committed out of revenge, etc., that are the most important.
The latter preponderate even more in England than in Germany.


Germany, 1896–1900. [815]

==============================+===================================================================
                              |   Number of Persons Convicted of the Following
                              |                    Crimes in
        Crimes.               +---------+---------+---------+---------+---------+-----------------
                              |         |         |         |         |         |   1896-1900
                              |         |         |         |         |         |    Average.
                              |  1896.  |  1897.  |  1898.  |  1899.  |  1900.  |---------+-------
                              |         |         |         |         |         |Absolute |
                              |         |         |         |         |         | Number. |  %
------------------------------+---------+---------+---------+---------+---------+---------+-------
Theft and embezzlement        | 109,545 | 112,591 | 116,977 | 113,159 | 114,831 | 113,420 | 29.96
Receiving stolen goods and    |         |         |         |         |         |         |
  being accessory after the   |         |         |         |         |         |         |
  fact in general             |   8,164 |  7,922  |   8,490 |   8,124 |   8,068 |   8,153 |  2.15
Procuration, etc.             |   2,816 |  2,671  |   2,765 |   2,622 |   2,648 |   2,711 |  0.72
Counterfeiting                |     234 |    166  |     203 |     212 |     186 |     200 |  0.05
Perjury                       |   1,523 |  1,450  |   1,478 |   1,316 |   1,198 |   1,393 |  0.37
Criminal breach of trust and  |         |         |         |         |         |         |
  obtaining money under false |         |         |         |         |         |         |
  pretenses                   |  28,649 | 25,169  |  26,546 |  26,580 |  26,079 |  25,604 |  6.76
Forgery                       |   4,761 |  5,068  |   5,185 |   5,479 |   5,231 |   5,144 |  1.36
Robbery and extortion         |   1,048 |    995  |   1,114 |   1,114 |   1,009 |   1,056 |  0.28
Fraudulent bankruptcy         |     931 |    924  |     871 |     952 |     905 |     916 |  0.24
Total of economic crimes      |     --  |    --   |    --   |     --  |    --   |    --   | 41.89
Bigamy                        |      76 |     72  |      64 |      70 |      64 |      69 |  0.02
Incest                        |     462 |    381  |     397 |     411 |     448 |     419 |  0.11
Rape, etc.                    |   4,483 |  4,182  |   4,507 |   4,597 |   4,762 |   4,506 |  1.19
Total of sexual crimes        |     --  |    --   |     --  |     --  |     --  |     --  |  1.32
Insults                       |  53,968 | 54,143  |  55,988 |  55,514 |  52,883 |  54,499 | 14.39
Malicious mischief            |  17,485 | 17,486  |  18,213 |  18,858 |  18,261 |  18,060 |  4.77
Arson                         |     479 |    468  |     501 |     519 |     472 |     487 |  0.13
Assaults                      | 116,613 |117,864  | 122,561 | 126,490 | 124,646 | 121,632 | 32.12
Rebellion                     |  18,377 | 18,484  |  17,968 |  19,817 |  17,951 |  18,393 |  4.86
Homicide                      |   1,511 |  1,562  |   1,468 |   1,542 |   1,580 |   1,532 |  0.40
Total of crimes of vengeance, |         |         |         |         |         |         |
  etc.                        |     --  |    --   |    --   |    --   |    --   |     --  | 56.67
Political crimes              |     561 |    428  |     466 |     416 |     305 |     435 |  0.12
                              |         |         |         |         |         +---------+------
    General total             |     --  |    --   |    --   |    --   |    --   | 378,629 |100.00
==============================+=========+=========+=========+=========+=========+=========+======


England, 1881–1900.

=============================+=======================================================
                             |    Number Arraigned for Each of the Crimes Given:
                             +-------------------------------------+-----------------
          Crimes.            |                                     |    1881-1900
                             |           Annual Averages.          |     Average.
                             +--------+--------+--------+----------+---------+-------
                             |1881-85.|1886-90.|1891-95.|1896-1900.|Absolute |
                             |        |        |        |          | Number. |   %
 ----------------------------+--------+--------+--------+----------+---------+-------
Theft (of every kind)        | 57,373 | 52,573 | 50,432 |  45,960  | 51,584  | 32.92
Embezzlement                 |  1,475 |  1,345 |  1,335 |   1,387  |  1,385  |  0.88
Receiving stolen goods       |  1,302 |  1,239 |  1,348 |   1,241  |  1,282  |  0.82
Burglary                     |  1,464 |  1,530 |  1,665 |   1,630  |  1,572  |  1.00
Robbery and extortion        |    320 |    322 |    310 |     278  |    307  |  0.20
Fraud                        |  1,054 |    965 |    997 |     870  |    971  |  0.62
Counterfeiting, etc.         |    534 |    410 |    365 |     309  |    402  |  0.26
Perjury                      |    100 |     85 |     78 |      77  |     85  |  0.05
Fraudulent bankruptcy        |     49 |     41 |     43 |      35  |     42  |  0.03
Total of economic crimes     |    --  |    --  |    --  |     --   |    --   | 36.78
Bigamy                       |    116 |     99 |    104 |     103  |    105  |  0.07
Indecent assault upon girls  |        |        |        |          |         |
  under 16                   |    --  |    305 |    258 |     236  |    249  |  0.16
Rape, etc. upon adults       |    647 |    639 |    636 |     595  |    629  |  0.40
Total of sexual crimes       |    --  |    --  |    --  |     --   |    --   |  0.63
Malicious mischief           | 21,779 | 19,646 | 18,484 |  17,470  | 19,594  | 12.51
Arson                        |    155 |    133 |    117 |     104  |    127  |  0.08
Assaults                     | 72,707 | 66,020 | 63,601 |  59,611  | 65,484  | 41.80
Assaults upon officers       |    322 |    285 |    291 |     278  |    294  |  0.19
Homicide (including attempted|        |        |        |          |         |
  homicide)                  | 13,223 | 11,850 | 12,626 |  12,524  | 12,555  |  8.01
Total of crimes of vengeance |    --  |    --  |    --  |     --   |    --   | 62.59
Political crimes             |      4 |      0 |      0 |       0  |      1  |  0.00
                             |        |        |        |          +---------+-------
    General total            |    --  |    --  |    --  |     --   |156,668  |100.00
=============================+========+========+========+==========+=========+=======


France, 1881–1900. [817]

=====================+===========================================================
                     |              Number Arraigned for Each Crime.
                     +-------------------------------------------+---------------
Crimes.              |                                           |    1881-1900
                     |             Annual Averages.              |    Averages.
                     +---------------------+----------+----------+--------+------
                     |1881-1885.|1886-1890.|1891-1895.|1896-1900.|Average |   %
                     |          |          |          |          |Number. |
---------------------+----------+----------+----------+----------+--------+------
Vagrancy             |  15,629  |  19,050  |  18,449  |  14,148  | 16,819 | 11.17
Mendicity            |   9,421  |  14,625  |  14,707  |  11,274  | 12,506 |  8.30
Aggravated theft     |   1,668  |   1,715  |   1,517  |   1,308  |  1,552 |  1.03
Simple theft         |  44,596  |  47,941  |  49,145  |  43,750  | 46,358 | 30.78
Counterfeiting       |      98  |     141  |     134  |     111  |    121 |  0.08
Procuration          |     341  |     361  |     406  |     304  |    353 |  0.23
Forgery              |     355  |     304  |     237  |     224  |    280 |  0.19
Obtaining money      |          |          |          |          |        |
  under false        |          |          |          |          |        |
  pretenses          |   4,210  |   4,422  |   3,898  |   3,496  |  4,006 |  2.66
Breach of trust      |   4,106  |   4,495  |   4,488  |   4,834  |  4,480 |  2.98
Commercial frauds    |   3,221  |   3,015  |   2,607  |   2,931  |  2,941 |  1.95
Fraudulent           |          |          |          |          |        |
  bankruptcy         |      86  |      63  |      63  |      44  |     64 |  0.04
Simple bankruptcy    |     934  |     967  |     802  |     860  |    890 |  0.59
Perjury              |     126  |     126  |     151  |     136  |    134 |  0.09
Total of economic    |          |          |          |          |        |
  crimes             |      --  |      --  |      --  |      --  |     -- | 60.09
Bigamy               |       6  |       6  |       8  |       8  |      7 |  0.00
Adultery             |   1,038  |   1,758  |   1,838  |   2,212  |  1,711 |  1.14
Rape and indecent    |          |          |          |          |        |
  assault upon       |          |          |          |          |        |
  adults             |     103  |      76  |      95  |      70  |     86 |  0.06
Rape and indecent    |          |          |          |          |        |
  assault upon       |          |          |          |          |        |
  children           |     717  |     592  |     584  |     452  |    586 |  0.39
Total of sexual      |          |          |          |          |        |
  crimes             |      --  |      --  |      --  |      --  |     -- |  1.59
Defamation and       |          |          |          |          |        |
  insults            |   3,513  |   2,918  |   2,940  |   2,877  |  3,062 |  2.03
Insults to officials |  13,492  |  13,728  |  15,258  |  13,450  | 13,982 |  9.28
Malicious mischief   |   3,291  |   4,876  |   4,530  |   4,382  |  4,269 |  2.84
Arson                |     207  |     245  |     263  |     213  |    252 |  0.17
Serious assaults     |     187  |     155  |     178  |     183  |    175 |  0.12
Intentional assaults |  27,768  |  28,971  |  33,443  |  36,158  | 31,585 | 20.97
Violence to officials|   3,721  |   3,746  |   3,926  |   3,502  |  3,723 |  2.47
Homicide             |     518  |     506  |     515  |     461  |    500 |  0.33
Infanticide          |     191  |     191  |     157  |     118  |    164 |  0.11
Total of crimes of   |          |          |          |          |        |
  vengeance, etc.    |      --  |      --  |      --  |      --  |     -- | 38.32
Political crimes     |       4  |       1  |       2  |       0  |      1 |  0.00
                     |          |          |          |          +--------+-----
    General total    |      --  |      --  |      --  |      --  |150,607 |100.00
=====================+==========+==========+==========+==========+========+======


Here, also, the political crimes and the sexual offenses show the
smallest figures. The economic crimes exceed considerably those
committed out of revenge, etc., a fact to be accounted for in great
part by the inclusion of vagrancy and mendicity among the economic
crimes. These tables hardly lend themselves to international
comparison, since certain acts are regarded as misdemeanors in one
country, and as contraventions in another.


Italy, 1891–1895. [818]

===============================+==================================================
                               |         Number Convicted of Each Crime.
                               +------+------+------+------+------+---------------
                               |      |      |      |      |      |    Average
           Crimes.             |      |      |      |      |      |   1891-1895.
                               |      |      |      |      |      +--------+------
                               | 1891.| 1892.| 1893.| 1894.| 1895.|Absolute|
                               |      |      |      |      |      |Numbers.|   %
-------------------------------+------+------+------+------+------+--------+------
Simple theft                   |44,380|38,750|35,343|37,022|41,875| 39,474 | 29.07
Aggravated theft               |14,512|15,103|15,230|15,238|17,132| 15,441 | 11.37
Fraud (of every kind)          | 6,288| 6,202| 6,446| 6,861| 7,917|  6,742 |  4.97
Counterfeiting, etc.           |    85|    59|    59|    68|    90|     72 |  0.05
Forgery                        |   788|   626|   683|   726|   839|    732 |  0.54
Procuration                    |   182|   188|   185|   162|   267|    196 |  0.15
Robbery, extortion, etc.       |   683|   719|   824|   879|   966|    814 |  0.60
Total of economic crimes       |   -- |   -- |   -- |   -- |   -- |    --  | 46.75
Rape etc.                      |   724|   797|   879|   902| 1,066|    873 |  0.64
Corruption of minors and other |      |      |      |      |      |        |
  offenses against morals and  |      |      |      |      |      |        |
  the order of the family      | 1,036| 1,246| 1,269| 1,373| 1,411|  1,267 |  0.93
Total of sexual crimes         |   -- |   -- |   -- |   -- |   -- |    --  |  1.57
Defamation and insults         | 9,030| 9,957| 9,005|11,247|12,196| 10,287 |  7.58
Malicious mischief             | 5,396| 4,938| 4,493| 5,069| 5,617|  5,102 |  3.76
Arson                          |   213|   156|   197|   210|   197|    194 |  0.14
Minor assaults                 |24,275|27,617|23,740|27,479|28,924| 26,407 | 19.45
Serious assaults               | 6,491| 8,440| 9,124| 8,211| 9,199|  8,293 |  6.11
Threats                        | 4,788| 5,997| 5,875| 6,702| 8,053|  6,283 |  4.63
Violence, insults, etc., to    |      |      |      |      |      |        |
  officials                    |10,293|11,829|11,999|11,835|11,800| 11,551 |  8.51
Homicide                       | 1,686| 1,946| 2,145| 2,035| 2,049|  1,972 |  1.45
Infanticide and abortion       |    60|    59|    54|    64|    81|     63 |  0.05
Total of crimes of vengeance,  |      |      |      |      |      |        |
  etc.                         |   -- |   -- |   -- |   -- |   -- |    --  | 51.68
Crimes against the safety of   |      |      |      |      |      |        |
  the state                    |    11|     9|    10|    10|    12|     10 |  0.00
                               |      |      |      |      |      |--------|------
    General total              |   -- |   -- |   -- |   -- |   -- |135,773 |100.00
===============================+======+======+======+======+======+========+======


The results of the Italian statistics agree in general with those that
have gone before.


Netherlands, 1897–1901. [819]

==========================+=============================================
                          |     Number of Convicts for Each Crime.
                          +-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+---------------
                          |     |     |     |     |     |    Average
         Crimes.          |     |     |     |     |     |  1897-1901.
                          |1897.|1898.|1899.|1900.|1901.+--------+------
                          |     |     |     |     |     |Absolute|  %
                          |     |     |     |     |     |Numbers.|
--------------------------+-----+-----+-----+-----+-----+--------+------
Vagrancy and mendicity    |2,139|2,173|2,209|1,873|1,857|  2,050 | 16.42
Simple theft              |1,685|1,830|1,740|1,544|1,758|  1,711 | 13.71
Aggravated theft          |  936|  919|  761|  837|1,029|    896 | 17.18
Receiving stolen goods    |   95|   69|   88|   82|   98|     86 |  0.69
Embezzlement              |  320|  262|  295|  309|  269|    291 |  2.33
Causing or being accessory|     |     |     |     |     |        |
 to the debauch of a minor|   14|    6|   10|   14|   16|     12 |  0.10
Obtaining money under     |     |     |     |     |     |        |
  false pretenses         |  102|  115|   97|  112|  115|    108 |  0.87
Extortion and blackmail   |    8|   12|    6|    9|    5|      8 |  0.07
Forgery                   |   75|   72|   49|   64|   42|     60 |  0.48
Perjury                   |   29|   18|   15|   22|   18|     20 |  0.16
Fraudulent bankruptcy     |   14|   14|   12|   20|   12|     14 |  0.11
Total of economic crimes  |     |     |     |     |     |        | 42.12
Rape and indecent assault |     |     |     |     |     |        |
  upon adults             |   88|   81|   94|  110|   97|     94 |  0.75
Rape and indecent assault |     |     |     |     |     |        |
  upon children           |   13|    5|   13|    6|   18|     11 |  0.09
Total of sexual crimes    |     |     |     |     |     |        |  0.84
Simple insults            |  356|  319|  330|  288|  291|    316 |  2.53
Insults to officials      |  549|  508|  431|  421|  440|    469 |  3.76
Malicious mischief        |  916|  900|  861|  857|  874|    881 |  7.06
Arson                     |   10|   12|   22|   25|   15|     17 |  0.14
Rebellion, etc.           |1,188|1,091|1,069|1,166|1,112|  1,125 |  9.01
Assaults                  |4,241|4,020|4,101|3,814|3,715|  3,978 | 31.87
Assaults upon officials   |  340|  286|  331|  330|  296|    316 |  2.53
Homicide                  |   16|   16|   12|   14|   19|     15 |  0.12
Infanticide and abortion  |    4|    3|    4|    4|    0|      3 |  0.02
Total of crimes of        |     |     |     |     |     |        |
  vengeance, etc.         |     |     |     |     |     |        | 57.04
Political crimes          |    3|    1|    1|    0|    0|      1 |  0.00
                          |     |     |     |     |     +--------+------
    General total         |     |     |     |     |     | 12,482 |100.00
==========================+=====+=====+=====+=====+=====+========+======


These figures thus confirm in general the results of the preceding
tables. The most frequent crimes are those committed out of revenge
etc. and the economic crimes. The sexual crimes only reach low figures,
and the political crimes are negligible.

We have placed certain crimes, like homicide and arson, in all the
tables, among the crimes of vengeance, etc., although they may also be
committed from an economic motive. The French and Italian criminal
statistics give information upon the frequency of the motives which
lead to these crimes.


France, 1881–1900. [820]

================================+===========================================
                                | Percentage of the Crimes of Homicide and
Presumable Motive of the Crimes.|         Arson due to Each Cause.
                                +----------+----------+----------+----------
                                |1881-1885.|1886-1890.|1891-1895.|1896-1900.
--------------------------------+----------+----------+----------+----------
Cupidity                        |    26    |    28    |    31    |    26
Love, jealousy                  |     2    |     2    |     6    |     3
Adultery                        |     3    |     3    |     2    |     2
Concubinage, debauch            |     6    |     6    |     5    |     8
Hate, revenge                   |    24    |    27    |    28    |    28
Domestic disputes               |    15    |    13    |     9    |    12
Drink-shop quarrels             |     2    |     1    |     1    |     1
Various motives                 |    22    |    20    |    18    |    20
================================+==========+==========+==========+==========


About 28% of the crimes, then, had an economic motive, about 12% had a
sexual motive, and 40% were committed out of revenge.


Italy, 1880–1881. [821]

=======================================+=============================
                                       |Percentage of Crimes of Blood
   Presumable Motive of the Crimes.    |     due to Each Cause.
                                       +--------------+--------------
                                       |    1880.     |    1881.
---------------------------------------+--------------+--------------
Cupidity                               |      9.2     |     9.98
Question of interests                  |      4.2     |     8.76
Love, lawful or unlawful               |      7.5     |     8.76
Family relations and questions of honor|      2.6     |     3.11
Defense of life                        |      4.9     |     3.04
  ,,   ,,  property                    |      1.7     |     1.89
Domestic disputes                      |      3.0     |     4.43
Anger                                  |     30.3     |    23.67
Hate and revenge                       |     26.5     |    28.46
Cruelty                                |      4.1     |     2.72
Drunkenness                            |      3.2     |     4.25
Politics                               |      0.1     |     0.14
Various and unknown motives            |      2.6     |     0.79
=======================================+==============+==============


Finally, it must not be forgotten that certain crimes of a different
kind (leze-majesty and malicious mischief, for example) are sometimes
committed simply that the author of them may get himself imprisoned,
and hence should be classed as economic crimes.

We have now reached the question: how close a connection have the
different crimes with economic conditions? We shall give only a
detailed sketch of the subject; to treat it more fully would require
extensive monographs. We shall limit ourselves to indicating the
general lines.








CHAPTER II.

ECONOMIC CRIMES.


It is necessary to divide these crimes into separate groups.
Notwithstanding their partial similarity they differ too much among
themselves to be treated together. I propose to speak of them under the
four following heads: A. Vagrancy and mendicity; B. Theft, and
analogous crimes; C. Robbery, homicide for economic reasons, etc. (that
is to say, economic crimes committed with violence or directed against
life); D. Fraudulent bankruptcy, adulteration of food, etc. (that is to
say, economic crimes committed almost exclusively by the bourgeoisie,
while those of the first three categories are committed almost
exclusively by the poor). Some crimes, like that of embezzlement,
belong to the second class as well as to the fourth (for example, a
workman’s making off with a bicycle loaned to him, and the embezzlement
of deposits by a bank director).

It seems to me unnecessary to explain this division. It creates four
fairly distinct groups, which contain all the economic crimes. However,
I must point out why I treat vagrancy and mendicity in this way, while
both are generally regarded not as misdemeanors but as contraventions.
[822] Properly speaking they ought not, therefore, to appear in a work
on criminality, but the following are the reasons why they nevertheless
find a place here; first, they are the most important and the most
common contraventions; second, there is a very close relation between
vagrancy on the one hand, and criminality properly speaking on the
other. This relation has been shown by many authors. As Professor Prins
says in his “Criminalité et répression”, vagrancy and mendicity are the
novitiate of crime. I will only recall here the opinions of two
writers, Josiah Flynt and E. Sichart. The former, the author of
“Tramping with Tramps”, has given up a part of his life to tramping for
some years in America, Germany, and in other countries, in order to
familiarize himself with the vagrant and the criminal; his conclusions
accordingly have great value. He is of the opinion that the vagrants
endowed with great energy become professional criminals, to fall again
into vagrancy as soon as their physical and mental forces decline so as
no longer to permit them to carry on their criminal trade with success.
[823]

Sichart, the prison director, having examined 3,181 convicts, found
that 28% of them had been convicted before for vagrancy, and 27% for
mendicity—55% in all. [824] These figures differed according to the
kind of criminal. There were to


    each 100 thieves            44.2   vagrants,   35.0   mendicants
     ,,  100 swindlers          11.1      ,,       20.2       ,,
     ,,  100 sexual offenders   14.0      ,,       17.3       ,,
     ,,  100 incendiaries       15.1      ,,       15.5       ,,
     ,,  100 perjurers           4.2      ,,        4.7       ,,


For these reasons, then, it is necessary to treat of vagrancy and
mendicity.




A. Vagrancy and Mendicity.

In examining the etiology of these contraventions, we perceive that
different causes lead to them. We shall treat them successively and
endeavor to find their relation to the economic life.

First. As a first cause of vagrancy and mendicity is the fact that
under capitalism there are always workmen who cannot sell their labor.
The number of these persons increases greatly at the time of a crisis.
When the men out of work have no resource in their family and no longer
receive aid from their union, they are obliged to go from place to
place looking for employment, and if they do not succeed in finding it
must have recourse to begging in order not to die of hunger. Statistics
furnish the proof that the army of vagrants and mendicants is in fact
made up in part of the unemployed who, though they wish to, cannot find
work.

In the first place, vagrancy and mendicity increase in winter (as in
general all economic criminality does), when forced unemployment is at
its height, and needs are most pressing, while they diminish in summer.
The following figures with reference to some of the German states show
these facts.


Grand-Duchy of Baden, 1884–1891. [825]

=========+===================+================
         | Number Convicted  |Number Convicted
 Months. |  of Vagrancy and  | per Diem, the
         |    Mendicity.     | Minimum = 100.
---------+-------------------+----------------
January  |       7,232       |      364
February |       6,315       |      336
March    |       4,816       |      235
April    |       2,945       |      148
May      |       2,743       |      133
June     |       2,475       |      124
July     |       2,540       |      124
August   |       2,410       |      118
September|       1,989       |      100
October  |       2,672       |      130
November |       3,857       |      195
December |       5,310       |      259
=========+===================+================


Hesse, 1899–1900. [826]

==================+===============================
                  | Number Convicted of Vagrancy
    Months.       |      and Mendicity.
                  +----------------+--------------
                  |Absolute Number.|Daily Average.
------------------+----------------+--------------
December-February |      479       |     5.32
March-May         |      334       |     3.63
June-August       |      259       |     2.82
September-November|      531       |     3.64
==================+================+==============


The following figures confirm those that have preceded.


Saxony, 1882–1887. [827]

======+==================================================================================
      |                  Number Convicted of Vagrancy and Mendicity.
      +-------------------++-------------------++-------------------++-------------------
      |  First Quarter.   ||  Second Quarter.  ||  Third Quarter.   ||  Fourth Quarter.
Years.+--------+----------++--------+----------++--------+----------++--------+----------
      |        |Percentage||        |Percentage||        |Percentage||        |Percentage
      |Absolute|    of    ||Absolute|    of    ||Absolute|    of    ||Absolute|    of
      |Numbers.|  Annual  ||Numbers.|  Annual  ||Numbers.|  Annual  ||Numbers.|  Annual
      |        |  Total.  ||        |  Total.  ||        |  Total.  ||        |  Total.
------+--------+----------++--------+----------++--------+----------++--------+----------
 1882 |  6,752 |   36.1   || 4,220  |   22.6   || 3,181  |   17.0   || 4,546  |   24.3
 1883 |  6,619 |   36.6   || 3,934  |   21.7   || 2,957  |   16.5   || 4,567  |   25.2
 1884 |  6,641 |   37.6   || 3,855  |   21.8   || 2,721  |   15.5   || 4,462  |   25.2
 1885 |  6,555 |   35.9   || 3,424  |   18.7   || 2,872  |   15.7   || 5,440  |   29.7
 1886 |  7,139 |   41.5   || 3,507  |   20.4   || 2,654  |   15.4   || 3,900  |   22.7
 1887 |  5,787 |   39.1   || 3,344  |   22.6   || 2,251  |   15.2   || 3,411  |   23.1
======+========+==========++========+==========++========+==========++========+==========


These statistics justify the conclusion drawn by Ostwald, from whom I
have taken the figures for Hesse. This author is a competent witness,
as he tramped as a vagrant for some time himself. He says: “These
figures directly contradict the statement that antipathy to regular
work forms the principal source of vagrancy and mendicity; especially
as there is no inclination to frequent the highways in winter. It is
the need that comes of unemployment that drives out these poorest of
the poor; and whoever wishes to do away with vagrancy must make the
economic existence of the working people secure, instead of visiting
the victims of poverty with Draconian punishments.” [828]

Another proof in support of the assertion that unemployment is a cause
of mendicity and vagrancy, is to be found in the fact that the figures
for vagrancy and mendicity rise considerably at the time of economic
crises. The same phenomenon occurs more or less when the price of grain
or bread goes up. Then those whose labor is only poorly paid must find
some means of increasing their resources; and further when bread is
dear less of other things can be bought, which brings about a decrease
in production and consequently an increase in forced idleness.

In the first part of this work I have mentioned authors who have shown
for different countries that the curve of vagrancy rises or falls as
economic conditions become worse or better. I add here the data that I
have been able to find elsewhere.


England, 1856–1896. [829]

=======+========================++=======+========================
       |  Vagrants Convicted.   ||       |  Vagrants Convicted.
Years. +--------+---------------++Years. +--------+---------------
       |Absolute| To 100,000 of ||       |Absolute| To 100,000 of
       |Numbers.|the Population.||       |Numbers.|the Population.
-------+--------+---------------++-------+--------+---------------
1856-57| 19,270 |      99.7     ||1876-77| 22,475 |      90.9
1857-58| 21,473 |     109.9     ||1877-78| 23,662 |      94.5
1858-59| 16,401 |      83.0     ||1878-79| 25,790 |     101.6
1859-60| 16,374 |      82.2     ||1879-80| 30,323 |     117.5
1860-61| 17,496 |      86.9     ||1880-81| 28,088 |     107.8
1861-62| 20,636 |     101.4     ||1881-82| 28,729 |     109.0
1862-63| 21,758 |     105.8     ||1882-83| 28,825 |     108.2
1863-64| 20,414 |      97.7     ||1883-84| 28,370 |     105.3
1864-65| 20,307 |      96.7     ||1884-85| 27,467 |     100.9
1865-66| 19,607 |      91.8     ||1885-86| 26,546 |      96.4
1866-67| 21,071 |      97.5     ||1886-87| 28,690 |     103.0
1867-68| 24,125 |     110.2     ||1887-88| 31,380 |     111.5
1868-69| 29,890 |     134.8     ||1888-89| 28,032 |      98.5
1869-70| 28,367 |     126.3     ||1889-90| 25,001 |      86.5
1870-71| 24,902 |     109.4     ||1890-91| 22,577 |      77.6
1871-72| 21,325 |      92.4     ||1891-92| 23,623 |      80.3
1872-73| 19,433 |      83.2     ||1893   | 24,830 |      83.3
1873-74| 19,582 |      82.8     ||1894   | 25,676 |      85.4
1874-75| 17,692 |      73.5     ||1895   | 23,524 |      77.4
1875-76| 19,841 |      81.4     ||1896   | 25,188 |      81.9
=======+========+===============++=======+========+===============


When we compare these figures with the course of economic events, we
find the following: 1856 was a bad year economically, and 1857 and 1858
were still worse; in 1859 the situation improved, to become worse again
in 1860, 1861, and 1862. The improvement was restored in 1863, while
1864 and 1865 were fair; in 1866, 1867, and 1868 conditions became
worse again, but improved from 1869 to 1874. With 1875 things took a
turn for the worse, and this condition lasted till 1879, when there was
a slight improvement; 1880, 1881, and 1882 were fair, while 1883 was a
passably good year. In 1884 a period of depression began, which lasted
till 1888, following which there was an improvement until 1891, with
the succeeding years up to 1894 not so good. In 1895 things once more
took a turn for the better. [830]


With some exceptions the curve of vagrancy rises and falls, then,
pretty much as the economic situation grows worse or improves.


Bavaria, 1835–1861.

Dr. G. Mayr has proved that during the period named there was a close
connection between the movement of the price of grain and the figures
for vagrancy. (See p. 42 of this work.) [831]


Flanders, 1839–1848.

Ducpetiaux had given proofs of the same correlation. (See pp. 33–37.)


France, 1840–1886.

Lafargue has proved that vagrancy and mendicity follow in general the
curve for bankruptcies. (See p. 235.) [832]


Hesse, 1895–1900. [833]

======+====================================================
      |Number of those Convicted of Vagrancy and Mendicity.
Years.+-------------------+--------------------------------
      | Absolute Figures. | To 100,000 of the Population.
------+-------------------+--------------------------------
 1895 |       2,583       |             21.96
 1896 |       2,244       |             21.49
 1897 |       1,968       |             18.49
 1898 |       1,658       |             15.60
 1899 |       1,267       |             11.82
 1900 |       1,442       |             12.95
======+===================+================================


In this period the economic depression in Germany, dating from about
1890, began to decrease.


Netherlands, 1860–1891.

Since there are no statistical investigations of the course of vagrancy
and mendicity I have composed the following chart from the official
data.


[Illustration: I. Number Convicted of Vagrancy and Mendicity to 100,000
of the Population. II. Price of Bread (in Centimes per Kilogram).]


A comparison of the two curves shows that there is a parallelism,
tolerably constant up to 1869. After this it ceases with some
exceptions. The great fall in the price of bread, beginning with 1878
(as a consequence of the agrarian crisis), even coincides with a
considerable increase in vagrancy and mendicity. To explain this we
must consult the statistics of failures. These show that the great
increase of vagrancy and mendicity coincide with an equally great
increase in the number of bankruptcies, beginning in 1875 and lasting
to 1882. For the following years there is no relation between the two
phenomena apparent.


Prussia, 1854–1870.

I have composed the following table by means of the data given by
Starke in his “Verbrechen und Verbrecher in Preussen” (pp. 55 and 115).


======+=================+===============================
      |  Number of New  |Price of 50 Kilograms in Marks.
Years.|Cases of Vagrancy+---------+---------+-----------
      | and Mendicity.  |  Wheat. |   Rye.  | Potatoes.
------+-----------------+---------+---------+-----------
 1854 |     14,619      |  12.90  |  10.40  |   3.17
 1855 |     16,665      |  14.21  |  11.45  |   3.37
 1856 |     20,414      |  13.51  |  10.64  |   3.13
 1857 |     15,801      |  10.18  |   6.87  |   2.18
 1858 |     15,318      |   9.08  |   6.38  |   1.91
 1859 |     16,978      |   8.93  |   6.79  |   1.98
 1860 |     16,320      |  10.48  |   7.65  |   2.41
 1861 |     14,239      |  11.04  |   7.71  |   2.79
 1862 |     12,846      |  10.68  |   7.97  |   2.47
 1863 |     11,840      |   9.18  |   6.78  |   2.04
 1864 |     12,026      |   7.95  |   5.69  |   2.10
 1865 |     11,640      |   8.13  |   6.24  |   2.03
 1866 |     13,664      |   9.80  |   7.30  |   2.05
 1867 |     15,339      |  12.89  |   9.87  |   2.95
 1868 |     14,801      |  12.48  |   9.84  |   2.62
 1869 |     15,091      |   9.70  |   8.08  |   2.16
 1870 |     13,320      |  11.04  |   7.78  |   2.58
======+=================+=========+=========+===========


Although the curves of the price of foodstuffs and of vagrancy do not
exactly conform, the influence of the price is none the less evident.
The three periods of high prices (1854–56, 1860–62, and 1867–68)
coincide with high figures for vagrancy and mendicity. (It is to be
noted that the effect of an economic depression does not always make
itself felt the following year.)


Kingdom of Saxony, 1889–1892.

Bebel showed that mendicity increased greatly in the above period (a
crisis of great intensity). (See pp. 228–229 of this work.) [834]



I am of the opinion that these data show sufficiently that the increase
or diminution of vagrancy and mendicity are regulated by the economic
situation; in other words, that a great many persons become guilty of
these contraventions not because they are not willing to work, but
entirely as a consequence of an unfavorable economic environment. There
are some exceptions to this rule. Above (pp. 89–90) I have shown that
these exceptions do not weaken the general conclusion; the unfavorable
influence of the economic depression may be neutralized by
counter-determinants. It must further be remarked especially with
regard to vagrancy and mendicity, that the application of the laws
relative to these offenses is quite arbitrary, and it happens at the
time of a crisis that the courts do not punish those who are guilty of
them, whence it follows that the statistics do not give an accurate
picture of the reality. [835]

It is impossible to fix exactly how far the influence of economic
depressions extends; in other words, we cannot determine the number of
vagrants and mendicants who become such directly through forced
idleness. When it is necessary to record a certain number of
convictions for vagrancy and mendicity, although the economic
conditions are most favorable, we shall not even then be able to say
that this proves that the convictions fell only upon persons who could
have found work, but did not wish it.

Under the present economic system unemployment is chronic, that is to
say, it is present even in times of economic prosperity. Consequently
it has not been proved that those who are convicted during these
periods are necessarily lazy and do not want to work. The only figure
that I have been able to find with regard to the importance of this
cause of vagrancy and mendicity is this: that in Germany, out of a
total of 200,000 mendicants, there are 80,000 (40%) who are really in
search of work. [836] This figure being only approximate, its
significance is not great.

Before leaving the subject of this cause, we must say something with
regard to the objection that the workers who, on account of a long
period of unemployment, fall finally into vagrancy, are inferior to the
average, generally do not know a trade, and are often addicted to
alcohol; and that consequently in this case an individual factor plays
a rôle beside the economic factor.

It is true that most of the vagrants and mendicants do not know a
trade, nor are worth much as workmen. In his study Dr. Bonhoeffer says
that 55.4% of the vagrants and mendicants examined by him had not
learned a trade, or had learned it insufficiently. [837] This author
also shows (we shall return to this later) that a great proportion of
these people are also physically inferior to the average. This
inferiority is in part not the cause but the effect of the conditions
under which they have been living (insufficient food, etc.), [838] and
in part congenital weakness.

However, supposing that each of these individuals knew a trade,
supposing also that they were all robust and healthy and in a condition
to work regularly, would there then be fewer persons without work than
there are now? The answer to this question must be negative. Even if
every workman knew a trade, this fact would not increase the demand for
skilled workmen. At any given time the labor market demands only a
certain number of skilled workmen, and a certain other number of
unskilled laborers; the number of unskilled laborers available has no
influence. The same thing is true as to fitness for work; if all the
workmen had the same energy, the same zeal, etc., this would not
increase the demand for workmen; this demand is regulated by other
factors.

In my opinion it cannot be a question of individual causes; individual
differences explain partially who remain without work, and so become
vagrants; but it is the economic system which causes the existence of
persons without work. Vagrancy and mendicity would be no less extensive
even if all the workers knew a trade and were equal in zeal and energy.

In the second place the world of vagrants and mendicants is composed of
people too old to work, or more or less incapable of working, from
physical or psychical causes, so that they are no longer employed. So
far as I know the data concerning the age of vagrants and mendicants
are not numerous; I can cite those that follow.


England, 1894–1900. [839]

=======+==========+================================
       |          |Of Whom there were of the Age of
       |Number of +----------------+---------------
Years. |Mendicants| 50 to 60 years.|    Over 60.
       |Convicted.+----------+-----+----------+----
       |          | Absolute |     | Absolute |
       |          | Numbers. |  %  | Numbers. |  %
-------+----------+----------+-----+----------+----
  1894 |   13,021 |  1,638   | 12  |  1,916   | 14
  1895 |   10,497 |  1,387   | 13  |  1,490   | 14
  1896 |   11,839 |  1,512   | 12  |  1,801   | 15
  1897 |   10,735 |  1,338   | 12  |  1,701   | 15
  1898 |   11,047 |  1,540   | 13  |  1,838   | 16
  1899 |    9,308 |  1,374   | 14  |  1,667   | 17
  1900 |    8,402 |  1,253   | 14  |  1,690   | 20
=======+==========+==========+=====+==========+====


Netherlands, 1896–1901. [840]

======+===========+================================
      | Number of |Of Whom there were of the Age of
      |  Persons  +----------------+---------------
Years.| Convicted | 50 to 60 years.|    Over 60.
      |of Vagrancy+----------+-----+----------+----
      |   and     | Absolute |     | Absolute |
      |Mendicity. | Numbers. |  %  | Numbers. |  %
------+-----------+----------+-----+----------+----
 1896 |   2,181   |    541   | 24  |   273    | 12
 1897 |   2,139   |    529   | 25  |   278    | 13
 1898 |   2,173   |    534   | 24  |   291    | 13
 1899 |   2,215   |    564   | 25  |   285    | 12
 1901 |   1,857   |    491   | 26  |   257    | 13
===================================================


Russia, 1897.

In the work of Löwenstimm already cited we find mentioned the fact that
out of a total of 7,916 mendicants arrested in St. Petersburg, 1,185
(14.9%) were between 50 and 60 years of age, and 982 (12.4%) over 60.
[841]

As has been said, a certain number of vagrants are weak or sickly, and
consequently are nearly or quite unable to work. In “Les habitués des
prisons de Paris”, Dr. Laurent gives the following description of some
vagrants observed by him, true types of this kind of individual. “I
have known at the Santé in recent years an individual who has passed
almost the whole of his life in prison, who was born and lived in
misery. A natural child, his mother received him as a mistake and a
burden and tried to destroy herself and him. Later, convulsions twisted
him upon a hospital bed, and he has remained half-paralyzed. So far
from knowing how to read or write he can hardly see clearly, for an
opaque film covers his left eye. He has undergone more than twenty
sentences for mendicity and vagrancy, and he is still only 37 years
old. He leaves prison only to enter it again. So he complains bitterly
and blames the judicial authorities, who, instead of placing him in an
asylum, where he belongs, cast him into prison, because, says he, the
food does not cost so much.

“An individual 29 years old, the son of a drunkard and a consumptive,
has already been seven times sentenced for mendicity. He has been
half-paralyzed since he was 13 months old and can walk only with
crutches. Epileptic in addition, he drifts from prison to prison.

“These facts are very common, and it is impossible to estimate how many
of these poor devils live in the prisons, which are a kind of refuge
for them. Lately I saw a blind man who had been arrested for mendicity
and sentenced to a fortnight in prison.” [842]

The following figures, taken from the work just quoted, inform us as to
the number of such individuals.


Breslau.

===============================+=========+======
Physical and Mental Condition. |Absolute |
                               |Numbers. |  %
-------------------------------+---------+------
Physical condition weak        |   337   |  91
Incapable of military service  |         |
  from physical weakness       |   236   |  64
Mental anomalies               |   322   |  87
Epilepsy                       |    43   |  11
Imbecility                     |    86   |  23
  Total number examined        |   369   | 100
================================================


Here it must be noted that in the years 1896–97 there were on the
average only 9% of the conscripts of Silesia who were incapable of
military service.

The other figures that are known agree with the ones I have just cited.
Dr. Kurella found 20% to 30% of imbeciles or epileptics among the
vagrants. [843] Dr. Mendel also found a great number of psychic
abnormalities among the vagrants. [844]

All that I have just said demonstrates sufficiently, I believe, that
the cause named above plays a considerable rôle in the etiology of
mendicity and vagrancy. It is still necessary to give an answer to the
question: do all the individuals who fall under the unfavorable
conditions named under one and two, become vagrants or mendicants? It
is evident that the answer must be negative. Three expedients offer
themselves to one who has fallen into the blackest poverty; mendicity,
theft, and suicide. It is partly chance (opportunity etc.), and partly
the individual predisposition which fixes what anyone under the
conditions named will become, whether a mendicant or a thief. Generally
those who have still some intelligence and energy become thieves, the
rest vagrants. [845] The third expedient, suicide, also is frequently
met with among the lower proletariat. [846] Those who have recourse to
it are either those who have known better conditions and find that the
miserable existence that mendicity procures is not worth the trouble of
living, or those who have lost all energy. Sometimes persons commit
suicide to escape the shame of begging or stealing. These have been
called “the heroes of virtue”; but, considered from another point of
view, they may also be called the “victims of vice”, the vice of
others, of course. These have been born with a very strong moral
disposition and have lived in an environment where this disposition has
been developed. These cases prove the degree of intensity that the
social sentiments can attain; they are stronger than the fundamental
desire to live, although those whom these “heroes” are unwilling to
injure, reject these sentiments, by abandoning their fellows who find
themselves in want.

Third. A third category of mendicants and vagrants is made up of
children and young people. Let us see what relation there is between
this fact and the economic and social environment. All those who have
taken up this subject are agreed that a great proportion of the
children are systematically taught to beg by their parents. Whatever
may be the cause for which the parents act thus, these children are
entirely the victims of the detestable atmosphere in which they are
forced to live. Brought up in a wholesome environment they would become
neither mendicants nor vagrants. [847]

Another part of the vagrant body is made up of children who are either
illegitimate or orphans, or deserted by their parents, or forced by bad
treatment to run away from home. Tomel and Rollet mention the following
typical case. A girl of 16 was charged with vagrancy, and made this
heart-rending statement of her case before the tribunal: “I went on
Friday to find the police commissioner of the ward; I told him that I
had been without a lodging place for 15 days, and that I had not eaten
for 48 hours. I was employed at the house of a wine merchant, who, when
my mother died three years ago, took me as a servant (at 13 years of
age) at two sous a day as wages. But my employer failed, his shop was
closed, and I had to go out and wander in search of work without
finding anything. My father, sentenced to hard labor for life, died in
New Caledonia. I have no longer any mother, and since I did not wish to
imitate my grown-up sister, who leads a bad life, I preferred to get
myself arrested.” [848]

It is difficult to tell how many of these children there are. The only
figures that I know of are the following.


Italy, 1885–1889. [849]

Among the minors sent to a house of correction for vagrancy there were


=====================================+=========+======
      Divisions.                     |Absolute |
                                     |Numbers. |  %
-------------------------------------+---------+------
Illegitimate children                |    91   |  8.0
Orphans                              |   498   | 43.8
Children whose parents were in prison|    25   |  2.2
Other children                       |   524   | 46.0
                                     +---------+------
    Total                            | 1,138   |100.0
=====================================+=========+======


We must now speak of another kind of vagrant and mendicant, those whom
some criminologists have called born-vagabonds; children who run away
from home to meet with adventures and to see something more than the
neighborhood where they live. It makes little difference to us here
whence comes this desire; everyone, especially every child, has it more
or less (who is there who does not love to travel?) and there are those
in whom it is very strong. “Who among us,” say Tomel and Rollet, “at
certain moments of existence, does not feel the desire to break with
social conventions, or more simply, to break through the circle of his
horizon, in order to depart in search of the unknown? Put money in the
pocket of the tramp and you make a tourist. The sportsman and the
delinquent are separated only by the thickness of some hundred-sou
pieces.” [850]

These authors have hit the truth of the matter. Such children are
called born-vagabonds, but then we meet thousands of born-vagabonds who
have never become vagabonds in reality. The children who have a great
love of adventure are found in all classes of society, but only those
who come from among the poor become vagrants. It is in poverty then
that we find the “causa efficiens”; the same inclination that brings
poor children to prison, would perhaps lead them to a post of honor if
they had lived in better surroundings. There are people of all kinds
among criminals, and it cannot be denied that the majority of them are
inferior in every way. But this does not apply to this class of little
vagrants. Those who, as a consequence of years of experience, have a
right to speak, are agreed that such children can be made useful
members of society, if they are rationally guided. [851] They are bold
and energetic lads. Could it be believed that all the boys who, in
1889, came on foot to Paris from all parts of France to see the Eiffel
tower (there were some of them under seven years of age) were not brave
and energetic? Brought up in another environment they would have become
sailors or explorers, or would have undertaken long journeys as
tourists—while now they get into prison, to descend later lower and
lower. [852]

Fourth. Finally, the fourth category of vagrants and mendicants. This
consists of those not included in the other three classes of people who
are physically in a condition to work and who have opportunity to do
so, but are not willing to work. It is hard to determine with certainty
how large a part of the army of vagrants and mendicants they make up.
But it seems to me certain that the facts given above prove that they
are not as numerous as some authors and many other people believe.
Besides, how is it that the philanthropic institutions where everyone
admitted has to work, are always full, if it is true that most vagrants
are persons who are not willing to work?

The vagrants of this class are then lazy persons, unwilling to work,
but living at the expense of others, and consequently parasites. It is
with reason that many authors have blamed such persons (though, as Dr.
Colajanni says, justice would require that we should include all
do-nothings, and not the poor only). But this does not advance the
cause of sociology; her task is to find the causes of the phenomenon.

It is incontestable that the zeal and energy, evidenced by modern
peoples in their work, are not innate but acquired. All sound
individuals have, not in the same measure, it is true, an innate
tendency to exercise their muscles and their intellectual faculties,
but without external causes this inclination does not go very far. The
primitive peoples work no more than is necessary to provide for their
very moderate needs. They find people laughable who work more than is
strictly necessary. [853] The enormous change which took place in the
method of production little by little induced men to produce a greater
and greater amount of work; on the one hand were the slaves, forced to
labor hard, and on the other hand the property owners driven to work by
the desire of profit. In our present society the case is almost the
same; the great mass are forced to work by fear of poverty, the smaller
number by the desire for gain. And then the great majority of men have
been accustomed to work from infancy; much work is done from necessity,
but much from habit, which causes a feeling of uneasiness when one
cannot work.

The first reason why there are people who do not want to work, is that
they have not been accustomed to it from childhood. In general
children, like primitive people, who are analogous to them in many
ways, show little zeal for work. It is necessary to train them for a
fairly long time before they set themselves to work assiduously. What
will all those children whose parents have neglected them, or who have
even taught them to beg, turn into when they are grown up, if not into
vagrants and mendicants? They have never learned any trade, have never
become accustomed to work, have never found any pleasure in it, so that
later in life they will never have any desire to do anything. [854]

Part of those who have not been able to work for a long time go the
same road, they lose the habit of working, become lazy, and in the end
are not willing to do anything any more. [855] These, to be sure, are
the least diligent by nature, but that would not alone send them into
vagrancy if they had always been able to find work.

However, there is still one more thing to be said about the
circumstances which give rise to this class of individuals. In the
first place, the long duration, the monotony, and the disagreeable
features of the work of the proletariat, which, as a consequence is
rather hated than loved. [856] In the second place: the small wages of
a large part of the workers, and the comparatively large amounts that
clever beggars are able to secure. Flynt gives the following data as to
the “earnings” of tramps; in New York, $1 a day; in the Eastern States
generally, from 50 cents to $1 or $2, without counting food; in New
Orleans a skilful beggar can “earn” $1 a day. He estimates that in
Germany the daily receipts of a beggar are from a mark and a half to
four marks, and food; in England most beggars get from 18 pence to two
shillings, though some very clever ones even get as much as 10
shillings. [857] Löwenstimm tells that in Petrograd a skilful beggar
has a daily income of three rubles. [858] Florian and Cavaglieri say
that in Paris a beggar gets four francs, and if he is very clever, even
as much as twenty-five francs, a day. [859]

In some cases, then, it is more profitable, and in all cases more easy,
not to work. In consequence of these facts we read very often that the
public ought not to give to these idlers. But the public cannot
distinguish this class of mendicants from the others. It is certainly
true that professional mendicity would diminish if nothing were given
to mendicants; but on the other hand the great misery among the other
poor would be aggravated still more. And I venture to doubt whether the
advantage thus gained on one side would counterbalance the disadvantage
created on the other.

And these laments upon the subject of the stupidity of the public are
generally accompanied by anathemas upon those who prefer the life of
the parasite to work. No one would naturally be inclined to excuse
these individuals. But it is necessary to look at the question from
both sides. If these people are blamed, blame must be attached also to
a state of society in which honest labor is so poorly paid that begging
is often more lucrative. These individuals are cunning egoists and as
long as society is organized as it is, they are right from their point
of view. To be sure, they have no feeling of honor, they attach no
value to the opinion of others, but the feeling of honor is not innate
but acquired. As the facts show, vagrants generally come from an
environment where there can be no question of a development of moral
qualities. Dr. Bonhoeffer shows, for example, that about 45% of the
vagrants examined by him had been brought up in bad home surroundings
(alcoholism of the parents, etc.). Then, as we have seen above, the
social feelings can be developed only where there is reciprocity. I
should like to know whether society really concerns itself with the
fate of these unfortunates to such an extent that they in their turn
care greatly for the opinion of this same society. Certainly not. They
are pariahs, and since they are such the contempt of a hostile world is
a matter of indifference.

As we come to the conclusion of our observations upon the etiology of
vagrancy and mendicity, we have still but one category to consider,
that of those who are indolent by nature. There are individuals in whom
assiduous labor of any kind awakens a strong feeling of discomfort.
[860] As we have already stated above, in speaking of poverty in
general (see p. 288), the cause of this phenomenon is a species of
neurasthenia, more especially physical. It is necessary to recognize
that, while these individuals are out of harmony with society, they are
sick and must be cared for if society is to avoid trouble. Besides,
Professor Benedict, who was the first to point out physical
neurasthenia, himself recognizes [861] that such sick persons need not
become vagrants, if they are brought up in a favorable environment, and
that later the struggle for existence will not be painful to them.



To sum up, it is evident that the principal causes of vagrancy and
mendicity are lack of work, the want of care for the old, the sick, and
the weak, the abandonment of poor children, the low wages and long
hours of the workers. The persons who run most danger of being
incorporated in the army of vagrants are the weak, whether mentally or
physically, but this need not necessarily happen; the “causa causarum”
is the environment. [862]

History proves this also. If vagrancy and mendicity sprang from the
innate qualities of man, there would always have been vagrants and
mendicants, which is not the case. The appearance of these is due to
the economic structure of society. It is not possible to discuss this
at length and the reader is referred to the work of Florian and
Cavaglieri, “I vagabondi” (I, Part One). These authors show that the
first type of vagrant was the runaway slave, and then the serf who had
fled from his lord’s domain. In the following periods the penalties
with which vagrants were threatened (and they were very severe) were
especially designed to force the proletariat to serve the purposes of
the possessors of the means of production. [863] In measure as the
number of available workers increases and the proletariat submits to
the will of the capitalists, this cause becomes less important, and
disappears almost completely in our own time. It is rather the contrary
that takes place, since the army of vagrants and mendicants is now
mainly composed of those who have not been able to find work.
Vagabondage and mendicity are at present punishable because of the
importunity of the mendicants, the losses experienced by persons living
in the country especially, and also because of the danger to society
from the fact that the dangerous criminals are partly recruited from
this class.




B. Theft and Analogous Crimes.

Before examining the motives inducing the commission of theft (the most
important crime of this group, the others being mostly modifications of
it) we must first stop a moment to ask the question, “Is honesty an
innate characteristic or is it acquired?”

In my opinion it is indisputable that honesty is as little innate as
any other moral conception. [864] No child can distinguish between mine
and thine, it is only little by little that he gains this concept. On
the contrary he has the tendency to monopolize everything that he
desires (the prehensory instinct, Lafargue names it). [865] It is just
this instinct that must be combated to make a child honest. It would,
therefore, be more correct to say that dishonesty is innate. Unless one
takes account of this fact it is impossible to give the etiology of
theft and crimes of the same nature.

The motives for these crimes with which we are now occupied we shall
speak of under three heads. The first group includes the crimes
committed from poverty, the second those that result from cupidity, and
in the third group we shall treat of the criminals by profession.



a. THEFTS COMMITTED FROM POVERTY.

There are some needs which a man must satisfy, without which his
existence is impossible. These are fundamental needs, independent of
environment. If a man has not sufficient food, if he has not (at least
in non-tropical countries) clothing to protect him against cold, if
opportunity for rest is lacking, etc., his life is in danger. In our
present society there are always a number of persons who are in want of
the strict necessaries of life, and who are therefore obliged to steal
if they do not wish to succumb to poverty. It is evident that the word
“poverty” is not to be taken in the most limited sense, so that one who
can still buy a morsel of bread, and yet steals, may still be
considered as a thief from poverty.

We must make here one more observation before we enter upon the proofs
of this thesis. We have defined crime as an egoistic act. However, the
same act may be at once egoistic and altruistic, and this is the case
with some crimes committed from poverty, when an individual steals in
order not to have those in his charge die of hunger. What conflicts of
duty our present society creates!

The proofs that absolute poverty provokes a number of thefts are of
three kinds. The first two are based upon the dynamics of criminality.

First. In winter, when poverty is most pressing, the number of thefts
etc. is much greater than in summer. This is a fact so well known that
it is unnecessary to give detailed proofs of it, and I think it will be
sufficient to give the following statistics dealing with two important
countries for a great number of years.


Germany, 1883–1892. [866]

===============+========================================================================================================
               |                           Number of Punishable Acts Committed in the Months of
  Crimes.[867] +--------+---------+-------+-------+------+------+------+-------+----------+--------+---------+----------
               |January.|February.| March.| April.| May. | June.| July.|August.|September.|October.|November.| December.
---------------+--------+---------+-------+-------+------+------+------+-------+----------+--------+---------+----------
Simple theft {a|  7,991 |  7,342  | 6,909 | 5,777 | 6,097| 6,003| 6,230| 6,481 |   6,249  |  7,436 |  7,966  |  8,523
             {b|    113 |    115  |    98 |    85 |    87|    88|    88|    92 |      92  |    106 |    117  |    121
               |        |         |       |       |      |      |      |       |          |        |         |
Aggravated   {a|    913 |    877  |   830 |   777 |   840|   856|   879|   866 |     818  |    956 |    971  |    996
  theft      {b|    102 |    107  |    92 |    89 |    94|    98|    98|    96 |      94  |    106 |    112  |    111
               |        |         |       |       |      |      |      |       |          |        |         |
Embezzlement {a|  1,539 |  1,358  | 1,454 | 1,397 | 1,505| 1,485| 1,583| 1,551 |   1,459  |  1,604 |  1,573  |  1,659
             {b|    100 |     97  |    94 |    94 |    98|   100|   103|   101 |      98  |    104 |    105  |    108
               |        |         |       |       |      |      |      |       |          |        |         |
Receiving    {a|    682 |    615  |   571 |   442 |   458|   447|   444|   451 |     451  |    556 |    643  |    789
 stolen goods{b|    123 |    122  |   103 |    82 |    82|    83|    80|    81 |      81  |    100 |    120  |    142
               |        |         |       |       |      |      |      |       |          |        |         |
Professional {a|      3 |      5  |     4 |     8 |     4|     3|     3|     3 |       6  |      3 |      3  |      5
 and habitual{b|     71 |    130  |    94 |   195 |    94|    73|    71|    71 |     146  |     71 |     73  |    118
 receiving of  |        |         |       |       |      |      |      |       |          |        |         |
 stolen goods  |        |         |       |       |      |      |      |       |          |        |         |
               |        |         |       |       |      |      |      |       |          |        |         |
Fraud        {a|  2,174 |  2,050  | 1,909 | 1,744 | 1,823| 1,869| 1,932| 1,845 |   1,758  |  2,065 |   2,279 |  2,432
             {b|    107 |    111  |    94 |    89 |    90|    95|    95|    91 |      90  |    102 |     116 |    120
===============+========+=========+=======+=======+======+======+======+=======+==========+========+=========+==========


There is, then, a pretty considerable increase as winter approaches,
and a decrease with the summer months. I would call the attention of
the reader especially to the fact that it is the crimes of simple theft
and the receiving of stolen goods which show this change in the most
marked way, while aggravated theft, embezzlement and the professional
and habitual receiving of stolen goods show it in less degree. It is
the two former crimes which have poverty as their cause, while the
three latter are more apt to be committed from cupidity and by
professional criminals.

The following figures, taken from the criminal calendar composed by
Professor Lacassagne, have to do with


France, 1827–1870. [868]

Number of Crimes Against Property for Each Month, Reduced to an Equal
Duration of 31 Days.

                  January.               16,350
                  February.              15,400
                  March.                 14,250
                  April.                 13,450
                  May.                   13,625
                  June.                  13,450
                  July.                  13,225
                  August.                13,425
                  September.             13,875
                  October.               14,400
                  November.              16,100
                  December.              16,825


We have here, then, as always, a great increase in fall and winter, and
a corresponding decrease in spring and summer.

Second. A second proof of the importance of absolute poverty as a cause
of crime etc. is furnished by the fact that there is a considerable
increase of the crimes in question in times of economic depression
(high price of bread, lack of work, etc.). In Part One I have cited
many works in which this phenomenon is proved for a number of
countries. I refer the reader, therefore, to the more important of
these, and add other data here.


Germany, 1882–1911. [869]

=======+============+===========+================================================
       |            |           | Number of Persons Convicted of Crimes given
       |            |           | below, to 100,000 of Population over 12 Years
       |Price of Rye|  Imports  |                 of Age.
Years. |in Marks per|and Exports+------+----------+---------+------+-------------
       |1000 Kilogr.|    in     |      |          |Receiving|      |
       |  (Berlin.) | Billions  |Simple|Aggravated| Stolen  |Fraud.|Embezzlement.
       |            | of Marks. |Theft.|  Theft.  | Goods.  |      |
-------+------------+-----------+------+----------+---------+------+-------------
1882   | 152.3      |  6.3      |  250 |    28    |   26    |  37  |     46
1883   | 144.7      |  6.5      |  241 |    25    |   24    |  38  |     46
1884   | 143.3      |  6.4      |  231 |    25    |   23    |  39  |     46
1885   | 140.6      |  5.8      |  214 |    22    |   22    |  38  |     45
1886   | 130.6      |  5.9      |  210 |    20    |   21    |  41  |     45
1887   | 120.9      |  6.2      |  198 |    21    |   20    |  43  |     44
1888   | 134.5      |  6.7      |  194 |    21    |   20    |  44  |     44
1889   | 155.5      |  7.2      |  211 |    23    |   21    |  49  |     47
1890   | 170.0      |  7.6      |  206 |    24    |   21    |  50  |     47
1891   | 211.2      |  7.7      |  216 |    25    |   22    |  54  |     50
1892   | 176.3      |  7.3      |  236 |    31    |   25    |  59  |     52
1893   | 133.7      |  7.3      |  202 |    26    |   22    |  58  |     51
1894   | 117.8      |  7.2      |  198 |    27    |   22    |  60  |     52
1895   | 119.8      |  7.6      |  192 |    24    |   22    |  61  |     53
1896   | 118.8      |  8.2      |  184 |    24    |   19    |  58  |     50
1897   | 130.1      |  8.5      |  188 |    23    |   18    |  61  |     51
1898   | 146.3      |  9.4      |  191 |    25    |   19    |  63  |     52
1899   | 146.3      | 10.0      |  179 |    24    |   19    |  63  |     53
1900   | 142.6      | 10.7      |  181 |    23    |   18    |  60  |     51
1901   | 140.7      | 10.2      |  190 |    26    |   19    |  64  |     52
1902   | 144.2      | 10.6      |  191 |    28    |   20    |  66  |     55
1903   | 132.3      | 11.4      |  182 |    26    |   19    |  64  |     54
1904   | 135.1      | 12.1      |  176 |    24    |   17    |  62  |     54
1905   | 151.9      | 13.2      |  175 |    25    |   17    |  61  |     56
1906   | 160.6      | 14.8[870] |  179 |    28    |   18    |  62  |     58
1907   | 193.2[871] | 15.5      |  178 |    28    |   18    |  61  |     60
1908   | 186.5      | 14.0      |  189 |    32    |   20    |  61  |     63
1909   | 176.5      | 15.1      |  182 |    33    |   20    |  62  |     65
1910   | 152.3      | 16.4      |  176 |    32    |   19    |  63  |     65
1911   | 168.3      | 17.8      |  169 |    30    |   19    |  63  |     65
=======+============+===========+======+==========+=========+======+=============


If, in examining the preceding table, we do not lose sight of the fact
that the rise or fall of the price of grain does not make itself felt
immediately, and that in the criminal statistics of a certain year
there appear also persons who have committed their crime in a preceding
year, it is clear how enormous is the influence of the economic
movement upon economic crimes. The price of grain had formerly a
decisive influence upon the trend of economic crimes; now, in
industrial countries like Germany, it is rather the industrial
situation, without, however, the price of cereals losing all influence.
[872]


England, 1823–1896.

Dr. Tugan-Baranowsky proved for the periods 1823–1850 and 1871–1896 the
correlation between good and bad times and the decrease and increase of
criminality.

For the period 1858–1864 the same proof is given by Mayr (see Part I);
and for the years 1840–1890 by Fornasari di Verce (see Part I). The
figures of the former have reference only to crime in general, and do
not, therefore, show sufficiently the effect upon crimes that are
merely economic. [873]


Grand-Duchy of Baden, 1875–1892.[872]

J. S(chmidt), the statistician, shows the parallelism of the two curves
for the period mentioned (p. 243).


Bavaria, 1835–1861.

Dr. G. Mayr was one of the first statisticians to show the influence of
the price of grain upon crimes against property (pp. 39–42).


Belgium, 1839–1890.

Dr. Weisz has proved the influence of the price of grain during the
period from 1841 to 1860 (p. 61) and Professor Denis that of the
economic happenings for the period from 1840 to 1890 (pp. 235–237),
while Ducpetiaux draws attention especially to the enormous increase of
criminality in Flanders during the years of crisis, 1846–1847 (pp.
32–37). [874]


France, 1825–1886.

The influence of the price of grain upon crimes against property has
been shown for the periods 1845–1864, 1850–1864, and 1855–1864
respectively, by Drs. Weisz (pp. 60–61), Corne (pp. 48–49), and Mayr
(pp. 46–47). Lacassagne and Lafargue have shown the correlation between
the fluctuations of the economic life and those of economic crime for
the years 1825–80 and 1840–86 respectively (pp. 149 and 231 ff.).


Italy, 1873–1890.

For this period Fornasari di Verce has shown the parallelism between
the curves of economic occurrences and of economic crime (pp. 138–143).


New South Wales, 1882–1891.

The same author has shown here also the same correlation (p. 144).


Netherlands, 1860–1891.

Since researches for this country upon our subject are lacking, I have
composed the following diagram from the official data.


[Illustration:

 I. Number of those Convicted for Theft to 100,000 of the Population.
II. Price of Bread per Kilogram in Centimes.]


The parallelism of the two curves is striking, there being simply a
slight exception in the years 1871–1873. The increase of theft in the
years 1879–1881 coincides with a very great increase in the number of
bankruptcies, which continued until 1882. [875]

The same parallelism has also been shown for Prussia, Russia,
Wurtemberg, and Zürich by Starke and Müller, Tarnowsky, Rettich, and
Meyer, as quoted in Part I of this work. [876]

Few sociological theses, it seems to me, have been proved as
conclusively as the one of which we have just been speaking. The
important influence of the trend of economic events upon that of
economic criminality has been shown for thirteen different countries
for different periods of the nineteenth century. Some authors are of
the opinion that poverty cannot be the cause of crimes that are
committed when economic conditions are most favorable, and when
economic crimes have consequently reached their minimum. This assertion
still needs fuller proof, as I have already pointed out, since there
are still many persons who are in want of the necessaries of life even
in times of prosperity.

I must say here a few words in answer to a final objection to the
preceding observation; namely, that the increase of theft etc., in
times of economic depression, is, in great part, a consequence, not of
absolute poverty, but of the impossibility of satisfying needs that
have sprung up in more favorable times; and that the increase will be,
therefore, in large measure due to an increase of crimes committed from
cupidity, and not from poverty. This may be true in some cases, but
not, in my opinion in the great majority of cases, for the following
reasons. When the economic situation is favorable, when earnings are
more than usual, and when, consequently, wants increase and become more
intense, can everyone satisfy the desires awakened in him by the spirit
of imitation? Surely not; even at such times of prosperity there are
still many individuals with whom desire is awakened but who are not
able to satisfy it in a lawful manner. On the other hand, wants in
general diminish in times of crisis; cupidity is therefore less
excited, and with a limited income men are quite satisfied with having
the means of subsistence, when there are so many who lack the very
necessaries of life. In my opinion, crimes from cupidity increase
rather than diminish in times of prosperity, while in times of
depression the opposite takes place. This cannot be proved for each
economic crime separately, since criminal statistics do not show
whether a crime is committed from poverty or cupidity. However,
embezzlement, fraud, and aggravated theft are committed in a greater
degree from cupidity than is simple theft, (and by professional
criminals). Now statistics show that it is chiefly simple theft that
follows the course of economic events, the other crimes named doing so
much less; the same is true of the changes during the different
seasons. Finally, while absolute poverty in countries like Germany has
decreased and simple theft also, luxury and cupidity have increased,
together with the other crimes named. [877]

The third proof that poverty is a great factor in the etiology of theft
is the enormous number of widows and divorced women who participate in
these crimes (see pp. 452, 453). There is no reason to believe that
these women are more covetous than married women or spinsters; but it
is certain that their economic situation is often very burdensome.
[878]



We shall not employ any further methods to establish our thesis; since
for the reasons already stated they would lead to results of no great
significance, and it seems that the accuracy of the thesis has been
sufficiently shown by the proofs cited.

We have now come to the end of our consideration of the subject of
thefts committed from poverty. There are two ways in which it is the
cause of theft. On the one hand it incites directly the appropriation
of the property of others, and on the other hand it exercises a
demoralizing influence.



b. THEFT COMMITTED FROM CUPIDITY.

We have now to deal with crimes of persons who steal neither from
absolute poverty, nor by profession. Those who are guilty of these
crimes earn enough to satisfy their more pressing needs, and they steal
only when the occasion presents itself (whence their name of occasional
criminals) [879] in order to satisfy their desire for luxury.

The first question, then, which must be answered here is this: how do
these needs arise? The answer can be brief; they are aroused by the
environment. In a society where some are rich, who have more income
than is needed to supply the fundamental necessities, and who create
other needs for themselves, in such a society the cupidity of those who
have not similar incomes at their disposal will be awakened. The
desires which the criminals of whom we are speaking wish to satisfy by
their misdeeds are not different from those of the well-to-do. It goes
without saying that no one has ever desired any luxury that he has not
seen someone else enjoying. It would be a waste of time to discuss
this. Every need that is not strictly necessary, is not innate but
acquired. If one has much, the other, an imitator, wants the same.
There is but one piece of advice to give to those who are not convinced
of this simple truth; that they read some ethnological works treating
of peoples among whom there are neither rich nor poor. They will then
see that cupidity, with us a universal quality, is there unknown. [880]

The division between rich and poor is many centuries old and does not
belong to capitalism alone, although under capitalism the distance
between the two has greatly increased and is still increasing. The
greater this distance is, the more, other things being equal, cupidity
increases. [881]

The cupidity of those who can satisfy only the desire for the bare
necessities is not awakened in the same measure in each of them. As has
already been remarked by Guerry and Quetelet (see Part I), economic
crimes are most numerous in the countries where manufacturing and
commerce are most developed, and where the contrasts of fortune are
consequently the greatest. It is for this reason that the cities, where
the contrasts between poverty and wealth are greatest, give also very
high figures for crimes against property (see pp. 530–531).

Those who live in the same country or the same city are not, in spite
of that, in the same environment. Every great city has thousands of
workers who, because of the character of their labor, have no contact
with luxury; others, on the contrary, have the desire for luxury
awakened in them by the fact that their work brings them in touch with
wealth. Hence it is, for example, that so large a number of economic
crimes are committed by workers occupied in commerce (see p. 446), and
by servants. [882] There are workmen who have never been accustomed to
more than they are able to earn at the time, but there are also those
who have known better days and to whom the impossibility of satisfying
needs previously acquired is a constant source of suffering.

However, the contrast between rich and poor is not the only cause of
the origin of cupidity. We must also sketch in addition to the above,
especially the manner in which commercial capital tries to draw buyers.
The times are long gone by when the producer worked principally to
order. Modern industry manufactures enormous quantities of goods
without the outlet for them being known. The desire to buy must, then,
be excited in the public. Beautiful displays, dazzling illuminations,
and many other means are used to attain the desired end. The perfection
of this system is reached in the great modern retail store, where
persons may enter freely, and see and handle everything, where, in
short, the public is drawn as a moth to a flame. The result of these
tactics is that the cupidity of the crowd is highly excited. [883]

After what has been said it is unnecessary to dwell longer upon the
different ways in which cupidity is awakened in our present society.
However we must note the following. Almost all the thefts of the class
of which we are speaking (those committed by so-called occasional
criminals) are thefts of articles of very small value (see the figures
on p. 201); the exceptions are the thefts of large sums of money. The
authors of these last are in general the employes of banks, etc.,
persons who, from the nature of their work, have the opportunity to
appropriate other people’s money. When we investigate the reasons for
their committing their misdeeds, we shall see that nine times out of
ten (I cannot prove it by figures, but no one will contradict me) the
criminal is a speculator who has lost, or perhaps an individual who
visits prostitutes, and hence has great need of money.

Cupidity is thus excited by the environment, but not in the same degree
in every case, the environment not being the same for all. However,
even supposing that the environment were exactly identical for a number
of persons, cupidity would not be excited in the same measure in some
as in others, since they are not alike, one being born with more
intense desires than others (admitting that it is the environment that
calls forth the desires). The more intense a man’s desires, the more
risk he runs, other things being equal, of falling foul of the law. As
I have already remarked above, this is important for the person who is
seeking the reason why A and not B has stolen, though both live in the
same environment; for sociology this fact is only of secondary
importance, for it does not ask “Who becomes criminal?” but rather “How
does it happen that there are crimes?”

We have now examined one of the sides of the question; the principal
cause of these crimes is the cupidity awakened by the environment. If
the environment were different, cupidity would not be aroused and the
crimes would not be committed. In my opinion most criminologists do not
sufficiently appreciate the importance of this fact. It is very
difficult for anyone who lives at ease to form an idea of what is
passing in the mind of one who has only the bare necessaries of life
and is deprived of every comfort and amusement, while he sees others
who have too much, and yet often work less than he does.

Let us now examine the other side of the question. For this purpose let
us make use once more of the figure of balances in describing the
process that goes on in the brain of the man who hesitates. Upon one of
the pans cupidity exercises its force, in different measure according
to the person. What are the weights upon the other pan balancing the
first? It is the moral forces which must be considered first. I have
fully explained above how the economic environment has prevented the
social instincts from being developed in man, and how this is
especially true for certain classes of persons. It is unnecessary to
repeat this here. It will be sufficient to note certain points which
have a special importance for the kind of crimes with which we are
occupied at the moment.

He who steals, prejudices the interests of another, does him harm, and
at the same time injures society, the existence of which would become
impossible were theft permitted. In my opinion, the present
organization of society, of which the struggle of all against all is
the fundamental principle, has reduced this moral factor to very small
dimensions. In the economic domain each must be egoistic, for without
egoism he would lose in the struggle for existence. In the case of
theft and similar crimes, those injured are almost exclusively
well-to-do persons, to whom the damage is disagreeable, but who, in
general do not suffer much. The thieves, on the other hand, are almost
exclusively persons who have to live on very little. How can we expect
a poor man to take care not to do a small injury to the rich for fear
of causing them a little discomfort, when most rich people are
insensible to the suffering which without intermission, overwhelms the
poor. The present organization of society is responsible for the fact
that a slight sensibility to the misfortune of others offers only a
trifling counterpoise to the tendency to realize one’s desires in a
dishonest manner. [884] The idea that society in itself is injured by
theft cannot constitute any considerable counterpoise, since he who
violates the eighth commandment cannot feel himself at one with a
society which never has helped him when he was in difficulties.

After this general observation let us pass on to particular remarks
that apply to certain classes of persons only. How does it happen that
a great proportion of mankind are honest? To this question the answer
must be, “because they have been accustomed to it from infancy.” The
opposite also is true; a great number of thieves are such because any
moral education was out of the question in the environment in which
they were brought up. They satisfy their “prehensory instinct” without
being conscious of any ill-doing. With these the balance inclines to
the side of dishonesty, unless a counterpoise of some magnitude is
found. Above (pp. 489 ff.) we have seen that most criminals, especially
thieves, come from a totally corrupt environment. [885]

This does not apply to another category of thieves; those who do not
proceed from an absolutely corrupt environment—yet whose surroundings
are not good and wholesome. Ferriani [886] and Aschaffenburg [887] go
so far as to say that almost every child has once stolen something.
This may be a little exaggerated but it certainly has truth at the
bottom of it. If the child has no one to take the trouble to teach him
that he ought not to steal, it is more than likely that he will have to
answer for theft later (occasional theft is committed by children and
minors especially). It is true that all the children whose education
has been defective do not become thieves, nor even the majority of
them; there are those for whom a single prohibition will be enough to
make them respect the property of others for the rest of their lives.
There are others of them, weak characters who, notwithstanding such
prohibition, cannot resist when the temptation is strong. If their
education had been good, the environment in which they were brought up
more favorable, they would not have had to be turned over to justice.
Hear the opinion of one of those most competent to judge of the matter,
Raux, who, having put to himself the question whether the young people
detained in the “Quartier correctionnel” of Lyons have a real tendency
to steal, answers as follows. “Evidently not. Without entering into the
analysis of the circumstances which provoke crime, we shall give, in
support of our assertion, an observation as simple as conclusive. Young
prisoners condemned for theft have shown us upon different occasions a
probity, a most praiseworthy disinterestedness, in the presence of
things that they might have appropriated without exposing themselves to
any reproof.” [888]



We might close our observations upon theft from cupidity at this point
if there were not fear of an objection drawn from what has just been
said, namely the following. If the occasional thief has become such, on
the one side because of the cupidity awakened in him, and on the other
side in consequence of his lack of a good education, and if he differs,
not qualitatively, but only quantitatively from the honest man,
possessing less strength of character than the average—if all this is
true, then the figures for theft should be higher than the statistics
show. All of which would go to prove that it is wrong to deny that
criminals constitute a biological anomaly.

Here is my reply. First. Moral forces do not constitute the only
counterpoise to the tendency toward theft. Since the moral check often
lacks efficacy, another has been created which acts in the same way to
turn the egoist away from crime, namely the fear inspired by the
possibility of punishment. Any one would be credulous indeed to fancy
that those who have an opportunity to steal and do not profit by it are
deterred by moral forces. Without punishment criminality would be much
more extensive than it now is. Where the danger of being found out is
not great, the number of transgressions is enormous (think, for
example, of the cases of smuggling). [889]

Second. Many persons remain honest, not for moral reasons, but because
they lack the courage, cleverness, or other qualities necessary for
being otherwise, qualities which in themselves have nothing to do with
crime.

Third. Still others remain honest for reasons based upon mature
reflection. They find that it is too dangerous to commit an offense,
but do not hesitate in the presence of acts essentially criminal,
although they do not fall under the ban of the law. [890] No one is
ignorant of this, and only certain anthropologists who examine no one
but prisoners, have lost sight of it.

Those who compose the criminal world are by nature very diverse. Some
are the most dangerous individuals that it is possible to imagine,
others are rather weak than wicked. Among these last are ranged the
occasional criminals, who, taken together, form a danger to society,
but taken singly are not dangerous men in the strict sense. Leuss, who
learned to know prisoners, not as judge, or as medical expert, but as a
prisoner himself, says: “The great mass of prisoners are more
good-natured than the average man; the good-nature of thieves
corresponds with their weakness of will, that invincible obstacle to
their maintaining themselves in the world of industry. Stress must
constantly be laid upon the fact that these weak-willed, good-natured
persons are the ones who swell the number of crimes.” [891]

When we place beside the occasional thieves, those who never steal but
commit all sorts of reprehensible (though not illegal) acts, the
comparison is not to the advantage of the latter. Their trickery, their
pitiless egoism, often make them more dangerous to society than the
others; which should be a reason for criminal anthropology not to build
a system based solely upon investigations of prisoners.

Fourth. Finally many more crimes are committed than are mentioned by
criminal statistics. Although I have already spoken of this (p. 84), I
must return to it. In the first place, most criminal statistics give
the figures only for those convicted. Those acquitted have no place,
although, with few exceptions, a crime has nevertheless been committed.
We know that the number of acquittals is very considerable. In Germany,
there were 15 to 20 acquittals to 100 cases tried (1882–1896); [892] in
Italy the number of acquittals ran as high as 51.37% (1890–1895). [893]

In the second place, in many cases the prosecution is postponed for
different reasons, with the result that there is neither an acquittal
nor a condemnation. Then a great many cases never come to trial because
justice cannot discover the authors of the crimes. In Germany, for
example, of all the cases on the dockets in the criminal courts between
1881 and 1891, only 43 to 45% actually came before the judges. [894]
During the period between 1886 and 1890, the examining judges dismissed
on an average 8900 cases, either because the author of the crime was
unknown, or because the proof was insufficient. During the same period
and for the same reasons, 98,741 cases on the average were not
prosecuted by the authorities. [895] The authors of about 25% of the
crimes committed in Italy remained unknown (1887–1894). [896]

These two reasons by themselves show that the number of crimes is much
greater than the statistics would generally lead one to suppose, even
if one takes account of the fact that some of the complaints made to
the prosecutors are false.

In the third place, we have been speaking so far of the cases that come
to the notice of the officers, while in a great number of cases no
complaint is made, especially in the matter of petty theft, either
because the person injured wishes to avoid the annoyance of having to
appear in the police court as witness, or because he wishes to spare
the delinquent.

In the fourth place, a great many small thefts remain unknown even to
the person injured, since he does not notice the loss that he has
suffered.

All this goes to show that crime, taken in the strict sense, and
especially theft, is much more extensive than one would expect at
first, and the objection that might have been made to my thesis is
hence without weight. It is evident that the number of criminals
unpunished cannot be fixed with certainty. Dr. Puibaraud places it at
50%; [897] while Tarde believes that it is greater; [898] Yvernès, the
well-known French statistician, says that 90% of the professional
thieves remain unknown, and Dr. Thomsen, from whom I take this last
fact, says that this applies to other categories of criminals also.
[899] However this may be the number in any case is very considerable.

To sum up. I believe I have shown that the fundamental causes of theft
and similar crimes committed from cupidity are, on the one hand, the
cupidity aroused by the environment and, on the other, neglected
childhood among the poor. It is especially those weak in character who
run the greatest risk of becoming guilty of these crimes.



c. CRIMES COMMITTED BY PROFESSIONAL CRIMINALS.

In considering all the kinds of theft and analogous crimes, we note
that the thefts committed by professional criminals represent only a
minority. But as soon as we limit our consideration to the more serious
forms of theft, such as burglary and similar crimes, we shall discover
that they are committed almost exclusively by individuals whose
principal or subsidiary occupation is theft, and who, in general, do
not consider it shameful, and do not feel the slightest repentance.

The question arises, how it is possible for anyone to embrace so abject
a profession, and thus become so harmful a parasite. [900] There are
authors who would have us believe that there are persons who have
chosen crime from pleasure in it. As Leuss observes in his work, “Aus
dem Zuchthause”, this opinion is so absurd that it would be a waste of
time to consider it. No one of sound mind could possibly prefer so
abominable a profession, and one so full of risks from the point of
view of simple calculation. There must be other reasons for the
existence of such persons. [901] If we wish to examine these causes we
must divide professional criminals into separate groups.

The first category is composed of children. Sad as this is it is none
the less true. It is plain that not a single child follows the
profession of thief from pleasure, for a child prefers not to work at
all. These children, then, are taught to steal by their parents. If
they are not very numerous, in the great cities there are always some
cases of this kind. Dr. Puibaraud, former police official in Paris,
describes one of these as follows. “We recall that one day, on visiting
the Petite-Roquette, we found in a cell a child scarcely eight years
old, with a wide-awake face, a quick eye, but whose physiognomy was
already very peculiar. It was a young pickpocket who had been found
drunk upon the street, and who, being arrested by an agent and taken to
the station, had confessed that the gold he had in his possession was
the proceeds of a theft committed by him without the knowledge of his
‘papa.’ This capture ended by the whole family’s being arrested at
their lodgings, near the Place Maubert.

“This gamin was very intelligent and gave the following account of
himself, which was corroborated by what was brought out in the
examination. ‘My father showed me how to pick pockets, but so far I
have only “done” ladies because that is easier. With gentlemen you may
touch their leg when you stick your hand in their pocket and they turn
round, and that’s no joke! With ladies you do not get so close and they
do not feel your hand. It isn’t hard at all. Papa taught me well. We
went every day together to the Palais Royal and Place de la Bastille
omnibus stations. The Palais Royal is no good. The best is the
Madeleine, but Mother G. works that and she quarrels with papa. We
don’t go there any more. Last week papa told me to wait for him at the
Palais Royal omnibus stand. He didn’t come, and, “ma foi!” I went to
work by myself. I got a purse from an old lady. There were sixty francs
in it. I drank a bit and then I was arrested.’” [902]

As we see this child found theft the most natural thing in the world
(and any other child in the same environment would think the same); he
“worked” with his father. If exceptionally favorable circumstances do
not happen to present themselves to such children they will belong to
the army of professional criminals all their lives.

Now, as for the others, those who have not been brought up for a life
of crime, yet practice it as their profession—how can we explain their
manner of life? The answer to this question can be found only in the
works of those who have familiarized themselves with the life of
criminals, and who have lived in their midst in order to know them
(like Flynt, for example), or who are in a position, because of their
profession, to study them in detail, and become their confidants (like
the well-known almoners of the Grande-Roquette: Crozes, Moreau, and
Faure). [903]

Except for a few subsidiary circumstances the life of the professional
criminal may be summed up as follows. With very rare exceptions he
springs from a corrupt environment, perhaps having lost his parents
while still very young, or having even been abandoned by them. Being
misled by bad company, he commits an “occasional” theft while still a
child, for which he must pay the penalty of an imprisonment; he may, at
times owe his entrance into prison to a non-economic misdeed. This,
however, is a very rare exception. [904] As we have remarked above,
prison never improves him, and generally makes him worse. If he is in
contact with the other prisoners, among whom there are naturally a
number of out and out criminals, he hears the recital of their
adventurous life, learns their tricks and all that he still needs to
know to be thoroughly informed as to “the profession.” Nor will the
separate cell be any more profitable to him, brutalized as he already
is by his earlier environment. Then after a certain time he is set at
liberty and returned to society. The partisans of free will say that he
has expiated his fault and can now commence a new life.

That is easy to say, and certainly justice will not concern itself with
him any further until he commits a new offense. But this is not the
same as saying that society pardons him and aids him, in order that he
may remain in the right path. On the contrary, forgetting that we must
forgive those who have trespassed against us, society makes life hard
for him. It is almost impossible for him to find work; the fact that he
has been in prison is enough to insure his being refused everywhere.
Why should anyone hire an old prisoner when there are so many others
who have never got into the courts? And then most prisoners have never
learned a trade, and this is one reason more why they cannot easily
find employment. The liberated convict becomes a nomad, begins by
losing all contact with the normal world (supposing he ever had any)
and feels himself a social pariah. On the other hand he has relations
more and more frequent with the “under world”, with those who recognize
no duty toward a society which is not interested in their fate. His
moral sense comes to be more and more blunted until he becomes a
criminal by profession, having a feeling neither of shame nor of
repentance.

The ignorant public, who know nothing about the professional criminal
except when he appears before the tribunal, is astonished to find that
there are persons so abject. This astonishment is like that of some one
who has never seen a house built, and cannot imagine how such a
colossus can be put up. But he who has seen how the house has been
erected by adding one small brick to another no longer feels any
astonishment. It is the same with the professional criminal; he who has
followed the story of the criminal’s life recognizes with Dr. Havelock
Ellis, that his crime is but the last link of a solidly forged chain.

Generally the professional criminal does not give the least sign of
repentance. He does as much injury to society as he can, without having
any shame about it. Yet he is not entirely deprived of moral sense,
only it extends merely to those who are really his fellows. All the
tales of the world of professional criminals which depict them as void
of all sense of duty toward their fellows, proceed rather from the
imagination of the authors than from facts really observed. The only
competent authors are those who have been able to study the criminal in
his own environment, and not in prison, where his true character makes
itself known as little as that of an animal in a cage. Hear the opinion
of Flynt, for example. “It is often said that his (the professional
criminal’s) lack of remorse for his crimes proves him to be morally
incompetent; but this opinion is formed on insufficient knowledge of
his life. He has two systems of morality: one for his business and the
other for the hang-out.” [905] There follows the description of the
relations existing between him and society of which we have already
spoken, after which the author continues as follows.

“In the bosom of his hang-out, however—and this is where we ought to
study his ethics,—he is a very different man. His code of morals there
will compare favorably with that of any class of society; and there is
no class in which fair dealing is more seriously preached, and unfair
dealing more severely condemned. The average criminal will stand by a
fellow-craftsman through thick and thin; and the only human being he
will not tolerate is the one who turns traitor. The remorse of this
traitor when brought to bay by his former brethren I have never seen
exceeded anywhere.” [906]

After expatiating upon this subject, Flynt continues: “It is thought by
criminologists that the good fellowship of the criminal is due to
self-preservation and the fear that each man will hang separately if
all do not hang together. They maintain that his good feeling is not
genuine and spontaneous emotion, and that it is immaterial what happens
to a ‘pal’ so long as he himself succeeds. This is not my experience in
his company. He has never had the slightest intimation that I would
return favors that he did me; and in the majority of instances he has
had every reason to know that it was not in my power to show him the
friendliness he wanted. Yet he has treated me with an altruism that
even a Tolstoi might admire. At the hang-out I have been hospitably
entertained on all occasions; and I have never met a criminal there who
would not have given me money or seen me through a squabble, had I
needed his assistance and he was able to give it. This same comradeship
is noticeable in all his relations with men who are in the least
connected with his life and business; and it is notorious fact that he
will ‘divvy’ his last meal with a pal. To have to refuse the request of
one of his fellows, or to do him an unkindness, is as much regretted by
the criminal as by anyone else; and I have never known him to tell me a
lie or to cheat me or to make fun of me behind my back.” [907]

This is altogether different from what is generally said and written by
those who allow themselves to be led away by their imagination. It is
plain that the manner in which criminals act toward a society that is
hostile to them will not fail to influence the relations they have with
their fellows, just as war for those who take part in it cannot leave
their moral sense as regards their compatriots unharmed. However,
nothing permits us to put the actions of these persons among themselves
in the same rank as those towards society. In my opinion this fact has
great significance for the moralist and the criminologist; it is one of
the forms of the dualism of ethics. It is of very high importance for
the criminologist, for its shows that we are upon the wrong track,
since it is precisely the more serious forms of crime that the present
methods of repression favor.

In imprisoning young people who have committed merely misdemeanors of
minor importance, and who have not yet lost all touch with normal
society, and putting them in contact with inveterate criminals, or
perhaps putting them into a cage like beasts, without striving to
enlighten their darkened minds or teach them morality, and without
making them capable of sustaining the struggle for existence by
teaching them a trade, we are bringing up professional criminals.
Punishment, as a means of intimidation, misses its aim in great part,
for the professional criminals are recruited among individuals who are
not easily intimidated.

We have now come to the question why a certain number only of those
whose childhood has been neglected and who have committed a light
offense, become professional criminals. In the first place there are
those whom chance favors, since they are assisted, it may be by their
families, it may be by some philanthropist, and so return to the right
path. There are those also who have the advantage of being able to find
work, since no one knows that they have been in prison.

Others have less chance; no one aids them, there is no work for them;
all, however, do not become professional thieves. Those who become such
are the more intelligent, energetic, ambitious, and courageous of these
outcasts; the others become vagrants and mendicants. Here is the
opinion of Flynt upon the criminal by profession, an opinion which
agrees with that of other competent authors. “I must say ... that those
criminals who are known to me are not, as is also popularly supposed,
the scum of their environment. On the contrary, they are above their
environment, and are often gifted with talents which would enable them
to do well in any class, could they only be brought to realize its
responsibilities and to take advantage of its opportunities. The notion
that the criminal is the lowest type of his class arises from a false
conception of that class and of the people who compose it....

“In this same class, however, there are some who are born with
ambitions, and who have energy enough to try to fulfil them. These
break away from class conditions; but unfortunately, the ladder of
respectable business has no foothold in their environment....

“Not all of these ambitious ones are endowed with an equal amount of
energy. Some are capable only of tramp life, which, despite its many
trials and vicissitudes, is more attractive than the life they seek to
escape. Those with greater energy go into crime proper; and they may be
called, mentally as well as physically, the aristocracy of their class.
This is my analysis of the majority of the criminal men and women I
have encountered in the open, and I believe it will hold good
throughout their entire class.” [908]

There are readers, perhaps, who will find that these qualities of the
professional criminal give the lie to the environment hypothesis, since
individual factors are recognized in a certain way. For myself I do not
find it so. The qualities mentioned have nothing to do with crime as
such; they can be utilized to the profit as well as to the detriment of
society; it will depend upon the environment in which the individual
endowed with them has been raised what direction he will take. It would
not be difficult to name a number of historic celebrities (Napoleon,
for example) who, if they had been born in the lower stratum of a great
city, in place of in a favorable environment, would have had only the
sad celebrity of criminals exceptionally endowed.

The psychology of this kind of criminals is not yet complete however.
Besides intelligence, energy, and courage we find cupidity as their
great characteristic. [909] They see others who can enjoy themselves
without working hard, and it is their ambition to do the same, cost
what it may. Since fate has made it impossible for them to attain it
honestly they risk another method. This type of criminal is well
delineated in the remark made by the notorious Lemaire, when he said to
the president of the court: “If I were a property owner, I should not
be here.” [910]

To have invested funds, to spend plenty of money, not to have to work
much, this is their ideal; to share the lot of the working-man, who,
notwithstanding his long and hard labor, never succeeds in procuring
for himself the pleasures of the rich, makes life insipid in their
eyes. M. Gisquet, former prefect of police, gives in his memoirs the
following declaration made by Leblanc, the notorious professional
criminal. “If I were not a thief by vocation I should become one by
calculation; it is the best profession. I have computed the good and
bad chances of all the others, and I am convinced by the comparisons
that there is none more favorable or more independent than that of
thief, nor one that does not offer at least an equal amount of danger.

“What should I have become in the society of honest men? A natural
child, with no one to protect me or to recommend me, I could only
choose a disagreeable trade, become a delivery-boy in a store, or at
most reach the miserable place of shipping clerk in a warehouse; and
there, a supernumerary for many years, I should have died of hunger
before I reached a salary of six hundred francs. As a workman in any
class whatever you exhaust yourself quickly through the fatigues of
your labor, to earn a miserable wage, and to live from day to day; then
when accident, sickness, or old age come you must go beg or die in the
poorhouse....

“In our condition we depend only on ourselves; and if we acquire skill
and experience at least they profit ourselves alone. I know very well
that we have risks to run, that the police and the courts are at hand,
that the prison is not very far distant; but out of eight thousand
thieves in Paris, you never have more than seven or eight hundred in
jail; that is not a tenth of the whole. We enjoy, then, on the average,
nine years of liberty to one in prison. Well, where is the worker who
has not a dead season? Besides, what does he do when he is without
work? He carries his possessions to the Mont-de-Piété; while we others,
if we are free, lack for nothing; our existence is a continual round of
feasting and pleasure.” [911]

This is the type of the perfect egoist. In ranking men according to
their social sentiments, such an individual would be put at the very
lowest point in the scale. And then he has grown up under unfavorable
circumstances (illegitimate birth, etc.). The innate egoism of this
individual may perhaps be modified by the individual factor. But this
in no way diminishes the truth of the environment hypothesis, for we
are treating for the moment the question why this particular individual
has become a criminal, and not that of the cause of the existence of
professional criminals. And these two questions are far from being
identical. The existence of individual differences is the reason why
one runs more danger of becoming a professional criminal than another;
but it is the environment which brings it about that the predisposed
individual actually becomes such. The falsity of the environment
hypothesis would be demonstrated if such individuals could be proved to
become criminals under all circumstances. This is of course not the
case. When individuals like these are not brought up in an atmosphere
of poverty, they no longer see on the one side persons who enjoy
everything while doing nothing, and on the other side those who, while
toiling hard, live in poverty,—they will not become examples of
altruism indeed, but they will not become guilty of crime. They may
even become very useful members of society, since they are generally
more largely endowed with intelligence, energy, and courage than the
average man. Rightly exercised, these qualities are very useful; but
badly directed they are very harmful to society. [912]



So far we have been treating of the etiology of theft and analogous
crimes; we shall conclude this section with some observations upon the
causes that have led to the designating of these acts as crime.

Theft is a crime only because it is very harmful to society. [913] If
in the majority of cases the individual does not take account of this,
the assertion is nevertheless true. Everything that is harmful to
society the individual considers as immoral. (Why this is so is a
psychological question, with which we are not concerned here.) If we
picture to ourselves present-day society, based as it is upon exchange,
without the strict prohibition of theft, we shall see that it could not
possibly exist. Life would be especially impossible in a society where
the division of labor has attained a high degree of development, if it
were permissible to take anything without giving an equivalent.

Since the human race has existed there has been private property,
however trifling and unimportant it may have been. It is therefore very
unlikely that theft has ever been permitted [914] (it is impossible to
produce proofs in support of this), since it is difficult to imagine
that anyone would consent to see himself stripped of things destined
for his own use, to which, further he was more or less attached. [915]
But there is a great difference between a prohibited act and a crime.
It is proved that among primitive peoples theft is not reckoned among
the crimes. Hear the opinion of one of the greatest specialists in this
field, Dr. Post. “We find here and there a phenomenon very surprising
from our modern point of view, namely that theft is not universally
regarded as a misdemeanor, but the thief rather respected for his
cleverness. The maximum obligation that a theft lays upon the thief is
simple restitution of the stolen property. The consequence of theft is
thus simply the duty of restitution under the civil law.... Theft lies
entirely outside of the province of criminal law.” [916]

It is not difficult to explain the cause of this. Let the reader
picture to himself the primitive forms of society, so different from
those we have at present; contrasts of possessions were unknown, and
the needs of men consequently less numerous; men produced only for
their own consumption and not for exchange. If by chance more was
produced than was needed, the surplus was given to others, for it was
impossible to exchange it, or to preserve it for any great length of
time, the necessary technique for this not having yet been acquired.
“The law of hospitality” was universal and enjoined men to provide
those in need with whatever they lacked. [917] It is quite
comprehensible that at such a stage of development theft should not be
in evidence, for the motives which drive men to it would be lacking. On
the one hand cupidity was not awakened, and theft did not result from
absolute poverty, since if there was poverty the whole group suffered
together. [918] On the other hand the social instincts, being highly
developed by the environment, constituted a restraint that would
prevent the execution of a theft if the thought of it should occur. But
even supposing that in such a society a theft, for no matter what
cause, should nevertheless be committed, it would be little thought of,
and certainly the thief would not be severely punished, for his act
would not be very harmful to society.

As the social structure changed the ideas about theft changed equally;
with the origin of the system of exchange and of the contrasts of
property, came powerful motives for theft, and at the same time the
social instincts grew weaker. Thus theft came to be considered a more
serious matter than before, and the graded system of punishments for
it, beginning with a fine, ended in capital punishment. [919] It is not
our task to investigate the reason why the punishment for theft has not
always been the same during the whole civilized period; it is enough
for us to establish the fact that the act has always been considered as
a grave offense, the perpetrator of which incurred severe penalties.




C. Robbery and Analogous Crimes.

As the figures reproduced above (pp. 535–542) have shown, the crimes
with which we have now to concern ourselves are relatively rare. It is
unnecessary to say that this has not always been so, but that there
have been great changes in this regard. At one time robbery and similar
acts of violence were the ordinary forms of professional crime. Happily
for peaceable folk this is no longer the case; these crimes have been
in large measure replaced by others less serious, like theft and fraud.
[920] All modern states have not reached the same stage of development,
nor all parts of the same state. There are those of them that, more
than others, recall the past to us. So is it in regard to their
criminality. While robbery may be said to have disappeared from the
states of northern Europe, it is still very common in a country like
Italy, and is met much less frequently in the modernized provinces of
northern Italy than in the backward southern provinces, as the
following figures show. [921]


Italy, 1887–1889.

===================+==========================================
                   |     Average to 100,000 Inhabitants.
    Provinces.     +-------------------+----------------------
                   |Robbery, etc., with|Robbery, etc., without
                   |     Homicide.     |      Homicide.
-------------------+-------------------+----------------------
Apulia             |       5.01        |         0.27
Basilicata         |       2.42        |         4.18
Sardinia           |       2.06        |        12.11
Sicily             |       1.22        |        14.56
Liguria            |       1.07        |         8.65
Calabria           |       0.97        |         6.36
Latium             |       0.89        |        17.15
Campania and Molise|       0.71        |         8.08
Piedmont           |       0.63        |         4.67
Romagna            |       0.63        |         6.47
Abruzzo            |       0.58        |         2.07
Marches and Ombria |       0.55        |         2.46
Venetia            |       0.33        |         2.58
Emilia             |       0.28        |         5.80
Lombardy           |       0.21        |         3.14
Tuscany            |       --          |         5.68
===================+===================+======================


According to the figures given by Dr. Bosco, in the United States,
also, the most backward states give the highest figures for homicide.
[922]

The poorer classes have more resemblance to the people of a bygone day
than have the well-to-do; it appears from the statistics (see pp. 438
ff.) that economic criminality takes a more violent form among the
former than among the latter. [923]

An investigation into the causes of this change in the form of economic
criminality will indicate also the principal causes of the persistent
existence of this kind of crime, however it may have decreased in
modern times. In my opinion these causes are as follows:

First. The opportunity for committing them presented itself more often
formerly, since the means of communication were very primitive,
travelers had to traverse uninhabited countries, etc., and in addition
the states were not so well organized as at present, and had not the
means of suppressing bands of brigands vigorously.

Second. While the opportunity to commit violent economic crimes
successfully was diminishing, there was a constantly increasing
opportunity to commit other economic crimes, such as theft,
embezzlement, and fraud. The accumulation of great wealth in the
cities, the development of credit, in short, the enormous extension of
capitalism, has multiplied the opportunity for economic crimes without
violence.

Third. One of the consequences of the development of society has been
the gradual diminution of the importance of the rôle played by
violence, and, since criminality presents itself always and everywhere
under the same forms as the normal life, violent economic criminality
has also commenced to form a smaller and smaller part in the totality
of economic crimes. The assertion that violence has lost the importance
of its rôle upon the human stage might surprise one, and appear
ironical in times like ours when war is the chronic condition, when the
military preparations of all the states have reached a degree hitherto
unknown. Violence, however, has decreased in so far as it is exercised
by the individual as such. The greater becomes the centralization of
the state, the more it claims for itself the exclusive right to use
violence in the cases where it judges it necessary, and the more it
prohibits individual acts of violence.

It is not the development of the state that is alone to be considered
in this regard; the economic system enters in also. Under capitalism
violence is of no use; he who is master of the means of production
attains his end, i.e. makes a profit, without the use of violence.
Where it is necessary, however, modern man does not recoil from it, as
the wars of expansion prove.

Fourth. Civilization (in the proper sense of the word) has become more
general. Formerly the privilege of a few only, it now extends to a
greater number. The great mass are still deprived of it, but primary
instruction contributes to its development.

When we consider the gradual diminution in the number of economic
crimes committed with violence, it clearly appears how false is the
notion that anyone committing such a crime is for that reason a
biologically abnormal being. Will anyone claim that the number of
biologically abnormal persons has constantly diminished? The contrary
is much more likely.

We need not concern ourselves with the details of this question, since
it has already been thoroughly treated by Professor Manouvrier (see Pt.
I of this work, pp. 168–171). He who uses violence to attain an
economic end may perhaps, physiologically considered, be a perfectly
normal man. How many children are there who do not use force to take a
toy from a weaker child? Must we class them as abnormal on that
account? And are those who voluntarily take part in a war abnormal?
Certainly there is a great difference between those who take part in a
war, and those who, for economic reasons, commit a crime, but this
difference is of a social nature. Our ideas of war and homicide are not
the same, but the act of killing one’s neighbor remains identical. If
homicide were the evident proof of biological abnormality the soldier
also would be abnormal.

Scientific questions can be solved by reason alone, and not by
sentiment. We who experience a profound repulsion at the thought of a
murderer, hold him for a being apart, since we feel ourselves so remote
from him. Scientific research tells us that this feeling is not innate
but acquired, for we detest such acts because the environment in which
we live has accustomed us to hate them. If our environment were
different, our feelings would likewise be different. Besides, war
proves that these feelings are not innate, by hardening the mildest
persons in a very brief time.

With time the number of persons who have a horror of violence has
increased. Does this prove that men have become better, or simply that
they feel a repugnance to the act only and not to its effect? J. J.
Rousseau once said: “If, in order to fall heir to the property of a
rich mandarin living at the farthest confines of China, whom one had
never seen or heard spoken of, it were enough to push a button to make
him die, which of us would not push that button?”

It is certain that beside a great number of persons who would not wish
to charge their consciences with such a crime, there would also be
plenty who would commit it, and their number would be great enough to
make the order of mandarins pass into legendary history. There is no
reason to suppose that there are fewer persons in our day who would
commit such acts, than formerly; if men are no longer as violent as
they once were, they do not recoil any more than formerly when it is a
question of suppressing, through the agency of a third party, those who
oppose them; as witness the wars of expansion.

As the motives of these crimes are the same as those of economic crimes
without violence, we shall treat first those that are caused by
poverty; secondly, those that are committed from cupidity; and thirdly,
those that are the work of professional criminals.

Statistics show that a part of the economic crimes of violence are
committed from poverty, for their movement is influenced by the
fluctuations of economic conditions. We take from the German criminal
statistics the following table of the course of these crimes in the
different months of the year.


Germany, 1888–1892. [924]

Number of Crimes a Day in the Different Months, on the Basis of an
Average of 100 Crimes a Day throughout the Year.

=============+========+=========+======+======+====+=====+=====+=======+==========+========+=========+=========
   Crimes.   |January.|February.|March.|April.|May.|June.|July.|August.|September.|October.|November.|December.
-------------+--------+---------+------+------+----+-----+-----+-------+----------+--------+---------+---------
Robbery, etc.|  100   |   87    |  78  |  84  | 94 | 98  | 99  |  106  |    84    |  120   |   132   |   116
=============+========+=========+======+======+====+=====+=====+=======+==========+========+=========+=========


The highest figures are shown in the winter months when poverty is at
its height. (The slight increase from April to August, which appears
also in the case of a number of other economic crimes, I am unable to
explain.)

As we have seen in the statistics in Part One, the economic situation
also exercises its influence upon the movement of these crimes during a
period of years. We refer to them here while adding some others.


Germany, 1882–1898. [925]

======+=========================+==============================
      |                         |To 100,000 Inhabitants over 12
Years.| Price of Wheat and Rye  |   there were Convicted for
      |per 100 Kilogr. in Marks.+--------------+---------------
      |                         |   Robbery.   |  Extortion.
------+-------------------------+--------------+---------------
 1882 |         185.19          |     1.3      |      1.7
 1883 |         165.37          |     1.3      |      1.5
 1884 |         159.73          |     1.4      |      1.5
 1885 |         154.01          |     1.1      |      1.4
 1886 |         147.26          |     1.3      |      1.3
 1887 |         145.99          |     1.2      |      1.4
 1888 |         155.43          |     1.2      |      1.3
 1889 |         169.64          |     1.2      |      1.4
 1890 |         181.32          |     1.3      |      1.4
 1891 |         216.31          |     1.3      |      1.4
 1892 |         184.00          |     1.4      |      1.8
 1893 |         146.94          |     1.1      |      1.6
 1894 |         127.10          |     1.3      |      1.7
 1895 |         132.17          |     1.1      |      1.9
 1896 |         139.29          |     1.2      |      1.7
 1897 |         152.08          |     1.0      |      1.7
 1898 |         170.55          |     1.3      |      1.6
======+=========================+==============+===============


Although there are exceptions, the influence of the price of grain
makes itself felt. It should be remarked that the years 1889–1892 were
years of crisis.


France, 1825–1882.

In his study “De la criminalité en France et en Italie” Dr. Bournet
shows that in the period mentioned the maxima of assassinations
coincide with the years of economic crises, namely: 1839, 1840, 1843,
1844, 1847, 1867, 1876, and 1881. [926] It should be remarked that
assassinations are committed not simply from economic motives, but for
other reasons, whence it follows that the parallelism cannot be as
great as in the case of economic crimes that are not committed from
other motives.


Italy, 1873–1890.

Dr. Fornasari proves that economic events have a great influence upon
these crimes (see Part One, p. 143).


Prussia, 1854–1896.

Dr. Starke (see Part One, p. 64) and Dr. Müller (see pp. 76–78) have
proved that the changes of economic conditions are here also cause of
an increase or diminution of these crimes.



Although these data are less numerous than we might desire, they show
sufficiently that, in part, violent economic crimes are committed
because of poverty. [927]

Above I have shown how it happens that only some of those who live in
absolute poverty commit crime. We have only, then, to ask ourselves why
one commits a crime with violence and the other without violence. The
causes are of different kinds. Oftenest it is chance, i.e. opportunity,
that is the cause. No one uses violence if it is not necessary, and
since the opportunity of committing a successful theft is much greater
than that of committing an economic crime with violence, it is the
first that is most often practiced. Those who, when driven by abject
poverty, commit an economic crime with violence, when the opportunity
presents itself, are persons who lack neither the force nor the courage
necessary, and in whom the environment in which they live has not
inspired a great aversion to violence. Further, absolute poverty is so
powerful a factor that it often neutralizes the important influences of
education and environment.

From cupidity. The class of criminals who use violence or commit a
homicide from cupidity is very small. They furnish only a minor part of
violent economic crimes, the total number of which is not itself very
great. To show how far the influence of economic environment goes I
will cite some striking cases taken at random.

First. In 1892 a certain Scheffer was convicted at Linz (Austria) of
attempted murder. His crime was the following. He and his wife could
earn their living only by working hard. Chance brought a change. One of
their relatives, a young girl who had lost her father and mother a
short time before, came to live with them. The girl being very rich,
the condition of the Scheffers was entirely changed; from then on they
could live in abundance. Once habituated to this wealth they were
filled with the fear that their relative would marry and the money pass
to someone else. Little by little the idea came to them of persuading
the girl to make a will in their favor, and then killing her, an idea
which they rejected at first, but which nevertheless became stronger
and stronger. From unforeseen circumstances the crime was never
consummated, but stopped in the attempt. [928]

Second. In a little village upon the frontier of Austria and Bavaria
there was committed in 1893 a murder under the following circumstances.
One evening, while returning by himself along a lonely road, a rich
peasant who was in the habit of carrying a considerable sum of money
with him, was killed and robbed. It was proved that his servant was the
author of the crime. This man was a natural child, very poor, and had
had to work very hard all his life. Seeing his strength going he was in
great fear of being no longer able to earn a living. His sole enjoyment
in his monotonous and toilsome life was getting drunk on Sundays. Like
most of the inhabitants of his commune he was an ardent poacher. [929]

Third. In 1892 the wife of an employe of the post office was
assassinated in her dwelling in Berlin, and all her money stolen. The
criminals were two young workmen of 17 and 18 years of age, one of whom
knew by chance that the woman had savings. [930]

These three cases, types of hundreds of others, have in common the
opportunity which had excited, in an unusual degree, the cupidity of
the criminals, and the fact that these were very poor. Whatever other
causes may have entered in, it is certain that without the great
difference of fortune between the authors of the crimes and their
victims, the crimes would never have been committed.

Finally, we come to the influence of the environment upon the authors
of the crimes. As we have seen, the conditions under which criminals
are brought up are in general very unfavorable, and this is especially
the case with dangerous criminals. Consider, for example, the second
case (we know nothing of the environment of the criminals in the
first). What a life this murderer had behind him. The influences which
give most men their aversion to violence were entirely lacking. On the
contrary his environment had brutalized him. A natural child, he had
been brought up in very poor circumstances, and was stupefied by long
and toilsome work, with a weekly intoxication as his sole relaxation.
No one would assert that this same individual would have become an
assassin if he had lived under totally different conditions.

Or look at the third case. One of the guilty parties had been brought
up under unfavorable conditions (of the education of the other we know
nothing), both were forced, quite young, to earn their living and had
been thrown with bad companions, and one of them had already been
sentenced to imprisonment.

It is a mistake to believe that such a case is the exception instead of
being the general rule. He who takes the trouble to read the
biographies of these criminals knows that they have always been brought
up in an unfavorable environment, that they have suffered imprisonment
at an early age, and have fallen lower and lower. As far as I know
there are no statistics upon this subject except those of Dr. Baer in
his study already referred to. Out of 22 young assassins examined by
him 9 (40%) had had a bad education, 11 (50%) a defective education,
and only 2 (10%) a better education; 8 (36%) were orphans; 11 (50%) had
been brought up in very poor circumstances and were obliged while quite
young to contribute to the support of the family; 10 (45%) had grown up
in the streets of a great city and had thus been exposed to
demoralizing influences; and 13 (60%) had received an insufficient
primary education. [931]

The researches of Dr. Baer have to do with Germany, but they hold good
for other countries also. Take, for example, the opinion of Tomel and
Rollet, who are authors of great experience. In speaking of the
“criminal type” they say: “Well, no, this type does not exist, since we
always find the same conditions in the genesis of the criminal
temperament, and if these educational and environmental conditions had
been absent, the destiny of the little assassin might have been quite
different.” [932]

We have still to fix our attention upon one side of the environment in
which the authors of the crimes with which we are concerned at the
moment, have lived. They come generally from an environment where,

First, education often consists simply in the administration of a sound
beating to the child, a fact which habituates him to the idea that
violence is an ordinary act, especially as he sees the members of the
family often strike one another;

Second, the men ordinarily carry a knife, and do not hesitate to
threaten with it, or even to use it in case of a dispute. It is evident
that the influence of this upon character is great at the
impressionable age of childhood. The tendency toward violence, combated
among children of the well-to-do classes, is, on the contrary, often
strengthened among the children of the poor. If later chance places in
their way an opportunity to profit by violence they recoil from it less
than others. [933]

The authors of violent economic crimes spring nearly always from the
lower classes of the population; the exceptions are few in number. We
will take up one of these exceptions which has attained considerable
notoriety, an evident proof of the rarity of these cases.

In 1878 an old woman was murdered in Paris and all her papers of value
were stolen. It was proved that Barré, a business agent, and Lebiez, a
medical student, both of whom had passed their youth in a favorable
environment, were the guilty persons. This is one of those very rare
cases where objection can be made to the environment hypothesis with a
semblance of truth, but a closer examination shows that environment
nevertheless played its part in this frightful tragedy. The two
criminals, sprung from fairly well-to-do provincial families, having
gone to Paris, had been living in straitened circumstances. At the time
of their deciding to commit the crime their pecuniary condition was
very bad. In the second place, both had constant recourse to
prostitutes; and in the third place both were ardent speculators.
Because of his business Barré was in contact with those who gambled at
the bourse, and seeing men enrich themselves without work he entered
feverishly into speculation. He lost, drew his father into a new deal,
and was still unfortunate. In order to go on and retrieve his losses he
used money entrusted to him (his first crime), but still lost. Going
from one malversation to another he finally, in order to extricate
himself, had recourse to the crime narrated above. His accomplice was
found in nearly the same situation. [934]

The effect of environment is to be discerned, then, as easily in this
case as in those that have been referred to before. Limiting ourselves
to the principal influence alone, we see that if these individuals had
not been in contact with the world of speculation, their cupidity would
not have been excited to such a point that they were induced to commit
crime. Here the rôle played by chance in such cases clearly appears; if
they had been fortunate in their speculations they would never have
become criminals.

As with all crimes, the question presents itself as to how far
individual factors were active, in other words, do the individuals who
are guilty of such crimes differ from other men? Certainly, and that to
a considerable extent. But in granting this we do not, however,
recognize a qualitative difference between them and other men such as
would make them biologically abnormal. The motives which have induced
these persons to commit crime, are present, though only in small
measure, in everyone. Those who commit these crimes have by nature very
intense material needs; in the curve A D (see p. 534) they occupy the
places near D. As regards their social sentiments they are ranged near
the other end of the curve, and their repugnance to violence is very
small. Further, they have the necessary courage and strength. [935] If
we consider how little chance there is of finding all this united in
one individual, it will become clear that few individuals are
predisposed to these crimes, and when they are committed the criminal
is found in a special environment. In my opinion there can be no
question of individual factors, then; it is the environment that
decides here. There will be persons always and everywhere who run more
danger than others of committing such a crime; but it is the
environment which will decide whether they will commit it or not.

Professional criminals. The great majority of violent economic crimes
are committed by professional criminals. When an individual has fallen,
from whatever reason, into the world of professional crime, sooner or
later comes the time when he must use violence if he wishes to attain
his end. Joly has very well said in his social study, “Le crime”: “The
man who has formed the habit of breaking into houses and bursting open
safes, is forcibly drawn sooner or later to rid himself of witnesses
who surprise him at this work, or of a victim who might perhaps
recognize him.” [936] It cannot be asserted of these individuals any
more than of others, that they are born with a special tendency toward
assassination, a tendency to be explained by atavism, or something
approaching it. They have been living in an environment in which such
acts are considered as a necessary evil inherent in their trade. Driven
by the tendency to imitate, they do as others do. Certainly there are
those of them who do not commit these crimes, but that proves nothing,
for it may be that chance has favored them and they have never been
under the necessity of using violence, or they have less courage and
force than the average man, or, it may be, have an exceptional innate
aversion to violence.

As Professor Manouvrier remarks, the case would be entirely different
if such criminals killed without plausible motives, if they committed
murder without anything but the act in view. The facts show that this
is not so. Note the opinion of Flynt. “The taking of life is ... [a]
deed that he [the professional criminal] regrets more than he has been
given credit for. One thinks of the criminal as the man who has no
respect for life, as one who takes it without any twitchings of
conscience; but this is not the general rule. The business criminal
never takes a life, if he can help it.” [937]



We need not treat here of the causes which have led to the designating
of these acts as crimes; they are the same as those given above in
connection with economic crimes without violence. The harm done by
these crimes is naturally greater than in the case of crimes without
violence, since they put life as well as property in danger. It is
interesting to note here, once more, the dualism of ethics; many
primitive peoples consider these acts as crimes when they are committed
within the same group, but very honorable when once the act passes
beyond the limits of the group. [938] Further, with modern peoples this
difference still persists; colonial wars often resemble a colossal
robbery.




D. Fraudulent Bankruptcy, Adulteration of Food, and Analogous Crimes.

We reach now the last group of economic crimes, those which are
committed wholly, or in great part, by the bourgeoisie. The motives of
these crimes are not all the same; here too it is necessary to make
distinctions. The categories into which we must distribute the motives
leading to these crimes are analogous to those which lead to theft
etc., poverty and cupidity. And as in the case of theft it is necessary
to add a third category, that of the great criminals, who can be
compared with criminals by profession.

The first category may be compared with that of theft committed from
poverty; those who fall into this class are persons who, for one reason
or another, have seen their business decline, and not knowing any other
way to escape from their difficulties, hope to retrieve their losses
and save themselves by committing a misdeed. I take from Moreau’s “Le
Monde des Prisons” a typical case. After having described how a certain
R. had succeeded in setting himself up in business and had been
successful, the author speaks as follows. “Unhappily the panic caught
him among the first. His business became worse and worse. In a few
months he lost several thousand francs. Two of his traveling salesmen
ran off with their goods. Orders ceased coming in. It was failure,
dishonor. He fought, but was wrecked....” [939] Finally, in order to
escape ruin he committed a breach of trust; he was discovered and
convicted.

We cannot say that it is absolute poverty that drives these persons to
commit a crime, for generally they have enough left to keep them from
dying of hunger. And if not, they are generally members of families who
are in a position to keep them from the worst poverty. Further they can
try to provide for their wants by paid labor. Nevertheless these cases
are somewhat analogous to those of absolute poverty. Picture to
yourself the state of mind of one who has led a more or less
comfortable life, who has been independent, and enjoyed the esteem
granted to a man who is well-to-do, and who sees that the time is
approaching when all this will come to an end, and that there remains
nothing for him to do but accept some minor poorly paid employment, and
lead henceforth an existence that cannot satisfy him in any way.
Imagine also that chance throws in his way an opportunity to commit a
crime with good hope of success. It must be granted that we find here
very powerful determinants to crime.

This cause of crimes of this class is of an entirely social nature.
Under another mode of production, for example, under that of village
communities, the idea of committing such crimes could not arise. For
this reason we cannot say that social causes have often nothing to do
with the matter, but that it is the man’s own fault if his business
goes to pieces. This is certainly true at times; but it is the present
organization of society which makes it possible for a man to be in
charge of an enterprise which he is not fitted to conduct, while
another who is fitted for it cannot find employment for his talents. It
is only in a society where complete anarchy reigns in the economic
life, that it is possible for a man to think he is capable of directing
a business merely because he happens to have capital.

Let us now examine the other side of the question. What are the forces
capable of preventing these projects from being realized? First let us
ask, what is the environment in which many of these individuals who are
guilty of such crimes are brought up? Certainly they have learned that
one must be honest, that it is wrong to pick pockets, etc., and they
will not fail in this regard. But they have learned also that the
principal end in life is to grow rich, to succeed. Too often this is
contrary to the principle of probity. “Be honest, be honest, if
possible, but ... make money!” This is the principal rule imprinted
upon the minds of the children in certain bourgeois environments. It is
an honesty of a special kind that is inculcated, not a moral honesty,
but an honesty for the sake of one’s own interests. “Honesty is the
best policy” says the quasi-moral precept. Those whose probity has this
for a basis have only a weak check to prevent them from becoming
criminal, when the thought of the wrong act arises within them. They
remain honest so long as it is to their advantage, but woe to society
when this is no longer the case.

But further, the environment in which these persons have lived after
their youth has not contributed to reinforce the social sentiments, and
consequently those that are working in an anti-criminal direction.
“Every man for himself” is the principle of success in such an
environment. It is evident that the social sentiments must be strongly
opposed in their development if the maxim just given is that which
dominates. To act morally implies sacrificing one’s own advantage for
the sake of the general good. He who is compelled always to have his
own interests at heart can give very little thought to the interests of
others.

As in the case of all crimes, it is necessary with regard to these also
to put the question, are the individuals who are guilty of them, as
regards their innate qualities, like those who have lived and still
live under the same conditions? And as is the case with all crimes, the
answer here must be in the negative. Those who are guilty of these
crimes are, in general, those who are below the average in the strength
of their moral qualities. They are rather weak than bad; they are
conscious of the harm that they do to others and are ashamed of it, but
they are too weak to resist the pressure of circumstances. As always it
is the environment that is the cause of the crimes’ taking place; it is
the individual differences which explain in part who is the one to
commit them. Adapting the well-known sentence of Quetelet we may say,
“it is society that prepares the crimes, it is the men of inferior
moral caliber who execute them.” If the environment were entirely
different the men of inferior moral caliber would not be guilty of
crime.

It may be observed, perhaps, that if it is true that a special
predisposition on the part of the individual is unnecessary for the
explanation of these crimes, they ought to be more numerous than they
are. This is true enough, but it does not refute the opinion which has
been expressed. For, first, as is the case with all the others, these
crimes are more numerous than the criminal statistics show; second,
there are reasons why some men do not commit crime, although all
circumstances lead to it, and their moral condition does not prevent.
For example, there are those who, as a consequence of the struggle for
existence, have lost all energy and all courage, and give up the fight,
even the fight with dishonest weapons; others, prudent by nature, take
into consideration the fact that, bad as their situation may be, it
would be worse if the crime were discovered, etc.

Statistics prove that it is really the decline of business that is the
cause of a great number of bourgeois crimes. In the first part of this
work I have given some which show this correlation, namely:


Italy, 1873–1890.

For this country the statistics on this question (see p. 144) have been
compiled by Dr. Fornasari di Verce. This author has shown that with the
exception of fraudulent bankruptcy (an astonishing and inexplicable
fact), commercial crimes are strongly influenced by economic
happenings.


Prussia, 1854–1878.

Dr. Starke has proved that the curve of these crimes is parallel with
that of economic events (p. 65).

These statistics, to be sure, are not numerous, since the number of
crimes committed by the bourgeoisie is small, and the other economic
crimes, like theft, for example, are much more important, and hence
draw the attention of statisticians more. [940]

We come now to the second category; bourgeois economic crimes from
cupidity (as is always the case, the line of demarcation between this
group and the preceding one is not distinctly traced, there being many
gradations between the two). They are committed, not, as in the first
category, by those whose business is declining, but by those whose
affairs are more or less flourishing. The only motive, then, is
cupidity; what they get by honest business is not enough for them, they
wish to become richer. After what has been already said about cupidity
it is unnecessary to go into detail here. It has been shown that it is
only under certain special circumstances that this desire for wealth
arises, and that it is unknown under others. It will be necessary only
to point out the fact that although cupidity is a strong motive with
all classes of our present society, it is especially so among the
bourgeoisie, as a consequence of their position in the economic life.
This, then, is the first and most important cause of these crimes, a
cause which is not individual, but entirely of a social nature.

In the second place, the opportunity to commit these offenses
undetected is enormous (I refer especially to the adulteration of
food). In general the consumer cannot judge whether the merchandise is
pure or not, and in most cases there is no inspection by experts, or
else it is worthless, since the experts are named by the producers
themselves.

In the third place, we have to ask ourselves, in what way does the
environment in which these persons live exercise an influence upon
their social sentiments? We have already called attention to this point
some pages above, and can be brief therefore. This environment tends to
weaken the social sentiments which might act as a check upon very
egoistic acts.

Considered from the point of view of the consumer the adulteration of
food products is a grave crime, for it injures the health and may even
endanger the life. But what moral impropriety will be seen in it by a
producer who derives great profits from the exploitation of children,
or who, by a corner in grain, causes a great increase in the price of
bread? Is there, sociologically speaking, a difference between these
two groups of acts? Certainly not; the one is as harmful as the other,
nay, the last two probably more harmful than the first.

This kind of crime must be the despair of those who seek for some
biological anomaly of the criminal as the primary cause of crime, for
here the anomaly forms almost the rule. Dr. Puibaraud, in his
“Malfaiteurs de profession”, rightly says: “The adulteration of food is
carried on under our eyes, at our very doors, and we are so used to it
that we say nothing. They put fuchsine in our wine, margarine in our
butter, chicory in our coffee, tallow in our chocolate, and we swallow
it all in perfect good humor. What is the use of protesting? So things
are, and ‘business could not be carried on’ if they gave us really pure
food. So we swallow it all without gagging or moving a muscle. Provided
we are not poisoned—too quickly—we profess ourselves satisfied.” [941]

Everyone knows that the adulteration of food is enormous. If anyone has
any doubts let him read the reports of the chemists upon a product
whose adulteration is easy, milk, for example. His doubts will
disappear rapidly; at least half of the milk is adulterated. It is only
the adulteration of food products that constitutes a legal offense, but
the adulteration of other articles does not differ from this when
considered from a sociological point of view, and it is unnecessary to
say that there too the adulteration is enormous.

There are, to be sure, manufacturers and merchants who are not guilty
of such acts; first, because certain articles cannot be adulterated;
second, because in certain branches the oversight in the interests of
the consumers is very rigorous; third, because certain producers find
it more advantageous to be honest, knowing that thereby they will
procure a large body of regular customers. These three reasons have
nothing moral in them, though there is a fourth reason which affects
certain producers, namely that they have scruples against such
practices. [942]

Let us consider once more the curve of the individual differences.
Those persons who should be placed between A and B are those who, if
the conditions we have named are present, will commit without scruple
misdeeds of the kind we are considering. The great average class,
between B and C are those who, in general, are not guilty of acts
prohibited by law, but who probably do things which in reality do not
differ much from these, and, in any case, are not permissible by the
moral code of the consumers (for commerce has a morality of its own).
These are the persons who get rid of their merchandise by means of all
sorts of tricks and dodges, are silent about the bad qualities of their
wares and exaggerate the good ones; these are the dairymen who put
water in their milk (“for absolutely pure milk is not wholesome”, they
say); the doctors who make visits when they are no longer necessary;
these are those who.... But let us stop; we could fill pages with the
practices of those whose honesty is not proof against trial. [943]

In going from B to C the moral aversion to such acts, observed in
individuals, becomes gradually greater, and the danger that they will
commit such practices diminishes, and we finally approach those who
should be placed between C and D, those who are in no way guilty of
such acts.

As is always the case with economic crimes, it is, then, the
environment that is the cause of these offenses, while individual
differences explain in part who are the authors of them.

We come now to the last category of the criminals of this group, to the
great criminals, to those who throw themselves into gigantic
enterprises while knowing beforehand that these will certainly or
probably fail, or those who make great purchases of stock, and
afterward cause a rise in price through the dissemination of false
news, etc.

If there is any kind of crime that is the consequence of the economic
environment exclusively, this is the one. Such crimes can arise only in
a time like ours, with its insatiable thirst for gold, with the
unlimited opportunity to deceive the public, greedy for great profits.
A superficial knowledge of economic history is enough to make it plain
that the bourgeois crimes, and especially those which we are now
discussing, can be committed only under an economic system of the kind
that ours is.

This should make those anthropologists reflect who wish always to find
the causes of crime in the man himself and not in his surroundings.
Naturally the originators of such deeds are marked out by
characteristic traits. But there is no reason to admit that persons
with such dispositions could not have been born also under a different
economic system. Yet such crimes do not appear under any other mode of
production.

What is the kind of persons who commit these crimes which society has
prepared for? We note first that chance must have prepared such
individuals in the proper environment, for a crime of this kind. If
they were in the class of agriculturists, for example, the idea of
committing it would not have occurred to them; it is only in a special
environment that such crimes can be committed.

These people are characterized, in the first place, by excessive
cupidity. In this regard they come high in the curve. Their prodigality
is without limits; once they have executed a great coup they buy
splendid palaces, give costly fêtes, support several mistresses, etc.
An individual of this type, Arton, had a mistress who cost him 300,000
francs in one year; he needed a million to cover his annual expenses.
[944] This is why they are not content with the large incomes which
they could obtain honestly; they wish to surpass others in wealth,
being ordinarily very vain. [945]

We have said that such individuals would probably have succeeded in
securing large incomes honestly, for all are of a high order of
intelligence. In following their machinations we are astonished by
their perspicacity and their cleverness. Plans like theirs could never
have been conceived and still less executed by men of mediocre
intelligence. [946]

“I believe,” says Professor Morselli in his preface to Laschi’s work
which we have quoted, “in fact, that no common intelligence is needed
to cover up malversations for a long time, to organize clever swindles,
outrageous frauds and bankruptcies, exploitations of the credulous
public. It needs no more talent, perhaps it needs less, to accomplish a
great number of useful and honest things, to make a so-called discovery
or invention. We have, as I have said elsewhere, a fetishism with
regard to genius, talent, higher intelligence. The effort of mental
energy which is required by the complex planning and execution of a
financial crime does not differ, as far as cerebral dynamics are
concerned, from the effort demanded by an action that is perfectly
regular from a moral point of view.” [947]

In the third place, this class consists of persons who, as to the
intensity of their moral sentiments, take the lowest place. What an
ordinary criminal does in a small way, they do on a gigantic scale;
while the former injures a single person, or only a few, the latter
bring misfortune to great numbers. And they do it with indifference,
for the disapprobation of honest men does not touch them.

As I have already shown elsewhere, brought up in no matter what
environment, such individuals would not excel in the strength of their
social sentiments. But I have added that, nevertheless, the influence
of the environment of these persons is very great. We do not know much
of the circumstances under which they have passed their youth. At least
Laschi makes no mention of them in “Le crime financier”, the principal
work upon this class of misdeeds. It is more than probable that their
moral education is totally lacking, or has been only very superficial.
Theresa Humbert, for example, had already been instructed by her father
in the art of swindling on a large scale.

On the other hand we know the environment in which they have generally
passed the rest of their lives. They belong to the world of
speculation, an environment which has very special ideas upon economic
morals. In most of the cases of this kind, facts are brought out which
show that the moral ideas in these circles differ much from those of
the rest of mankind. It is evident that those who commit these crimes
go farther than the morality of their world permits. But it takes great
moral perspicacity to distinguish in this field the demarcations
between what is permitted and what is not, and it is just this
perspicacity that some persons lack. This is why most criminals of this
kind, when they are brought into court, say with sincere conviction
that they are innocent, that they have done nothing that is
incompatible with morality. [948]

Then, speculation etc. is one of the infallible means for killing all
social sentiments; it is egoism pure and simple. Can we be astonished
that some of these individuals [949] in such an environment enter into
conflict with the penal law? It seems to me not. Nor is there any
reason to grant that they are abnormal from a biological point of view.
So even the Italian school is forced to admit that the stigmata found
elsewhere cannot be pointed out in these individuals. [950]
Furthermore, in this case we can hardly speak of atavism. It may be
that our ancestors were great offenders, but it is not probable that
they ever were guilty of swindles of this kind.

It is not necessary to speak fully of the reasons which cause these
acts to be classed as crimes. They are harmful to the regular progress
of capitalism and consequently are threatened with penalties. The
punishment of the adulteration of food-stuffs, on the contrary, is a
consequence of the opposition of the consumers to one of the harmful
effects of this system.

In this connection it is interesting to note, first, that the penalties
prescribed for these crimes are relatively light as compared with those
for ordinary economic crimes, like theft, for example, especially when
we reflect that the harm done by them is much greater; second, that the
number of punishable acts is very limited as compared with those which
really deserve punishment. As Baccaro observes in his work, “Genesi e
funzione delle leggi penali”, it is these crimes which show clearly the
class character of the penal law. [951]








CHAPTER III.

SEXUAL CRIMES.


Most authors who treat of the correlation between criminality and
economic conditions, have devoted their attention to economic crimes
especially, and have had little or nothing to say about sexual crimes.
Man’s sexual instincts, they say, have nothing to do with the economic
life, they are a factor apart, and accordingly there is no relation
between criminal sexuality and economic conditions.

We flatter ourselves that we shall be able to show that their opinion
is erroneous, that a relation between sexual criminality and economic
conditions does exist, although it is by nature less direct than that
between economic crimes and the mode of production.

Having already remarked that the social forms of the sexual life
(marriage and prostitution) are, in the last analysis, determined by
the mode of production, we will not return to this topic. And it does
not fall within the province of this work to speak of the relation of
the intensity of the sexual life in general to economic conditions.
From history we see that the sexual life plays now a greater, now a
smaller part. It would be hard to admit that the causes of these
changes are within man and not outside of him, particularly when very
evident causes are to be found in the environment. Who does not see
that the intensity of the sexual life of the upper classes of Rome of
the decadence is explained by the exaggerated luxury, the idle
existence of this group, and the dependent position of a part of the
women (slaves).

In our present society the relation between the sexual life and
economic conditions is equally clear. Everyone knows that the sexuality
which occupies a very great place in that part of the bourgeoisie which
passes its life in idleness and prodigality, is the consequence of this
manner of living. On the other hand the low intellectual condition of
the proletariat is the cause of a sexual life much more intense than it
would be if the environment permitted a harmonious development of the
whole nature. Engels, in his “Condition of the Working-class in
England”, says of the English proletarians, what is applicable to the
workers in other countries also. “Next to intemperance in the enjoyment
of intoxicating liquors, one of the principal faults of English
working-men is sexual license. But this, too, follows with relentless
logic, with inevitable necessity out of the position of a class left to
itself, with no means of making use of its freedom. The bourgeoisie has
left the working-class only these two pleasures, while imposing upon it
a multitude of labors and hardships, and the consequence is that the
working-men, in order to get something out of life, concentrate their
whole energy upon these two enjoyments, carry them to excess, surrender
to them in the most unbridled manner.” [952]

Further the dependent economic position of woman in our present society
is also a factor of the increase of the intensity of the sexual life
(especially prostitution).

However, it is not this question but sexual criminality upon which we
must fix our attention. Here also we must divide the crimes into
groups, as they differ too much among themselves to be treated of
together. We shall take up in order, then: A. Adultery; B. Rape and
indecent assault upon adults; C. Rape and indecent assault upon
children.




A. Adultery.

It has been said, “the history of property is also that of theft.” In
the same way we may say that the history of monogamy is also that of
adultery, or in other words, that there is no monogamy without
adultery. There must be, therefore, powerful and constant causes
occasioning this offense. As we have seen above when we were setting
forth briefly the history of marriage, adultery by the man was a
permitted act at different stages of the social development. [953] If
we ask why men committed this permitted act, but one reason can be
alleged; they are not monogamous by nature. On the part of the woman
the same act constituted, on the other hand, most often a very serious
offense, threatened with the most severe penalties, which did not,
however, prevent adultery on her side also. The cause is not different
for the two sexes; women, too, are not monogamous by nature, though
perhaps more nearly so than men.

From what we have just said the etiology of this crime is fixed. The
only difference between the present and the past is that adultery by
the man also is punished in our time—there is no change in the etiology
of the crime. It may be said that the fundamental cause of adultery is
to be found in the nature of man, then, and that it is thus
anthropological and not social. I cannot admit this view of the matter
any more than I can believe that the ultimate cause of theft is the
necessity of eating in order to live. If the fundamental cause of the
offense of which we are treating is to be found in man, it would be
present always and everywhere without reference to the environment.
Sociology shows however, that this is not so. Up to a certain degree of
social development men and women alike have been free in this respect;
in other cases it is only the woman who is forced to remain true to her
husband; and at times both have been compelled to remain faithful.
Consequently, for one who does not consider society as an immovable
body, but sees that everything is in motion, the fundamental cause of
this crime is to be found in the structure of society itself, which in
certain cases, prohibits a man from satisfying his natural
inclinations. When the polygamous tendencies are stronger than the
pressure of society a crime is committed.

If we consulted only the criminal statistics we should hardly ever meet
with adultery. It is unnecessary to add that the penal laws dealing
with this matter are so drawn up that a prosecution for adultery almost
never takes place; it goes without saying, however, that in reality the
offense is very common.

In the first place we must look into the question of the classes of
society in which the offense occurs oftenest. Though there are no
statistics on the matter I believe that we shall not be far wrong in
saying that adultery takes place oftenest in that part of the
bourgeoisie that lives in idleness, often also among the proletariat,
and least often among the intellectual bourgeoisie and the petty
bourgeoisie. In seeking for the causes of this fact we see clearly that
they cannot be found in the man himself, for the individuals forming
these classes do not differ as to their innate characteristics.
Consequently, these causes must be found in the environment; the
following being the principal ones.

First. The more marriage is contracted for convenience the greater the
danger of adultery. This is one reason why adultery is more common
among the “upper ten thousand”, where marriage is often a commercial
affair, and why it is less frequent among the intellectual bourgeoisie,
in which there are more marriages of inclination.

Second. The more frivolous and trifling the life any class leads, the
more frequent will adultery be in it. This is another reason why
adultery is frequent among the idle rich, and less frequent in the
intellectual class and the petty bourgeoisie.

Third. The more the social causes of marriage are felt in a certain
class, the greater the moral aversion to adultery. This is one reason
why this offense is found less often among the petty bourgeoisie than
in the working class.

Fourth. The greater the number of marriages concluded for purely
physical reasons without any intellectual reasons entering in, the more
numerous will be the cases of adultery. This applies especially to the
proletariat, among whom most of the marriages are contracted from
affection, but where, because of lack of culture, there is often no
possibility of intellectual communion. When this harmony is lacking it
comes about that the difficulties of life, so great in this class,
cause an estrangement from which infidelities frequently result.

Finally, let us consider briefly the question of which individuals in
the different classes are guilty of adultery. The predisposition to
polygamy is not the same for all. In the second place, the sexual
instincts are much more intense in some cases than in others. In the
third place the environment in which one has lived is not the same as
that of another, and opportunities do not occur in the same way for
each. The joint action of these causes explains sufficiently why one
commits the offense in question and not another.

In setting forth the etiology of adultery we have been giving the
reasons why it has been designated as a crime. Little by little the
conception of marriage has been modified in consequence of the social
changes that have taken place; there is a growing number of persons who
consider the life in common permissible only when both parties desire
it without being constrained by the law. The partisans of this opinion
disapprove of adultery, but for different reasons from others, who
consider it as the infraction of an acquired right. Professor Ferri
formulates this new morality as follows. “What is vile about adultery
is not that it is an assault upon individual property, it is the
disloyalty of the act, the trickery and hypocrisy of it.” [954]

While finding adultery immoral the adherents of this opinion believe
that the law has no right to interfere. Even the persons who do not
share their point of view believe that the penal code should cease to
concern itself with this crime. Hence it comes, among other things,
that the laws are so drawn that prosecutions are very rare. It is
probable that adultery will disappear from the list of offenses.




B. Rape and Indecent Assault upon Adults.

In his work, “Genèse normale du crime”, Professor Manouvrier expresses
himself as follows upon the crime of rape. “Every normally constituted
man would be a born violator if the sexual appetite could find no other
means of satisfaction than rape. The crime is rare, however, and we
know why; there are women for the ugliest and the poorest. However,
famine may come; there is also opportunity, and many devils capable of
leading into temptation the brute that every man is at his birth. For
the ‘criminologists’ must not delude themselves upon this point if they
wish to make criminal anthropology truly scientific. If we were to take
a well-born child of a distinguished European family, and isolate him
from his birth from all the influences of environment except those
strictly necessary for the preservation of his life, we do not know
what strange beast he would turn into. On the other hand we do know
that behind our acquired polish our natural brutality still persists.”
[955] Here in a few words is the environment theory applied to the
origin of the most serious sexual crimes. Let us consult some facts to
see whether the theory is correct.

First of all it must be remarked that this crime is not the act of a
pervert but of a brute. It is important not to forget this since
perversion does play a part in the crimes which we shall take up under
C. Some authors do not make a distinction between these two kinds of
crimes, which prevents their giving a really fundamental treatment of
the etiology of them.

Let us see what the movement of this crime teaches. Its curve in the
different months shows that it rises towards spring, to reach its
maximum in summer, after which it regularly decreases, reaching its
minimum in winter. An example of this is given in the following table,
which includes also crimes committed against children. [956]


France, 1827–1869.

=========+=============================+==============
         |Sexual Crimes Committed Upon |   Days of
         +--------------+--------------+  Conception
Months.  |   Adults.    |  Children.   |  1863-1871.
         +--------+-----+--------+-----+--------+-----
         |Absolute|  %  |Absolute|  %  |Absolute|  %
         |Figures.|     |Figures.|     |Figures.|
---------+--------+-----+--------+-----+--------+-----
January  |   584  | 7.09| 1,106  | 5.57| 2,603  | 7.84
February |   563  | 6.84| 1,041  | 5.23| 2,661  | 8.02
March    |   643  | 7.82| 1,366  | 6.88| 2,608  | 7.85
April    |   608  | 7.39| 1,700  | 8.56| 2,887  | 8.69
May      |   904  |10.98| 2,175  |10.95| 3,000  | 9.21
June     | 1,043  |12.67| 2,585  |13.03| 3,018  | 9.08
July     |   860  |10.45| 2,459  |12.42| 2,911  | 8.76
August   |   794  | 9.64| 2,208  |11.13| 2,742  | 8.25
September|   653  | 7.93| 1,773  | 8.93| 2,810  | 8.46
October  |   523  | 6.46| 1,447  | 7.29| 2,625  | 7.91
November |   514  | 6.24|   983  | 4.95| 2,620  | 7.89
December |   534  | 6.49|   939  | 5.05| 2,665  | 8.02
=========+========+=====+========+=====+========+=====


The movement of sexual crimes does not tell us much about their
etiology. It is plain that the opportunity of committing them occurs
much oftener in summer than in winter, and the chance of catching the
criminal “in flagrante delicto” is also much greater during the hot
months. Even without statistics we should know that the temptation to
these acts is greater in warm weather, and further, the rise of
temperature towards spring probably increases the sexual tendencies.
But all this does not explain the origin of this class of crimes, for
if it is true that the sexual tendencies in man are increased by the
rise of the temperature toward spring, this affects the sexual life in
general, and not the sexual criminality alone (as is shown by the
column of the days of conception).

In the same way we learn little of the etiology of these crimes from
their movement in the course of the years. In the first part of this
work we have given some statistics on this question, which we
recapitulate here with additional data.


England.

The author of the English criminal statistics of 1899 fixes attention
upon the fact that the maximum of sexual crimes was reached in 1893 and
1894, when the price of wheat was very low (p. 48).


France, 1825–1878.

As Professor Ferri shows in his study upon the influence of
temperature, [957] the curve of rape committed upon adults presents
some resemblance to that of economic events, the years that were
economically bad coinciding with the minimum figures for the crime in
question. Thus the unfavorable years of 1835–37, 1846–47, 1865–68
brought a diminution of rapes committed upon adults, and the favorable
years of 1832–35, 1847–50, 1857–59 an increase. Although there are some
exceptions, the influence of the economic situation is indubitable.


Italy, 1873–1890.

Dr. Fornasari di Verce says that indecent assaults increase with the
improvement in economic conditions, and vice versa (p. 143). On the
other hand, Dr. Colajanni proved for the different parts of Italy
(1875–1880) that a greater consumption of meat did not lead in most
cases (22 out of 35) to an increase in the number of indecent assaults
(op. cit., pp. 501–504).


New South Wales, 1882–1891.

As we have seen in Part One (p. 144) Dr. Fornasari di Verce has shown
that in this country sexual crimes increase in prosperous years, and
vice versa.


Prussia, 1854–1896.

As to this country, Professor von Oettingen gives, for the years
1854–1859 and 1862–1871, some figures which show a slight connection
between the price of grain and sexual crimes (Part One, pp. 53, 54).
Dr. Müller also shows (see the tables pp. 77, 78 and pp. 80, 81) that
economic conditions exercise an influence upon sexual crimes; thus, for
example, the years 1857–1859 were characterized by cheap grain and high
figures for sexual crimes; the same was true of the years 1863–1866 and
1869. On the contrary the years 1854–1856 and 1861, show a high price
for grain and low figures for the crimes in question. There were,
however, some exceptions; during the crisis of 1873–74 the sexual
crimes did not decrease, and in the following years the correspondence
of the curve of these crimes with that of the economic situation is no
longer to be noted.

The data upon the relation between the economic situation and these
crimes are not as numerous as those upon economic crimes, and there are
also many exceptions. With some reservations, however, we can say that
an improvement in economic conditions tends to increase the crimes in
question. However, this does not teach us much with regard to the
etiology of them; the statistics of births have long since shown us
that the sexual life is more intense during the periods of economic
prosperity, than during those of depression. [958] Better nourishment
renders the sexual instincts stronger, without its being necessary that
they should manifest themselves in a criminal manner. The proof of this
is furnished by those who are sufficiently nourished both in good times
and bad and are yet not guilty of these crimes. (For statistical proofs
see the statistics given later.)

We must then try to discover the true crime-producing factors in other
statistical data. First let us inquire whether married or unmarried
persons are more often guilty? As we have seen above, German criminal
statistics are the only ones which give us absolutely certain
information on this point. These show (see p. 454) that at all ages
bachelors, widowers, and divorced men are more often guilty of sexual
crimes than married men, and at certain ages much more so.
Unfortunately these statistics do not distinguish the rapes committed
upon adults from those committed upon children. The data of Dr. J.
Socquet give us some slight information. [959]


France, 1876–1880.

=============+=================================
             |To 1,000,000 of the Population in
Civil Status.|  Each Group there were Charged
             |      with Rape upon Adults
-------------+---------------------------------
Bachelors    |                8
Married men  |                3
Widowers     |                2
=============+=================================


Marriage, then, tends to diminish the number of these crimes. The
economic life having, in its turn an influence upon the number of
marriages the relation between this life and the crimes in question is
clear. If the economic situation of many persons did not prevent their
contracting marriage at the period of life indicated by nature, these
crimes would be much less frequent. As Dr. Augagneur says: “Our laws
and physiological exigencies do not harmonize.”

A second question is, what is the class of the population that commits
these crimes? As we have seen, the statistics of Italy and Austria show
(see pp. 437, 438) that it is almost exclusively the poor who are
guilty of sexual crimes. In Italy 92.1% are indigent or have only the
strict necessaries of life; in Austria 91.2% are without fortune, and
only 0.2% are well-to-do.

The statistics of the professions of convicts in Germany (see p. 441)
show also that those who are arraigned for these crimes are especially
working-men, and particularly unskilled laborers (among whom the
statistics include also white-slave traders, professional criminals,
etc., see p. 442). Unfortunately these statistics do not distinguish
between sexual crimes committed upon adults and those committed upon
children. The following table shows that the number is greater for the
first than for the second of these crimes. [960]


France, 1836–1880.

======================================+=================+=================
                                      |   1836-1840.    |   1876-1880.
                                      +-----------------+-----------------
                                      |    Percentage of Total Number
                                      |   Accused of Rape and Indecent
                                      |      Assault Committed Upon
                                      +-------+---------+-------+---------
                                      |Adults.|Children.|Adults.|Children.
--------------------------------------+-------+---------+-------+---------
Engaged in the cultivation of the     |       |         |       |
  soil, laborers, farm servants, etc. |   38  |    33   |  52   |    39
Workers engaged in handling the       |       |         |       |
  products of the soil, iron,         |       |         |       |
  wood, etc.                          |   30  |    26   |  25   |    25
Bakers, butchers, cabinet-makers, etc.|    5  |     4   |   4   |     4
Tailors, wigmakers, hat-makers        |    7  |     8   |   3   |     6
Merchants                             |    3  |     5   |   3   |     5
Sailors, carters, porters             |    6  |     5   |   4   |     3
Domestic servants and keepers of inns,|       |         |       |
  lodging houses and cafés            |    3  |     4   |   3   |     4
Liberal professions                   |    5  |    11   |   4.5 |    10
Vagrants                              |    3  |     4   |   1.5 |     4
                                      +-------+---------+-------+---------
                                      |  100  |   100   | 100   |   100
======================================+=======+=========+=======+=========


Although this table by itself has little value, since the comparative
figures for the population in general are lacking, it suffices to show,
by comparison with the preceding tables, that the crime with which we
are concerned is committed by working-people especially. The criminals
in a large number of the cases are rural, as the last table proves to a
certain extent, and as further appears from the following. [961]


France, 1846–1880.

=================+==============+==============
                 |  1846-1850.  |  1876-1880.
   Residence.    +--------+-----+--------+-----
                 |Absolute|  %  |Absolute|  %
                 |Numbers.|     |Numbers.|
-----------------+--------+-----+--------+-----
Rural population |   804  |  74 |  412   |  67
Urban population |   264  |  24 |  160   |  27
Residence unknown|    16  |   2 |   38   |   6
                 +--------+-----+--------+-----
Total            | 1,084  | 100 |  610   | 100
=================+========+=====+========+=====


Even when we take account of the fact that the rural population in
France is more numerous than the urban, we still see that the crime in
question is committed in the country especially. [962]

We must further inquire what is the part of the proletariat that is
guilty of rape upon adults? The answer must be that it is that which
forms the lowest stratum of society. As preceding statistics have shown
us (see pp. 427–430, 432), the number of illiterates or of those who
know only how to read and write, is very great among the authors of
sexual crimes. The following table gives us data more detailed and
concerned only with rape upon adults. [963]


France, 1875–1884.

=======================+========+=======+=====================
                       |        |       |   To 100 Persons
      Education.       |Absolute|   %   |upon the Conscription
                       |Numbers.|       |    Lists (1880).
-----------------------+--------+-------+---------------------
Unable to read or write|  319   |  28   |        13.8
Able to read and write |  802   |  71   |         --
With a higher education|   12   |   1   |         --
=======================+========+=======+=====================


Upon the basis of this table we have the right to say, then, that this
crime is almost never committed by persons having more than a primary
education.

This fact destroys the theory that the “human beast” exists independent
of environment; for if such were the case, this crime would be
relatively as frequent among more highly developed persons as among
those that are less so. This table proves what is always forgotten by
criminal anthropologists, that a man becomes a brute only under certain
fixed circumstances, and commits then acts that would be repugnant to
him if he lived in a different environment.

Those who commit these acts come from the strata of society in which,
in consequence of their living conditions, the sexual life is
considered from a purely animal point of view. What is the environment
in which the children of the lowest classes grow up, and what is the
sexual morality that they derive from it? The simple truth is that
there is no sexual morality for them. In consequence of the detestable
housing conditions (compare what was said upon this subject in
connection with prostitution) and of the bad society with which they
are thrown, the children are thoroughly conversant with the sexual life
in its most bestial manifestations. Their attention is fixed upon the
sexual life at an age at which it is still a closed book to children
brought up in a wholesome environment. As Dr. Lux says in his excellent
study upon sexual crimes, “Need, misery, and vice are the natural
surroundings of the children of the proletariat, and especially of the
lower proletariat; they form the environment out of which the child
draws his first and most lasting impressions; they are the school from
which they derive the lessons of a system of ethics which is in marked
contrast with the ethics of progressive humanity. Conceptions of moral
restraints can hardly be awakened in the offspring of the lowest ranks
of the proletariat; on the contrary, so far as the sexual sphere is
concerned, they are suppressed by the undisguised sexual intercourse of
parents, other adults, and prostitutes, with whom the children are
continually coming into contact....” [964]

One of the consequences of the lower position of woman in our present
society is that man considers women as destined to submit to his sexual
will. This is especially the case in the lower strata of the
population, where the woman is often only a means by which the man may
satisfy his desires.

Finally, alcoholism is still to be added as a criminogenous factor.
Above (pp. 509 ff.) we have seen that there are many chronic alcoholics
among the authors of these crimes; in Germany 23.3% and 20.5%, in
France 51.5% and 55.7%, in the Netherlands 10.84%, and in Wurtemberg
36.3%.

There is still another way in which alcoholism figures in the etiology
of these crimes. At a certain stage of intoxication the sexual
instincts are stimulated, while the moral forces are weakened. [965] So
in the cases where a sexual crime has been committed in a state of
drunkenness we may be sure that alcohol has been one of the principal
factors of it. The following figures give us some information on this
point.


England.

In his report to the international penitentiary congress at Brussels,
Dr. M. W. C. Sullivan shows, as the result of an investigation, that
more than 50% of the sexual crimes were caused by alcoholism, and that
acute alcoholism is especially active in the case of rape upon adults.
[966]


Austria, 1896–1897.

Out of 179 cases of rape, etc., there were 46 (25.7%) committed in a
state of drunkenness. [967]


France.

In his report at the Congress mentioned above, Marambat says that 6.6%
of the rapes and indecent assaults have been committed in a state of
intoxication. [968]


Netherlands.

The criminal statistics show that 11.82% of those convicted of sexual
crimes commit them under the influence of alcoholic drinks. [969]


Sweden.

Sigfrid Wieselgren, director general of the penitentiary establishments
of Sweden, in his report to the Brussels Congress gives a table which
shows that about 36% of those guilty of indecent assault were drunk at
the time of the crime. [970]


Switzerland, 1892–1896.

According to the criminal statistics, 21.5% of all the sexual crimes
are due to alcoholism. [971]



To sum up, we see that the causes of these crimes are the economic
condition which prevents some individuals from marrying at the natural
age, the inferior social position of woman, alcoholism, and above all
the sexual demoralization and lack of civilization in the lowest strata
of society.

It is plain that not all the individuals who live in this environment
are guilty of the crimes in question. The sexual instincts do not have
equal force at all ages, nor with all individuals. There are
individuals who have very pronounced sexual propensities, others who
are almost indifferent in this respect, and between the two extremes
lies the great majority. It is only for the first class that the danger
of a crime against morals is great, for the others it is less so. If
the opportunity (rape is almost always an “occasional” crime) presents
itself to persons already predisposed, the moral check to restrain them
is lacking. If they had lived in another environment, this act would be
repugnant to them, as statistics prove; for this crime is not committed
by persons of the other classes, although there are naturally
proportionally more persons with strong sexual instincts among them.
The opportunity to commit these crimes is happily not very frequent. As
Voltaire has expressed it, “Rape is a crime as hard to prove as it is
to commit.”



We must add a few words upon the history of this crime and the causes
that have led to its being classified as such. As Dr. Post (the
principal authority upon this question) has shown, among many primitive
peoples rape is only considered as a detriment to the property of the
man. [972] It is only little by little as the position of woman
improves, and her individuality is recognized, that rape is considered
as a grave encroachment upon the liberty of the woman, and that it is
punished as such.




C. Rape and Indecent Assault upon Children.

An examination of the etiology of these crimes shows that in great part
the individuals who are guilty of them belong to the same category of
criminals as those who commit sexual crimes upon adults. If they seduce
or outrage a child and not a woman it is from accidental reasons
(opportunity, lack of bodily strength, etc.); they are brutes who wish
to satisfy their sexual instincts at any price; they are not, however,
perverts. Although there is a quantitative difference between the man
who violates an adult and one who commits this act upon a child (the
latter being grosser and more egoistic than the former), there is no
qualitative difference between the two so far as the majority of the
criminals of whom we are speaking are concerned. We should only repeat
ourselves if we treated of the etiology of these crimes more fully.

As with the crimes of which we were speaking above, there is with
crimes against children also, a great increase toward spring, the
maximum being reached in the month of June, after which there is a
decrease, with the minimum in winter. [973] The statistics given for
France show also that in this country the periods of economic
prosperity bring an increase of these crimes, and the periods of
depression a decrease. [974] And it is probably the same with other
countries. As has been said also of the crimes against adults, all this
shows us very little of the etiology of these crimes, since the
intensity of the sexual life in general rises and falls in accordance
with the economic situation.

Here also the married men play a smaller part than the unmarried and
divorced; the poor classes show a larger number of crimes than those
that have property (see p. 616); the illiterate, and persons who know
how to read and write simply, show also proportionately higher figures
than persons with a higher education, [975] and alcoholism again takes
its place among the causes of this crime. [976]

A minute comparison of the statistics of sexual crimes committed upon
adults and of those upon children shows that a part of the latter are
of a character quite different from the former. By comparing, for
example, the statistics of the civil status of persons arraigned, we
see that the number of married men and widowers is proportionately much
greater in the case of crimes against children than against adults. The
following table shows this: [977]


France, 1876–1880.

==============+==================================
              |To 1,000,000 of the Population of
              |Each Group there were Arraigned
Civil Status. |        For Rape Upon
              +---------------+------------------
              |    Adults.    |    Children.
--------------+---------------+------------------
Bachelors     |      8        |       37
Married men   |      3        |       25
Widowers      |      3        |       50
==============+===============+==================


A comparison of the statistics of the occupation of the two groups of
these criminals (see p. 616) shows that in the crimes upon children,
the liberal professions show twice as many as those committed upon
adults. The same is true of merchants. [978]

The figures with regard to education show that the illiterate are about
equally numerous in both groups of criminals, but that the percentage
of those who have a higher education is 5 in the case of crimes upon
children, and barely 1 for those upon adults. [979]

While, as we have seen, sexual crimes upon adults are chiefly committed
in the country, the cities and manufacturing centers occupy a much more
important place in the statistics of those upon children, as the
following table proves. [980]


France, 1876–1880.

===========+================================
           | Rape and Indecent Assault Upon
           +---------------+----------------
Residence. |    Adults.    |   Children.
           +---------------+----------------
           |       %       |       %
-----------+---------------+----------------
Rural      |      67       |      53
Urban      |      27       |      43
Unknown    |       6       |       4
===========+===============+================


Contrary to what we find with regard to sexual crimes against adults it
is also the departments with the great cities which, in comparison with
the rural districts, give the highest figures. [981]

It appears from an examination of these data that sexual crimes upon
children and those upon adults have, in part a different etiology. Many
sexual crimes upon children are committed by persons who could also
satisfy their desires with adults, but abuse children instead. These,
then, are cases of sexual perverts.

A thorough examination of the causes of this perversion would be ill
placed in the midst of our investigation of the social etiology of
crime, for they are principally of a pathological nature. However
prostitution should be mentioned as contributing more to sexual
demoralization than any other cause. As Dr. Després says in his work
“La prostitution en France”, “Physicians think that rape [982] is an
aberration of the genetic faculty and that this crime is more often the
result of satiety than of deprivation of the natural exercise of the
genital functions.” [983]

Dr. Ladame expresses himself thus. “All the causes which divert the
genetic faculty from its natural end may lead to crime, and among these
causes prostitution plays, without doubt, the principal part.” [984]

It is plainly difficult to show by figures the degree of importance of
prostitution in the etiology of sexual crimes. The Swiss statistics,
which try, though very imperfectly, to record the causes of crimes, say
that 5.3% of the sexual crimes are caused by prostitution. [985] It is
unnecessary to say that this figure is too low.

We may add in conclusion that it is almost always upon the children of
the poor that these crimes are committed. The children of well-to-do
parents are so well guarded that crimes against them are the rare
exceptions. [986]








CHAPTER IV.

CRIMES FROM VENGEANCE AND OTHER MOTIVES.


Besides economic, sexual, and political criminality, there is still a
fourth category of crimes, the motives of which are quite diverse. We
shall treat, A. Crimes from vengeance, and B. Infanticide. The first
group is important both quantitatively and qualitatively; the second,
especially, qualitatively. The crimes committed from other motives are
either very rare, or very insignificant, or may be explained by the
same causes as those included under A, and hence may be passed over in
silence. [987]




A. Crimes Committed from Vengeance.

In a sociological work like ours we need not consider the psychology of
vengeance. [988] For our subject it is sufficient to show that the
feeling is innate in everyone, although in different degrees. As soon
as one person injures another, whether bodily, or in his interests, or
his honor, the desire to retaliate in one way or another immediately
appears. If this desire transforms itself into act, this act calls
forth a stronger reaction on the part of the opposing party, etc. It is
this that is called the instinct of vengeance. [989]

We must then begin by treating the causes calling forth feelings of
revenge, and by fixing our attention upon the two principal categories
of causes, those which spring from the economic life, and those which
are due to the sexual life.

We shall speak first of the causes that are due to the economic life.
The fundamental principle of the mode of production in which we live is
competition, strife—in other words, doing injury to others. So there
are innumerable cases in which the desire for revenge is excited by the
economic life. Many sociologists extol the beauty of this struggle and
pretend that its effect upon society is excellent. We shall refrain
from examining the truth or falsity of this statement; for the matter
in hand we need not concern ourselves with the fortunate victors, but
simply with the vanquished. After the exposition of the present system
of production it is superfluous to show all the opposing economic
interests and the feelings resulting therefrom; we shall mention a few,
and the others will be easily understood.

Imagine, for example, the state of mind of a small retailer who finds
himself totally ruined by the competition of a large department store
in the neighborhood; of that of working-men suffering great privations
during a strike, who see themselves supplanted by others, who think
only of their immediate interest in acting as strike-breakers. Or
imagine, again, the innumerable cases in which questions of inheritance
awaken vengeful feelings. And side by side with all this, picture the
economic life of village-communities where all the economic interests
were parallel, and where consequently the economic life engendered
neither envy nor jealousy. Anyone who grasps the enormous difference
between these two modes of production, will understand also how the
feelings of revenge are excited by the present economic system. [990]

In the second place, how far are vengeful feelings aroused by
sexuality? [991] As Sutherland remarks in his “Origin and Growth of the
Moral Instinct”, there are no peoples who are not more or less jealous
in sexual matters, [992] but great differences are to be observed in
this respect. While Nansen, for example tells how the Eskimo women are
almost ignorant of sexual jealousy, [993] there are other peoples among
whom the woman is killed by her husband if another man evinces any
regard for her. [994]

The facts show that the greater the power of the man over the woman,
the greater also is the sexual jealousy of the man, a jealousy which,
among other things, manifests itself in the very severe punishment of
adultery. [995] He who has a right to something wishes to keep it for
himself and does not tolerate injury to it on the part of anyone else.
When the man considers the woman as his chattel, or when he has great
power over her, sexual jealousy is strengthened by the feelings
connected with property. These latter feelings were more predominant
among the primitive peoples than true sexual jealousy, a proof of which
is that fact that among many of these peoples the law of hospitality
required putting the wife at the disposal of the guest.

From the present form of marriage (as among many primitive peoples) it
follows that each party has a right with relation to the other. [996]
The violation of this right is considered as a serious injury and gives
rise to a desire for revenge. This phenomenon is not natural, but
historical. If the present state of society did not necessitate an
artificial stability in sexual relationships, if the man and his wife
were economically independent, they would not believe that they had
rights over each other. [997]

Here is the first bond between sexual jealousy and the social
environment, but there is also a second, though a more remote one,
namely, that it is with those who have a gross conception of the
relations of man and wife, that revengeful feelings arise after love
disappears. Those who, because of the environment in which they live,
have formed a different idea of the relation between man and wife,
while feeling the most violent grief, remain strangers to the desire
for revenge. He who knows that neither love nor sympathy can be bidden,
knows also that a right in this matter can bring no change in the
feelings, and must remain only a nominal thing; he sees only the action
of fate, where the brute sees an evil will. This is one reason why the
number of crimes of passion is smaller among civilized people than
among the partly civilized.

We must notice, further, one kind of crime of passion, the revenge of a
woman seduced and then abandoned. Besides sexual jealousy there are, in
these cases, other motives playing their part. Often the woman has not
given herself for love alone, but also with the prospect of a marriage,
or a betterment of her economic position. It is not sexual vengeance
that is the sole motive here then, but also vengeance for economic
reasons. [998] Further the prohibition of inquiring into the question
of paternity may also enter in. [999]

After having pointed out the two principal categories of causes that
awaken revengeful feelings we must now enquire why, with certain
individuals, these feelings are translated into acts. Many
criminologists prefer to find environment of small importance in these
crimes and the individual factors the predominant ones. Let us see
whether the facts will uphold this theory. To begin with let us ask
what the movement of these crimes teaches us.

As statistics show, they increase towards spring, reach their maximum
in summer, after which a decrease follows with the minimum in winter,
as the following table proves. [1000]


Germany, 1883–1892.

=============+======================================
             |              Crimes.
             +--------------------------------------
             |On the basis of a supposed Average of
             |100 Crimes a Day the Daily Average for
             |    the Different Months would be
             +-------------------+------------------
             | Serious assaults  |    Homicides
-------------+-------------------+------------------
January.     |         75        |        88
February.    |         78        |        84
March.       |         78        |       100
April.       |         84        |        95
May.         |        102        |       108
June.        |        116        |       113
July.        |        119        |       118
August.      |        116        |       133
September.   |        110        |       124
October.     |        106        |       106
November.    |         93        |        93
December.    |         80        |        78
=============+===================+==================


Some authors seek for a remote explanation, when there is one near at
hand: in summer persons are more in contact with each other, a fact
which gives opportunity for disputes, and an increased danger of
consequent crimes.

We may sum up the principal data upon the movement of these crimes in
relation to the economic situation (given in Part One of this work) as
follows.


England, 1840–1890.

Fornasari di Verce draws attention to the fact that crimes against
persons (represented in great part by crimes of vengeance) increase in
times of economic prosperity and vice versa (see p. 144. See also the
data of Mayr, pp. 43 and 44).


Bavaria, 1835–1861.

Mayr shows for this period that crimes against persons increase when
the price of grain falls and vice versa (see pp. 40–42).


Italy, 1873–1890.

According to Fornasari di Verce there is a diminution of homicides and
assaults when economic conditions grow worse, and vice versa (see p.
143).


New South Wales, 1882–1891.

The same author says that homicides and assaults increase, while minor
offenses against persons decrease, when economic conditions grow worse
and vice versa (see p. 144).


Prussia, 1854–1896.

Dr. Starke and Dr. Müller show that the crimes we are considering
increase when economic conditions improve, and decrease when they grow
worse (see pp. 66 and 83). However, they show at the same time that
these phenomena did not take place at the beginning of the period
observed by them. Later they follow the regular course. [1001]


Canton of Zürich, 1853–1892.

For the period mentioned Meyer proves that crimes against persons
increase when economic conditions improve (see p. 69).



Examining these results we observe that the crimes in question increase
in the periods of prosperity, and vice versa; but we see at the same
time that there are also noteworthy exceptions (New South Wales and
France), and that in Germany in the last 20 or 30 years, this tendency
is no longer present. [1002] It is not difficult, it seems to me, to
explain why these crimes increase in periods of prosperity. Men are
thrown then into contact more frequently, they live a little more for
amusement, and consume (and this is certainly one of the principal
reasons) more alcohol than usual. Some authors see in this movement of
crimes against persons a natural law, according to which criminality
would be a fixed quantity, manifesting itself in economic crimes in
periods of depression, and in crimes against the person in periods of
prosperity.

As I have already said more than once this theory is erroneous. If it
were really true that an improvement of the economic situation
inevitably brought about an increase of crimes against persons, the
class of individuals who are always in fairly good circumstances would
also be largely guilty of these crimes. Statistics show us the
contrary.

Thus we arrive at the very important question, what are the classes of
the population which are especially guilty of these crimes? As the
statistics already given show they are the poorest classes (see pp. 437
ff.). In Italy, for example, 89.8% of those who commit homicide, and
91.1% of those guilty of assault, were indigent or had only the bare
necessities of life, though these form but 60% of the population. The
same is true of Austria, and the statistics of occupations gives a
similar result for Germany (see pp. 441 and 442).

The statistics that give information upon the degree of education of
these criminals are more interesting still. As we have seen above, only
0.1% of those guilty of assault had a higher education, while 40.5% of
these criminals were illiterate, and 59.4% knew only how to read, or to
read and write. In France from 1896 to 1900 the completely illiterate
constituted 16% of those guilty of assault, and 15% of the assassins,
while in the general population there were only 4.5% who did not know
how to sign their names. In Italy only 1% of the assassins and only
0.6% of those guilty of assault had a higher education, 99% and 99.4%
respectively were illiterate or knew only how to read and write. These
are striking figures.

In this connection let us stop for a moment to consider the geography
of these crimes, and place beside the figures on this point those of
illiteracy. We will begin with a table of figures for homicide and
assaults followed by death, for some of the countries of Europe. [1003]


==============+========+==================+=======+===========
              |        |   Homicides and  |       |
              |        | Assaults followed|       |
Country.[1004]| Years. |    by Death to   |Years. |Illiteracy
              |        |      100,000     |       |    %.
              |        |   Inhabitants.   |       |
--------------+--------+------------------+-------+-----------
Italy         | 1880-84|       70.0       |  1882 |   57.43
Spain         | 1883-84|       64.9       |  1889 |   68.10
Hungary       | 1876-80|       56.2       |  1880 |   59.70
Austria       | 1877-81|       10.8       |   ,,  |   40.10
Belgium       | 1876-80|        8.5       |   ,,  |   21.66
Ireland       | 1880-84|        8.1       |  1882 |   30.00
France        |   ,,   |        6.4       |   ,,  |   13.10
Scotland      |   ,,   |        4.4       |   ,,  |   11.00
England       |   ,,   |        3.9       |  1883 |   14.00
Germany       | 1882-84|        3.4       |1881-82|    1.54
Holland       | 1880-81|        3.1       | 1880  |   11.50
==============+========+==================+=======+==========


No one will deny the striking parallelism between these columns, the
highest figures for homicide being found where there are also the
largest figures for illiteracy. As we have seen already, however,
international statistics have inherent defects. The following figures
are better in this regard: [1005]


United States.

========================+====================+==========
                        | Number of Homicides| Illiteracy
      Birthplace.       |     to 100,000     |     %.
                        |    Inhabitants.    |
------------------------+--------------------+-----------
Sweden, Norway, Denmark |         5.8        |    0.42
Germany                 |         9.7        |    0.57
England and Scotland    |        10.4        |    2.50
Austria                 |        12.2        |   16.73
Ireland                 |        17.5        |   41.65
France                  |        27.4        |   43.60
Italy                   |        58.1        |   51.77
========================+====================+===========


We have here also, then, a striking parallelism. We will now take up
the geography of homicide, etc., in different parts of one country;
some of the faults inherent in the geography of crime are thus
eliminated.


Germany, 1893–1897. [1006]

======================+======================+==============+========================
                      |   Number of Persons  | Percentage of|
                      | Convicted for Serious|  Illiterates |  Percentage of Votes
 States and Provinces.|  Assaults to 100,000 |   among the  | Given to the Socialist
                      |  Inhabitants over 12 |   Recruits   |    in the Election
                      |  Years of Age.[1007] |  1892-1893.  |     of 1898.[1008]
----------------------+----------------------+--------------+-----------------------
Bavaria               |          391         |      0.03    |          18.0
West Prussia          |          334         |      4.01    |           4.9
Posen                 |          326         |      1.72    |           1.7
East Prussia          |          265         |      0.98    |          18.3
Silesia               |          252         |      0.57    |          22.3
Baden (Grand Duchy)   |          250         |      0.02    |          19.1
Hesse                 |          248         |      0.03    |          33.9
Alsace-Lorraine       |          237         |      0.30    |          22.7
Pomerania             |          227         |      0.22    |          17.2
Westphalia            |          223         |      0.08    |          17.7
Germany               |          219         |      0.38    |          27.1
Prussia               |          211         |      0.59    |          24.1
Rhine Province        |          201         |      0.08    |          15.0
Wurtemberg            |          197         |      0.04    |          20.3
Saxony (Province)     |          185         |      0.07    |          34.0
Brandenburg           |          184         |      0.15    |          35.6
Hesse-Nassau          |          161         |      0.14    |          30.9
Hanover               |          146         |      0.04    |          25.6
Sleswick-Holstein     |          106         |      0.10    |          38.9
Saxony (Kingdom)      |           82         |      0.01    |          49.4
======================+======================+==============+========================


The parallelism between the first two columns is undeniable; the states
and provinces with low figures for illiteracy show also a small number
of assaults, and vice versa, with some exceptions—notably Bavaria. The
reason why Bavaria is at the head of the list is undoubtedly because of
the alcoholism that prevails there.


United States, 1890–1900. [1009]

=============+===========+=============
             | Number of | Percentage
             |Inhabitants|     of
             | in 1900 to| Illiteracy
             |Each Murder|     in
   States.   |  (Annual  | Population
             |  Average  |  Over 10
             | from 1890 |  Years of
             | to 1900). |Age (1900).
-------------+-----------+-----------
Nevada       |     1,086 |      12.8
Colorado     |     2,141 |       5.2
Montana      |     2,704 |       5.5
Texas        |     2,986 |      19.7
Mississippi  |     3,001 |      40.0
Florida      |     3,367 |      27.8
California   |     3,519 |       7.7
Delaware     |     3,849 |      14.3
Louisiana    |     3,859 |      45.8
Alabama      |     3,966 |      41.0
Wyoming      |     4,206 |       3.4
Maryland     |     4,250 |      15.7
Arkansas     |     4,300 |      26.6
Utah         |     4,855 |       5.6
Tennessee    |     4,957 |      26.6
Washington   |     5,079 |       4.3
Oregon       |     5,235 |       4.1
Kentucky     |     5,394 |      21.6
Georgia      |     5,817 |      39.8
Idaho        |     5,992 |       5.1
S. Carolina  |     6,064 |      45.0
Virginia     |     6,079 |      30.2
Kansas       |     6,253 |       4.0
Nebraska     |     6,360 |       3.1
N. Carolina  |     6,645 |      35.7
United States|     7,649 |      13.3
Rhode Island |     8,241 |       9.8
Missouri     |     8,582 |       9.1
S. Dakota    |     8,924 |       4.2
N. Dakota    |    11,005 |       6.0
W. Virginia  |    11,021 |      14.4
Indiana      |    11,037 |       6.3
Minnesota    |    11,105 |       6.0
Iowa         |    11,147 |       3.6
Michigan     |    11,810 |       5.9
Connecticut  |    12,443 |       5.3
Ohio         |    12,523 |       5.2
Wisconsin    |    13,435 |       6.7
New York     |    14,195 |       5.5
Illinois     |    15,306 |       5.2
New Jersey   |    15,697 |       6.5
Pennsylvania |    20,169 |       6.8
Massachusetts|    29,222 |       6.2
Maine        |    38,581 |       3.3
New Hampshire|    45,732 |       6.8
Vermont      |    57,274 |       6.7
=============+===========+==============


Although less complete than in the preceding table, the parallelism
here is nevertheless striking; all the states below the average for
illiteracy, except one, rank low also in the number of murders. There
are however some very remarkable exceptions to the general tendency,
some states with small figures for illiteracy having nevertheless high
figures for homicide. It is not possible for me to explain the cause of
this, the details with regard to this country being lacking (it is very
remarkable that the newest states are those that constitute the
exceptions). The relation between these crimes and illiteracy is
undeniable however.


Italy, 1880–1883. [1010]

=================+========================+==================
                 |   Simple Homicides     | Illiteracy among
                 | and Assaults Followed  | the Conscripts
   Provinces.    |       by Death         |     (1896).
                 | to 100,000 Inhabitants.|     %[1011]
-----------------+------------------------+------------------
Girgenti         |          36.5          |      65.15
Campobasso       |          29.5          |      56.35
Avellino         |          29.5          |      56.07
Caltanissetta    |          29.0          |      58.02
Cantanzaro       |          27.3          |      65.76
Trapani          |          26.1          |      58.49
Cosenza          |          25.7          |      44.17
Palermo          |          22.3          |      45.21
Naples           |          22.2          |      45.15
Potenza          |          21.4          |      55.63
Caserte          |          21.3          |      43.11
Aquila           |          20.7          |      38.56
Calabria         |          19.5          |      43.95
Rome             |          17.7          |      35.33
Salerno          |          17.4          |      60.37
Catania          |          16.7          |      64.04
Chieti           |          16.6          |      57.44
Sassari          |          16.1          |      53.09
Leghorn          |          14.0          |      15.68
Teramo           |          13.8          |      61.37
Arezzo           |          13.4          |      38.60
Ancona           |          13.1          |      36.24
Lucca            |          11.9          |      18.49
Messina          |          10.9          |      49.52
Forli            |          10.2          |      49.63
Grosseto         |          10.2          |      61.42
Bari             |          10.1          |      64.60
Ravenna          |          10.1          |      43.23
Perugia          |          10.0          |      48.99
Cagliari         |           9.7          |      68.08
Pesaro e Urbino  |           9.4          |      53.94
Massa e Carrara  |           8.3          |      34.46
Macerata         |           7.5          |      43.43
Italy            |           7.0          |      36.65
Lecce            |           6.9          |      58.57
Ascoli Piceno    |           6.7          |      53.81
Pisa             |           6.0          |      35.86
Treviso          |           5.9          |      24.95
Cueno            |           5.5          |      18.68
Alessandria      |           5.2          |       9.86
Turin            |           4.9          |      19.71
Florence         |           4.3          |      35.16
Genoa            |           4.2          |      24.16
Mantua           |           4.0          |      25.06
Udine            |           4.0          |      11.08
Venice           |           3.9          |      31.92
Bologna          |           3.9          |      24.68
Sienna           |           3.9          |      48.56
Piacenza         |           3.5          |      37.82
Padua            |           3.0          |      34.32
Porto Maurizio   |           3.0          |      13.64
Novara           |           2.9          |      12.18
Bergama          |           2.8          |      27.00
Vicenza          |           2.5          |      31.41
Brescia          |           2.5          |      20.72
Emilia           |           2.4          |      33.08
Como             |           2.3          |       8.89
Pavia            |           2.3          |      21.39
Verona           |           2.3          |      31.86
Ferrara          |           2.2          |      36.97
Modena           |           1.8          |      35.41
Belluno          |           1.7          |      25.62
Cremona          |           1.6          |      12.71
Milan            |           1.4          |      18.85
Parma            |           1.1          |      31.68
=================+========================+===================


In this country also the parallelism is undeniable; almost all the
provinces with low figures for illiteracy have also low figures for
criminality, and vice versa.


To conclude, here are some figures with regard to


The Netherlands, 1901. [1012]

==============+======================+==================
              |    Assaults to       | Illiteracy among
  Provinces.  | 100,000 Inhabitants. | the Conscripts.
              |                      |        %
--------------+----------------------+------------------
Drenthe       |         15.9         |       7.2
Limburg       |         13.7         |       3.6
North Brabant |         12.9         |       4.1
Groningen     |         12.6         |       2.8
Zeeland       |          8.3         |       2.3
Overijssel    |          8.2         |       3.3
Gelderland    |          8.2         |       1.7
Netherlands   |          7.6         |       2.3
Friesland     |          7.3         |       2.3
Utrecht       |          6.9         |       1.1
South Holland |          4.2         |       1.1
North Holland |          3.8         |       1.2
==============+======================+==================


We have here then a confirmation in a general way of the rule proved
for other countries.

In view of all the preceding data we must conclude that it is the less
civilized persons who commit crimes of this class. How is this to be
explained? This is what we shall proceed to examine.

The first reason is that the more civilized a person is the less
revengeful feelings arise when some one injures him. The more the
motives of actions are appreciated, the less the desire for revenge
springs up. A child wants to revenge himself even upon an inanimate
object that has hurt him; it is almost the same with uncivilized
peoples, who so rarely take account of the motives of human action. It
is not so long ago that men took vengeance upon maniacs, a thing which
could not happen today.

In the second place, when the idea of revenge arises in a civilized man
he is more in a position to restrain himself than the uncivilized; he
is less impulsive; he knows that later he will repent of his act, and
that it may have disagreeable consequences for him.

In the third place civilization inspires a great aversion to acts of
violence.

Thus we come to the correlation between these crimes and the education
of the poor. The child is often moved to revenge, there is no inner
check to restrain his passions. When his education has been neglected
he runs, as his age advances, more danger than others of being guilty
of these crimes. And then children are very imitative. If we had good
statistics with regard to violent criminals we should see that they
almost always spring from surroundings in which violence is common. All
authors who are especially concerned with this matter are in agreement
on this point. [1013] The fact that parents among the lower classes use
blows as a means of instruction has for its national consequence that
when the children are grown they themselves have no fear of making use
of violence. [1014]

One further observation must be made here. Many persons think it quite
natural that one should not have the right to avenge himself for an
injury. Sociology, however, teaches us quite otherwise. Among primitive
peoples revenge, instead of being a thing prohibited, is a sacred duty.
Little by little vengeance, at first unlimited, became confined to “an
eye for an eye, a tooth for a tooth”; this in turn was replaced by the
so called “compensation”; and this in its turn yielded to penalties
inflicted by an authority superior to both parties. [1015]

If we enquire which are the countries where homicides and assaults are
committed most frequently we find that they are the most backward, and
thus give a picture of time past. Here we have in mind especially
Sicily (see the table with regard to Italy some pages higher) and
Corsica (while between 1880 and 1884 there was an annual average of 6.4
homicides to the million inhabitants, the figure for homicides in
Corsica was 110.2). Nothing is more mistaken than to believe that we
have here a question of race. As Professor Tarde remarks (see the
quotation on pp. 109–110), there have been times when the people of
these countries were much less violent than the northern peoples, now
so little given to this kind of crime. These two islands have so high a
figure because the “vendetta” is still universal there, and because it
is considered as a duty. [1016]

Although in less degree, the case is almost the same with the lower
classes of other countries as regards this type of crime. There are
those who from their manner of life most resemble our distant
ancestors. They are not, at least so much as other classes of society,
instilled with the idea that they have no right to avenge themselves
personally. On the contrary it is often considered an act of cowardice
to allow an insult or an injury to pass without taking revenge. This is
why the police are often resisted and their interference considered as
an intrusive meddling with matters with which they have no concern.

Such, in my opinion, are the principal reasons why the less civilized
classes are guilty of these crimes, and thus we are given an idea of
their etiology.

In the first table upon the relation between illiteracy and serious
assaults (Germany) we added also the percentage of votes given to the
socialists. As the table shows the percentage of these votes is in
general smaller in the localities where the kind of crime of which we
have been treating is most frequent; and vice versa. It is, then,
evident that there is a correlation between the two phenomena, and this
is easily explained. In the working circles in which socialism is
beginning to make its way, there is growing little by little, an
interest in things other than those which formerly occupied the
working-men in their leisure hours. They begin to become civilized and
to have an aversion to the coarser amusements. At the same time the
feeling of solidarity is awakened in them, and thus a powerful moral
check is created.

It was especially the figures for the crimes of vengeance that we
placed beside those for the votes given to the socialists, since the
relation between the two phenomena stands out very distinctly. This
correlation, however, holds for criminality in general, for almost all
the countries with a large number of socialist voters show also fairly
low figures for criminality, and vice versa. Nevertheless this
correlation is not as great for other crimes as for those which we are
at present considering, which is explained by the fact that most of the
criminals who are guilty of them are not much like other criminals,
especially those who have no respect for property (criminals from
poverty excepted). These last, greedy of pleasure, and always looking
out for their own interests, are those who, as regards the intensity of
their social instincts, occupy the last place. All this is inapplicable
to criminals by violence; they are not always really wicked, and after
their crime they often show a sincere repentance. Socialism exercises
no influence upon the category of individuals from whom the economic
criminals (from cupidity) are recruited, persons, that is to say, who
think only of their own interest, and show themselves insensible to a
movement for the well-being of the whole working class.

We have still to speak of one question which is sometimes put in
treating of this subject. If it is true, says some one, that it is
principally in consequence of their ignorance and their lack of
civilization that the lower classes commit the crimes in question,
these crimes must little by little present themselves less often, for
the development of these classes is improving, even if only gradually.
Now criminal statistics do show a gradual diminution in these crimes.
Homicide, the gravest form, has continually decreased in England,
Switzerland, France, and Sweden (where it has been reduced to a very
small figure), and in Italy (where a considerable diminution has been
shown). [1017] If we had criminal statistics much more ancient than the
existing ones it would be shown that this crime has decreased
enormously compared with remote epochs. The progress of civilization in
the lower strata of society is very slow, and criminal statistics are
all of relatively recent date.

Germany is, as far as I know, the only country where there has been any
considerable increase in these crimes (except those against life) in
the last twenty years. This exception does not, in my opinion,
invalidate the rule. The lack of civilization among the lower orders is
not the sole cause of these crimes; the innumerable conflicts
engendered by the present social system are also a cause. Besides, the
impulse given by the economic development in Germany during this period
has hardly been equalled in other countries; it has seen its population
grow and become congested, and conflicts increase in like proportion,
[1018] a cause sufficient to neutralize the civilization which brings
it about. Further there is the possibility that the police and the
courts have been more efficient during this period, so as to make the
increase of crime seem greater than it really is. [1019] Finally,
alcoholism is increasing, and may also neutralize the effect of
civilization. [1020]

We come, then, to one of the most important causes of this kind of
crime, namely alcoholism. Not only is chronic alcoholism demoralizing
(as we have seen on pp. 509 ff.), but drunkenness at the acute stage
makes a person more disposed to commit acts of violence, and at the
same time less able to control his instincts and passions. Further, the
degree of civilization reached by the individual has a great influence
upon his conduct when he is intoxicated; the civilized man is then much
less dangerous than the man without education. Dr. Grotjahn puts it as
follows: “The development of the moral consciousness is not without
influence upon the harmlessness or danger of intoxication. Persons in
whom the sense of responsibility for the consequences of their actions
has been sharpened by education, whether they owe this to their
teachers or their parents or to their own experience, in case they
become intoxicated to the point of having their minds clouded, will
still always keep a remnant of their power of judgment, which will hold
them back from violent and disastrous actions. On the other hand, in
the case of persons who lack all moral training, the scanty moral
restraints which check their native impulses most quickly disappear.”
[1021]

An examination of the physiological process caused by large doses of
alcohol not coming properly within the scope of a sociological work
like this, it is sufficient to show that great quantities of alcohol
undoubtedly do have this effect. [1022] We shall accordingly pass on to
the question of the correlation between violent crime and the acute
stage of alcoholism.

There are different ways of attempting to settle this question. In Part
One we have seen that some authors have tried the dynamic method,
Fornasari di Verce, for example, showing that in Italy, Great Britain,
Ireland, and New South Wales, these crimes increase and diminish with
the consumption of alcohol. Professor Ferri shows that during the years
1849–1880 the increase and diminution of cases of assault in France
coincide with the success and failure of the vintage. [1023]

Another method consists in inquiring what day of the week assaults are
most frequent. If the abuse of alcohol is really an important factor in
the etiology of these crimes more of them must be committed upon
Sunday, Saturday, and Monday, for the abuse of alcohol is greatest on
these days. The following table throws some light on the matter. [1024]


Number of Assaults Committed on Different Days.

=========+==========+==========+=========+===========+==========
         |          |          |Canton of|           |
         |  Vienna  |Korneuburg| Zürich  |Düsseldorf.|  Worms
         |(1896-97).|(1896-97).| (1890). |           |(1896-98).
---------+----------+----------+---------+-----------+----------
Sunday   |    68    |    72    |   60    |    121    |   142
Monday   |    49    |    12    |   22    |     32    |    57
Tuesday  |    27    |    11    |  }      |      9    |    34
Wednesday|    19    |    14    |  }41    |      9    |    34
Thursday |    19    |    15    |  }      |      5    |    35
Friday   |    18    |     4    |  }      |      4    |    27
Saturday |    28    |    11    |   18    |     35    |    37
=========+==========+==========+=========+===========+==========


The figures and the thesis agree, then, perfectly. It is plain, to be
sure, that we cannot charge all the cases falling on Sunday to alcohol,
since people come together more on that day, and hence the danger of a
conflict is greater, but most of the Sunday cases are certainly due to
alcohol.

Other authors compare the geography of these crimes with the
consumption of alcohol. Professor Aschaffenburg, for example, in the
study already quoted, points out the fact that in Germany the countries
with the greatest number of assaults are also those where there is the
largest consumption of alcohol. [1025]

However, although these indirect methods are not without value, it
seems to me that since they contain so many elements of uncertainty
they yield to the direct method. [1026] It is for this reason that I
shall follow here especially the direct method and shall indicate the
percentage of those who have committed these crimes when they were in a
state of intoxication. Though making use of this direct method I do not
think it infallible, but it is less liable to error than the others.
The especial weakness of it is that the persons who are accused pretend
in extenuation that they committed their crimes in a state of
drunkenness. Good statistics do not rely solely upon the statements of
the prisoners, but also upon the facts brought out at the trial. And
then, as Professor Löffler remarks, all those arraigned are not acute
enough to simulate a state of drunkenness, and there are even those
who, although addicted to overindulgence in alcohol, will deny that
they were intoxicated, either from shame, or for fear of a more severe
punishment.

Most criminal statistics do not concern themselves with this subject,
and even those that do are less detailed than we might wish.
Nevertheless they are sufficient, I believe, to prove the correlation
in question.


Austria, 1896–1897. [1027]

==================+====================================
                  |Percentage of Convicts who Committed
                  |      their Crimes in a State
     Crimes.      |          of Drunkenness.
                  +------------------+-----------------
                  |     Vienna.      |  Korneuburg.
------------------+------------------+-----------------
Rebellion         |       77.7       |      70.0
Malicious mischief|       63.4       |      43.5
Threats           |       56.8       |      46.7
Serious assaults  |       54.1       |      56.4
==================+==================+=================


Baden (Grand Duchy), 1895.

In 1895 64% of the cases of rebellion and 46% of the assaults were
committed in a state of inebriety. [1028]


Belgium, 1872–1895.

Out of the 2,045 convicts who entered the central prison at Louvain
from 1874 to 1895, 344 or 16.8% were drunk at the time of committing
the crime; of the 130 sentenced to hard labor for life 53, or 40.7%; of
the 88 condemned to death 38, or 43.1%. [1029] If we consider that a
very great number of these criminals were guilty of economic crimes,
and doubtless did not commit these in a state of intoxication, the
percentage of those who must have committed crimes of vengeance in such
a condition becomes very large.


France.

At the penitentiary congress at Brussels Marambat reported that out of
a total of 787 convicted of homicide, assault, etc., studied by him,
there were 260 or 33% who committed their crimes in a state of
drunkenness. [1030]


Hungary, 1897.

At the same congress Dr. J. Fekete stated that in 1897, 75% of the
25,000 street brawls, 66% of the 1,574 cases of resistance to the
authorities, 50% of the 13,564 serious assaults, and most of the
homicides were committed in a state of intoxication. [1031]


Massachusetts, 1894–1895. [1032]

    Crimes.                  Percentage of Crimes
                             Committed in a State
                             of Intoxication.
    Malicious mischief              70.0
    Homicide                        64.7
    Threats and violence            59.6
    Murder                          25.0
    Resistance to officers          19.0


Norway, 1886–1889. [1033]

    Crimes.                  Percentage of Prisoners
                             who had Committed their
                             Crimes in a State
                             of Intoxication.
    Resistance to officers          81.8
    Homicide                        66.6
    Assault                         55.0
    Threats                         40.0


Netherlands, 1901.

The criminal statistics of the Netherlands being among the few that
give any information upon this point, the following table is of real
importance: [1034]


    Crimes.                  Percentage of Convicts
                             who Committed their
                             Crimes in a State
                             of Intoxication.
    Serious assaults                51.88
    Resistance to officers          58.04
    Malicious mischief              41.69
    Threats                         39.77
    Assaults                        31.27


Sweden, 1887–1897.

During this period, out of 2,020 convicted of crimes against the
authorities, 1,648, or 81.5%, had committed their crimes in a state of
intoxication, and 4,358, or 67.4% out of 6,464 convicted of murder,
homicide, and other crimes of violence. [1035]


Switzerland, 1892–1896.

The official statistics for these years tell us that 34.8% of the
assaults and homicides were caused by alcohol. [1036]

It cannot be claimed, of course, that none of these crimes would have
been committed if their authors had not been drunk, but everyone will
agree with me that these high percentages show that acute alcoholism is
a very important cause.



We have now reached the end of our remarks upon the etiology of these
crimes, and have shown that the principal causes are, first, the
present structure of society, which brings about innumerable conflicts;
second, the lack of civilization and education among the poorer
classes; and third, alcoholism, which is in turn a consequence of the
social environment. [1037]

What part is played in these crimes by the so-called individual
factors? It seems to me that it is like that which the individual
factors play in other crimes—they explain in part which are the
individuals that commit the crimes, but they do not explain why the
crimes are committed.

This is totally contrary to what many criminologists claim, namely that
it is especially the effect of individual factors that is seen in these
crimes. Statistics prove the inaccuracy of this. If it were true these
crimes ought to appear equally in all classes of society, which, as we
have seen, is not the case. A choleric person naturally runs more
danger of committing such a crime than one who is phlegmatic; but no
one will deny that in all classes the proportion of the persons born
with a choleric disposition is the same. However, the influence of
environment brings it about that in the well-to-do classes even the
choleric run little danger of such a crime. Superficial civilization
(for a veneer is all that a great part of the bourgeoisie possesses) is
sufficient to limit these crimes to an insignificant minimum.

The obviousness of the reasons which have caused these acts to be
classed as crimes is such that it is needless to speak of them. In a
society like ours, with its numerous conflicts and its dense
population, life would be impossible if the individual were not
forbidden to avenge himself personally. Sociology teaches us that
vengeance, at first permitted, and even obligatory, has become a
prohibited act, because of the great harm it does to society. [1038]




B. Infanticide.

There are two chief motives for infanticide, which operate separately
or together, namely, fear of dishonor, and poverty. We shall speak
first of the former and put the question to begin with, what sort of
persons are guilty of this crime? Criminal statistics answer that—

First, they are, almost without exception, women.

Second, they are unmarried women much oftener than married.

Third, the guilty are almost exclusively very poor. According to
Italian statistics 88.1% of them are indigent; in Austria, 90.8%; and
there are no rich or well-to-do women among them.

Fourth, the women of the working class are much more often guilty than
those of the independent class, and the class of domestics furnishes
especially a very high figure (Germany). These results are confirmed by
the data of other countries. In Austria 80% of those convicted between
1880 and 1882 were domestics, [1039] and in France the same was true of
35% of those convicted between 1876 and 1880. [1040]

Fifth, the women working in the fields are especially likely to fall
into this crime (Germany); the data of other countries also show that
it is especially in the country that infanticide is committed. Dr.
Socquet shows that in France between 1871 and 1875 there were, to the
million inhabitants, 35 persons arraigned out of the rural population,
and 22 to the urban. [1041]

Sixth, illiteracy is very frequent among those convicted of
infanticide. We have seen that in Austria 39.5%, in France 20.0%, and
in Italy 92.9% were illiterate. Women knowing more than how to read and
write were not found among these criminals.

Most of the cases of infanticide are identical; it generally is, as
Fournier says, “a girl who has allowed herself to have a child without
the permission of the municipality”, and who has been abandoned by her
lover.

The ruling moral ideas place before her a frightful dilemma; if her
pregnancy is known by those about her and the child remains alive, she
is covered with ignominy, and a painful life awaits her. On the other
hand if she makes the child disappear, the others ignore everything,
and she avoids dishonor and its consequences. She therefore attempts to
conceal her pregnancy as long as possible, in the hope of a
miscarriage. But when she finds herself disappointed, when not only
terrible physical pains, but also mental tortures are making her almost
mad [1042]—then it happens that she kills her child.

Statistics show that most of these crimes are committed by women of the
lower classes. The number of unmarried mothers is here relatively
great; infanticide is quite rare (though a little more frequent than
one would suppose from the criminal statistics). There must be special
circumstances, therefore, to lead some of these women to this crime. As
we have seen in treating of marriage, the ideas of intimate relations
between persons who are not married are much less severe in the
proletariat, than in the bourgeoisie (a consequence of the fact that
the social causes of marriage are much less strong in the latter than
in the former), so that among the proletariat these relations are
pretty common. If they have consequences, the father and mother
generally marry. In this case the idea of killing the child does not
come to the woman. The unmarried mothers (very often domestics), who
are guilty of this crime are especially those who, seduced and then
abandoned by men of a higher class, have no family that can receive
them.

Besides women of the working class, there are also among the
infanticides some of the petty bourgeoisie, where the moral disapproval
of extra-matrimonial sexual commerce is very severe.

Not all women who find themselves in the situation described commit the
crime in question, of course. One will reason more than another, and
will prefer dishonor to the danger of a criminal trial; one woman has
the maternal instinct more fully developed than another, etc. In
relation to the social sentiments we see here a situation contrary to
what occurs in the case of most crimes. Crime is an egoistic act, that
is to say an act which injures the interests of others. This is true of
infanticide, but this differs from most of the other crimes in being
committed to escape moral disapproval, while they are committed only to
obtain a personal profit or to satisfy the passions. This is why those
guilty of infanticide are not generally those whose social sentiments
have little intensity, as is mostly the case with those who are guilty
of economic or sexual crimes. Infanticides are persons sensitive to the
opinion of others, while those who have little social feeling easily
bear shame. [1043]

These individual differences explain in part which are the individuals
who become guilty of the crime in question, but not the cause of its
existence. There are only a few crimes whose social origin is as clear
as that of infanticide. If the present structure of society did not
make the present form of marriage necessary, and thus bring about moral
disapprobation of extra-matrimonial sexual relations, there would be no
infanticide caused by fear of dishonor. [1044]

The repression of some of the strongest natural desires, required by
our present society, is so great that these requirements are bound to
be violated by some individuals in whom these desires are very
pronounced. This is true not only in the sphere of the economic life,
but also in that of the sexual life. As long as cupidity is awakened in
many, while only a few can satisfy it, theft will exist; as long as the
satisfaction of the sexual desires is permitted only after certain
economic conditions have been complied with, the prohibition will be
violated, and some persons will try to destroy the evidence of their
acts. [1045]

Besides the fear of shame, poverty also plays a part in the etiology of
infanticide. Again, it is the two motives combined that are
responsible. The great number of infanticides among domestics are not
committed simply from fear of shame, but also because the mother,
abandoned by everyone (especially in a country where inquiry into
paternity is prohibited) does not know how to support her child.
Besides these cases there are some committed from poverty alone, for
example when married women commit this crime (something, it should be
added, which happens very rarely).

Some statistical data will show that poverty is a fairly important
factor in the etiology of infanticide. Dr. Weiss shows that in Belgium
infanticide increased greatly in the years that were bad economically
(see p. 63 of Pt. I), and Dr. Starke does the same for Prussia (see p.
66). [1046]



As we have pointed out above, infanticide for the cause of poverty was
quite general among primitive peoples, since they were not in a
position to support a large population. It was for this reason that the
act was not considered immoral, and that it was even required in some
cases. In consequence of the continually increasing productivity of
labor, infanticide fell more and more into desuetude, and at the same
time was considered more and more reprehensible. [1047]








CHAPTER V.

POLITICAL CRIMES.


Finally we have still to treat of political offenses, offenses which,
in comparison with others, occur very rarely, and which by their nature
are totally different. [1048]

The origin of the state, and the possibility of political crimes, are
bound up with a certain phase of the development of the economic life,
that is to say with the origin of marked contrasts of fortune. Those
who had monopolized the power in the state defended their position by
laws whose infraction was threatened with severe penalties. Economic
conditions, however, undergo considerable changes, and when these have
reached a certain degree, the oppressed class, having become the more
powerful, breaks the political power of the ruling class and seizes it
for itself. If the dominant class does all that it can to maintain its
position unimpaired to the last moment, it will necessarily happen that
this development will lead to political crimes. This kind of political
crime may be called great political criminality. In western Europe the
last great struggle of this nature was that of the feudal classes and
the bourgeoisie. The former, once necessary, had become superfluous and
harmful; the bourgeoisie on the other hand, from an insignificant class
had become the most important. It overturned the whole political system
which embarrassed it, seized the power, and transformed the state
according to the exigencies of the economic system. A repetition of the
same process in eastern Europe we are now witnessing in the changes
going on in Russia. The economic development no longer corresponds to
the political system, which sooner or later will inevitably be replaced
by the modern system.

It would be a waste of time to insist upon the fact that those who
commit these acts have nothing in common with ordinary criminals but
the name. Most criminals are individuals whose social sentiments are
reduced to a minimum, and who injure others purely for the satisfaction
of their own desires. The political criminals of whom we are speaking,
on the other hand, are the direct opposite; they risk their most sacred
interests, their liberty and their life, for the benefit of society;
they injure the ruling class only to aid the oppressed classes, and
consequently all humanity. While the ordinary criminal is generally
“l’homme canaille” (as van Benedikt phrases it in his “Biologie und
Kriminalstatistik”) the political criminal is “homo nobilis.” History
rights the matter, for the name of the ordinary great criminal is
pronounced only with horror, and ends by falling into oblivion, while
the political criminal survives in the memory of posterity as a hero.
[1049]

We must put in the same class the political criminals who aim to
deliver a subjugated people from their oppressors. The authors of these
crimes also have nothing in common with ordinary criminals.

Besides these two kinds of political crimes, which are plainly
collective in their nature, there are cases of crimes committed by
individuals which for the most part are attempts upon the life of the
monarch or of one of his representatives. The more absolute a
government, the more liberty is restricted, and the less chance there
is, consequently, of seeing the situation changed by legal means, the
greater will become the danger that one of those oppressed will kill
the autocrat, either to better the situation or to take revenge for
what he and his have suffered. Anyone who wants to follow the genesis
of this kind of crime has only to turn to Russia. There all the factors
meet which lead to political homicide; the repression of all freedom, a
corrupt bureaucracy, and the impossibility of obtaining the least
change by legal means.

These circumstances naturally excite the revengeful feelings which
sooner or later show themselves in acts. Though we may have the
conviction that these acts are almost always useless, though we may
have a deep aversion to violence—this does not justify us in ranking
those who do these things with ordinary criminals. It matters not how
we may abhor violence as such; every reasonable man will justify it
when it serves to defend oneself, and most of the acts of political
criminals in Russia are only acts of defense against the unheard-of
cruelty and violence of the government. [1050]

Finally there remains a third kind of political crimes, analogous to
ordinary crime, the assassination of the monarch by individuals who
thus attempt to place themselves in power. These are actuated by the
same vile motives that inspire the robber-murderer—cupidity, desire to
dominate, etc.

Now what are the political crimes committed in our days? Leaving aside
the case of Russia, which is still living in an epoch that western
Europe has left behind, there are only the political crimes of
socialists and anarchists. There is little to be said about those
committed by socialists. The international social democracy attempts to
reach its end by legal means. Since the fall of absolutism it has been
possible to exercise an influence on the state in this way, an
influence which varies with the country. It is this possibility that
the social democracy makes use of. In conformity with its fundamental
principles it rejects all violence against the head of the state.
Accordingly its partisans have never committed such acts. The more
democratic the constitution of a country, the less justification the
social democracy will have for political crimes, as in Switzerland, for
example, a country where the penal code, moreover, mentions but few
political crimes. In other countries, where the democratic institutions
are weak, where the constitutional monarchy has still an absolutist
character, and where social democracy has become powerful, as in
Germany, political crimes are inevitable. Their number, however, is
insignificant in comparison with ordinary crimes. From a criminological
point of view they have little importance, though often punished
severely, and they are generally limited to the crime of leze majesty.
Social democrats are, then, sometimes guilty of minor political
offenses, and in some countries only. Whether this party will not in
the future be guilty of crime of the great political type, or, in other
words, whether it will not come to political revolution, is another
question and one that no one can answer with certainty. Like all the
bourgeoisie when the contest with the feudal classes was still going
on, the social democrats are a revolutionary class; they wish to place
society upon a basis different from the present one. It is possible
that in democratic countries they will attain this by legal means, and
consequently without there being any reason for political crime.
However, it may also happen that at a given moment when the proletariat
forms the majority of the legislative body, the ruling class may have
recourse to a “coup d’état”, to a political crime, in order to prevent
the proletariat from governing. This possibility is even a probability
in some countries, where the opposition of classes is very marked. In
Germany, for example, where the social democracy is very powerful, it
is very likely that the government will attempt some day to suppress
universal suffrage by a “coup d’état.” It is only in such a case that
the social democracy will in its turn abandon the legal way and be
forced to have recourse to other methods.

In the second place there are the political crimes of anarchists. Their
number is not great enough for us to learn their etiology from
statistics. [1051] We must therefore analyze individual cases. What are
the individuals that are guilty of these? The anarchists of the
propaganda are most exclusively young men. Leauthier and Langs were 20
years old, Angelillo also, Henry 21, Caserio 21, Schwabe 23, Pallas 24,
Lucheni 25, Vaillant and Bresci 31, and Salvador 33, at the time they
committed their crimes, and as far as I know there were none of them
who were over 33. In disposition they were very excitable. As soon as
an idea took hold of them they thought of nothing else. Chance brought
them into contact with anarchism which immediately made a conquest of
them. Brought up in another environment they would have become, for
example, religious devotees; in fact Caserio, Salvador, Vaillant,
Cyvoct, and Henry were such before becoming anarchists. [1052]

Extreme individualism is also a characteristic of theirs. [1053] They
abhor discipline, from which it follows that they nourish a fierce
hatred of militarism. Even a mild form of discipline, such as that of a
party of which one voluntarily becomes a member, is insupportable to
them. Some of them have been socialists, but have soon left the party.
Among these was Henry, who says in his defense: “For an instant I was
attracted by socialism, but I did not delay in separating myself from
this party. I had too much love for liberty, too much respect for
individual initiative, too much repugnance to incorporation, to take a
number in the enlisted army of the fourth estate.” [1054]

Another characteristic of nearly all active anarchists, and one
intimately connected with the preceding, is great vanity. Lucheni, for
instance, in speaking of his crime said, “I wanted to kill a person of
note, because that would get into print.” Vaillant had himself
photographed before making his attack, distributed his portraits right
and left, and when arrested asked whether the journals had printed his
picture, etc.

These traits of character, observed in the case of these individuals,
are not rare; vain and excitable individualists are fairly numerous,
yet almost none become active anarchists. We must therefore seek the
explanation elsewhere, and ask ourselves the question, in what
environment have they lived? When the president of the tribunal before
which Lucheni appeared, asked him what was the motive that led him to
commit his act, he replied, “It was poverty.” This is applicable to
almost all the active anarchists. See, for example, the life of
Vaillant. An illegitimate child without any education, he had to earn
his living at the age of 12; having escaped from his employer, with
whom he was living, he implored his mother to take him in. Rebuffed he
had himself arrested by the police, but when he was once more brought
back to his parents they refused anew to receive him. He tried to make
his own way, but failed in all that he undertook. It was when
embittered by all the miseries he had experienced that he became
acquainted with socialism, but finding this too theoretical he ranked
himself on the side of the anarchists, and the last link in this chain
of misery was his well-known crime. [1055]

There are authors who claim that poverty is not to be considered as one
of the principal causes of anarchy, and in support of their assertion
cite the case of Henry and some others, who while not living in easy
circumstances, yet did not know the blackest poverty. Those who reason
thus have a false notion of the motives that impel anarchists. It is
not only the poverty that they have themselves experienced that moves
them, but also, and chiefly, the poverty of others. Those who remain
insensible to the sufferings of their neighbors never become
anarchists; for not being able to draw any personal profit from
anarchism, they consider it madness. Placed in unfavorable conditions
such persons become ordinary criminals, or commit suicide. They never
sacrifice themselves for an ideal.

Thus we come to another psychological trait of the anarchists, namely
that they are born with pronounced altruistic tendencies. [1056] It is
their altruism which separates them from the ordinary great criminal,
whose social instincts are very weak. [1057]

It seems paradoxical to say that persons who commit such acts are of an
altruistic nature, but the paradox is only apparent. When two persons,
an egoist and an altruist, see a child being maltreated, the former
goes on his way saying that he would only get himself into trouble if
he interfered; the latter, on the other hand, delivers the child from
his tormentor, to whom he may give a good thrashing in addition. Here
the violent person is the altruist, the other the egoist. Every
comparison is imperfect, and this is the case with the one before us,
but there is some analogy between the act cited and those of the
anarchists. The crimes which they commit are egoistic towards certain
persons, but altruistic with reference to others. As a consequence of
their own poverty and of the irritation they feel when they see that of
their fellows, they have been seized with a hatred of society and wish
to avenge themselves. These sentiments are not tempered by much
intellectual development. This is a very important factor in the
development of active anarchism. Almost all these persons are either
very ignorant or have only an elementary education, some know a little
more, and persons of thorough education are not found at all among
them. Further, most of them lack pronounced intellectual aptitudes, but
are rather especially impulsive. [1058]

These individuals, excitable, vain, with little intellectual capacity,
and ignorant in addition, but oppressed by their own poverty and that
of others, and filled with a hatred of society, come into contact with
anarchism. It is unnecessary to give an exposition of this doctrine;
[1059] the active anarchists in their ignorance get no clear idea of
any theory whatever, and certainly not of anything as vague and
confused as anarchism. They have heard it said that it looks to the
formation of a society of altruists where there will be no more
poverty, and this appeals to their altruistic instincts; at the same
time anarchism gives a preponderating part to the individual, and this
draws their vanity. Thus their hate increases, and at the same time
attaches itself to certain individuals, whom anarchism holds
responsible for existing conditions. Further, the absurd opinion has
been instilled into them that it is possible for society to be
reorganized at a single stroke, and that to attain this end it will be
necessary to use violence.

Is it astonishing that such individuals come to attempt homicide? No;
to be sure all persons of this kind do not go so far; for that it would
be necessary that other conditions should be complied with. It is plain
that persons with a great aversion to violence would run little risk of
attempting an assassination; with others it is courage that is lacking;
others still attach too high a price to life and liberty to be willing
to risk them; etc. We must note this last point especially. Generally
active anarchists are persons who care nothing for a life in which they
have nothing further to lose. Their conduct in court and their
indifference in the face of death are proof of this; knowing beforehand
that they will almost certainly not go unpunished their act is often an
indirect suicide.

If we ask what the active anarchists wish to attain by their crimes the
answer is principally that they wish to avenge upon society the misery
experienced by others and by themselves, [1060] they wish to terrorize
the ruling classes, in order to force upon them social reforms; they
wish to set an example to the working classes and finally, they wish to
satisfy their vanity, by making themselves talked of. Once committed,
the crime is often the commencement of a vicious circle, since society
avenges itself upon the author, who, in turn, is avenged by his
friends; imitation thus leading to new crimes.

As in the case of all other crimes, I find for anarchism only social
causes, and in the last analysis, only economic causes. To be sure, the
individuals who commit these crimes are already predisposed in that
direction, but this is true of other crimes also. Only the
predisposition in these latter is simple, while that which leads to
anarchistic crimes is much more complex. However, this predisposition
alone explains nothing. I would ask those who think that only
individual factors play any part, whether fanatical persons with all
the characteristics of the anarchists of our time have not been found
in all ages and countries. Everyone, I think, will answer in the
affirmative. Well then, anarchistic crimes have occurred only during a
certain period and in certain countries. No one can deny that there are
as many persons predisposed to anarchistic crimes in a country like
Germany, as there are in Italy, for example. Yet anarchistic crimes do
not occur in Germany, for the good reason that the material conditions
of the proletariat there are so much better than in Italy, and the
degree of intellectual development in the working people is so much
higher; the German working-man derides the “naïveté” of the anarchists,
and detests their futile crimes. It is in the environment alone then
that we find the causes of active anarchism, the poverty and ignorance
in which the lower classes live.








CHAPTER VI.

PATHOLOGICAL CRIMES.


So far we have been examining crime in its relation to the economic and
social environment. We have not been able to discover the existence of
individual factors; the celebrated formula, “crime = individual factor
+ social factor,” has been shown to be incorrect if we are seeking for
the causes of crime instead of asking why a certain individual has
become a criminal. The conclusion obtained by sociology is the same as
that arrived at in anthropology by authors like Manouvrier, Baer, and
Näcke.

However, when one is trying to determine the cause of crime by
sociology, certain cases are at times met with that cannot be explained
in this way. For example, one person will steal useless objects which
he is perfectly well able to buy; another will assault or kill without
provocation, etc. These cases, it is true, are the exception, but they
do exist and must not be neglected. [1061] We have here, then, real
individual factors, factors which are found in certain individuals
only. Other crimes, forming the great majority, are committed from
motives which form the basis of all human acts, but are stronger with
some few than they are with the general body of mankind. It is these
individuals who run more danger than most of committing a crime when
they live in a certain environment. The great mass of criminals differ
only quantitatively from persons who never get into the courts; the
criminals we are about to consider on the other hand differ
qualitatively also.

One thing more before we ask ourselves what this individual factor is.
As many authors have remarked, it very often happens that, even in the
cases we are about to treat, there is a social factor. [1062] The proof
of this is that individuals thus disposed to crime, but belonging to
the well-to-do classes, seldom get to the point of committing them;
because their education being better, the tendency is sooner noticed,
they are better watched, and thus their committing a crime is often
avoided. Born-criminals, in the sense of those who become criminals
whatever the circumstances may be (the only meaning that can properly
be given to the word “born” here), are doubtless very rare. [1063]

What, then, is the nature of this individual factor? It is especially
the Italian school that has busied itself with this problem, and in
doing so has rendered a service to science, although it has given an
undue importance to this individual factor, attempting to discover it
in all crimes. The first hypothesis given by Professor Lombroso was
that of atavism, according to which the criminal was an individual in
whom reappeared the characteristics of his remote ancestors, the desire
to steal, kill, etc. It will not be far from the truth if we assert
that almost no reputable scientist now accepts this hypothesis as
correct. It has been attacked both from the side of sociology and from
that of anthropology. Sociologists have proved that the facts
contradict Professor Lombroso’s thesis, for primitive peoples are
neither thieves nor murderers, and our ancestors, consequently, may be
regarded as cleared of the same charge. [1064]

Anthropologists also are strongly opposed to this hypothesis. In his
article, “De geboren misdadiger” (the born-criminal) Professor
Jelgersma says that most of the anomalies observed in certain criminals
have no atavistic character, such as unsymmetrical eyes and ears,
abnormal growth of hair, etc. [1065] Dr. A. Baer makes the same remark
in his “Der Verbrecher in anthropologischer Beziehung”, and goes on as
follows: “The number of such abnormalities, which betray a disordered
and an apparently genuine atavistic condition, is ... so small and so
accidental, that no force can be recognized in them that might serve
for the explanation of criminality, or establish a causal connection
with the criminal nature of an individual. Out of this mixture of
stigmata of the most various origin and importance, to attempt to find
the sole basis in their atavistic character is to do more than
permissible violence to the facts. [1066]

After this beginning the Italian school put forth another explanation,
to which it attached the more importance as the hypothesis of atavism
fell into discredit: the criminal is either an epileptic or morally
insane. Although the correctness of this hypothesis has not been proved
any more than the other, [1067] the Italian school here found itself in
a field recognized by criminal-anthropologists as its true one. At
present one has even the right to say that the opinion in this regard
is almost unanimous. [1068] The origin of the tendencies of part of the
criminals is to be found in the pathological nature of the individuals
themselves. [1069] These are disordered or degenerate, not, as some
authors would have us believe, individuals differing more or less from
the average, but persons who suffer from mental diseases, or whose
nervous system is affected. [1070]

Among those disordered and degenerate, some individuals [1071] have
tendencies not found in others (such as the desire to kill for the sake
of killing), or their moral sentiments are excessively weak. It is to
be noticed that we have met with degeneracy above, as it is to be named
among the causes of alcoholism and prostitution also. In treating of
economic crimes we saw that degenerates also run more danger than
others of succumbing in the struggle for existence, and hence become
criminals more easily. Thus we meet degeneracy both as a direct and as
an indirect cause of crime.

We might leave the matter here, for we have come to a field other than
that of sociology. However, one more question presents itself. To what
extent are the economic system and its consequences the cause of these
maladies? It is plain that this important question belongs in a work on
sociology. We shall accordingly attempt to answer it briefly with the
aid of competent authorities.

First of all, we note that heredity plays a great part in these
maladies. The authors who have taken up the subject agree. It has been
remarked that:

First, the inheritance of defects is not inevitable; degenerate parents
may have sound children, though the chances are not very great.

Second, the disease of the parents is not always transmitted as such to
the child, but the child may be predisposed to this same disease or one
analogous. Dr. Féré expresses this as follows: “The diseases of the
nervous system ... make up a single family, indissolubly united by the
laws of heredity ... everyone (of those who have these diseases), if he
is still fertile, can reproduce them all.” [1072]

In speaking of heredity we come to the first relation between the
diseases in question and the social environment, since, in our present
society, human reproduction is intimately bound up with the economic
life. A person who is diseased but rich is often in a position to marry
and procreate, while he would have had a smaller chance if sexual
selection alone had been effective. On the other hand many well and
strong individuals are prevented at present from establishing a family,
since they lack the means to support it.

A second harmful kind of selection in our present society is found in
the effect of militarism, which takes the strongest individuals,
decimates them in time of war, or returns them to society weakened and
diseased, while the weak have the greater chance to procreate.

In the third place, the ignorance of the harmful effects for humanity
of the reproduction of degenerates is one of the principal reasons why
degeneracy is so frequently present. This ignorance is great in the
well-to-do classes, and naturally greater still among the poor. It is
often repeated, and with truth, that man takes great care to improve
his live stock by selection but takes none whatever in the matter of
his own race; the weak and the diseased continue to reproduce
themselves to the detriment of all society. The lack of all feeling of
responsibility, natural to our intensely individualistic society, also
contributes its share toward bringing to birth so many unhappy
creatures for whom it would have been better if they had never existed.

If we ask how it happens that one individual or another is degenerate,
we must answer that very often this degeneracy is due to heredity,
either in part or altogether. But if we enquire into the causes of
degeneracy in general heredity ceases to be a cause. As Professor
Dallemagne says: “Heredity creates nothing; from heredity to heredity
we must still go back to the cause.” [1073]

What are at present the principal characteristics of the relation
between degeneracy and the present economic system with its
consequences? Some authors in treating of the etiology of degeneracy
express themselves only in general terms, and point out no other cause
than “unfavorable circumstances.” Professor Jelgersma, for example,
says: “The simple psychoses, melancholia, mania, etc. are caused by
unfavorable circumstances. The cause of the psychoses of degeneracy is
deeper; the unfavorable circumstances have exercised their influence
from generation to generation, and thus an individual is born who is
abnormal from birth.” [1074]

These unfavorable circumstances must be more precisely defined,
therefore. We shall divide them into four great groups. [1075]

First. The material condition of the poor classes. “To be well,” says
Dr. Toulouse, “one must be sufficiently fed, must clothe himself
according to the season, be clean, not work beyond one’s strength, and
be more or less exempt from care.” [1076] This is a simple truth of
which all the world is convinced when it is a question of themselves or
of their families, but which the physicians forget only too often when
they are speaking of the social causes of diseases. [1077]

In the first place the poor classes are badly and insufficiently fed,
and as a consequence grow weak, and the children born to them are
inferior physically and mentally. The insufficient nourishment of the
mother during her pregnancy, and the insufficient nourishment of the
child during the first years of his life, are especially fatal to him.
Then those who are badly fed are predisposed to tuberculosis, scrofula,
and rickets, which, in their turn, may be the causes of degeneracy.
[1078] Rickety women often have a contraction of the pelvis, which
hinders child-birth, and may cause a lesion to the infant’s brain.
Note, for example, the opinion of Dr. Näcke, who says: “The social
misery, bad hygiene and food ... often enough beget a miserable
generation and must already have injured the germ. The same causes,
however, on the other hand easily produce feeble women with
qualitatively and quantitatively insufficient milk, and most of all
with a narrow pelvis, through which births take place with difficulty
and to the detriment of the brain of the child. If now the above named
factors come in later to affect the child, the derangement of nutrition
will be further increased, and it is no wonder if all kinds of rickety
and scrofulous symptoms appear in the body, and all kinds of children’s
ailments injure both body and mind.” [1079]

In the second place, unsanitary dwellings and insufficient clothing are
the cause of all sorts of diseases, especially tuberculosis, which in
their turn may lead to degeneracy. [1080] The density of population in
the great cities exercises its influence in the same direction.

In the third place, the long duration and intensity of the work forced
upon the proletariat also contribute to degeneracy. For each individual
there is a fixed measure of labor that he cannot pass without
experiencing harmful consequences in body and mind. Dr. Lewy describes
them as follows: “The consequences of immoderately long hours of labor
are, a certain overexcitement of the nervous system, which later gives
place to a permanent debility, with which may be associated a dull
headache as well as an inability to think clearly. If the overwork
continues for a longer time, soon all the systems of the body are
affected, the heart and larger arteries as well are injured in
structure and function, disturbances of the regular circulation appear,
manifested partly in swellings in various parts of the body, especially
in the feet, and partly through hemorrhages. The brain ceases to
function regularly, and so-called brain-symptoms appear, such as
vertigo, ringing in the ears, deafness, defective vision, paralysis,
and apoplexy. In the same way the liver, kidneys, and the digestive
tract may be drawn into the general weakening process. The muscles
become weak and slack, the body disposed to epidemic diseases, but
especially prepared to vocational diseases, to which persons in a
run-down condition most easily fall victim. If, then, the end of the
worker is not brought about prematurely by some intercurrent disease
like typhus, under the immoderate strain he uses up his existing forces
faster than he is in a position to replace them, and wastes away with
tuberculosis of the lungs, so much the quicker, of course, the weaker
he is constitutionally, and the younger he was when he had to submit to
excessive labor.” [1081]

The harmful consequences of long working hours make themselves felt
especially in the trades which are already dangerous to health, like
those where there is a great deal of dust produced, or those which use
poisons like lead, mercury, etc. [1082] Monotony of work joined with
long hours is also a cause of physical and intellectual deterioration.
Professor Vogt says: “The less variety work presents, the more
fatiguing is it, since it is only the same part of the muscles that are
continually called upon, while the rest of the muscular system, in
accordance with a well-known physiological law, degenerates from misuse
and wastes away. To a still higher degree the uniformity of work has a
deteriorating effect upon the mental powers; these become weakened much
more quickly in the case of long continued fatigue than the muscles,
while the unexercised mental faculties at the same time become
stunted.” [1083]

The present economic system has also led to the work of women and
children, and consequently to an important cause of the degeneration of
the race. The number of women forced to take part in trades for which
they are ill-fitted by nature is very great. The fear of being
discharged, and the impossibility of doing without their wages make
women with child continue to work up to the last moment of their
pregnancy, and recommence shortly after childbirth, leading to very
harmful results both for them and for their children. [1084] Then child
labor prevents the normal development of the children and ages them
prematurely. [1085]

Further, the cares and restlessness consequent upon the uncertainty of
life may be causes of the weakening of the nervous system and the
origin of a neurosis.

Finally, when an individual of this class falls sick his restoration to
health may be hindered by the lack of care and medical assistance and
the necessity of recommencing work too soon. [1086]

Second. The condition of the well-to-do classes. Most of the causes
producing degeneracy in the poor classes do not appear among the
well-to-do. With the latter there can be no question of insufficient
food or clothing, or of bad housing. Yet in the well-to-do classes the
idle, from their manner of living and this lack of regular exercise,
are led to excesses of all kinds, which may make them too, in another
way, subject to degeneracy. [1087]

In the active part of the bourgeoisie, among the manufacturers,
merchants, etc., the case is different. They are constantly absorbed in
the question of how to increase their wealth, or, if they are
unfortunate, they live in fear of losing the position gained. They are
in a state of agitation, of permanent overexcitement. So there are
numbers in the bourgeois class who overtax their minds, with the
resulting chance of neurasthenia, even where the individual is not
predisposed to it. All this applies also to the liberal professions,
though in a smaller degree; there also the great competition has
harmful consequences for the nerves. In “La famille névropathique” Dr.
Féré thus describes the consequences of overdriving: “... excessive
cerebral labor, intellectual and, still more, moral overwork, the
continual preoccupations of the struggle for existence are conditions
eminently fit to bring on functional troubles in the nervous system.
Neurasthenia, like hysteria, may be considered as a chronic fatigue.
The fatigue, to be sure, gives place to a number of troubles peculiar
to neurasthenia. And these troubles, even if only temporary, cannot
fail to have the most harmful effect upon children conceived under
these conditions.” [1088]

The opinion of the celebrated alienist Maudsley is also very
interesting; he says: “Perhaps one, and certainly not the least, of the
ill effects which spring from some of the conditions of our present
civilization, is seen in the general dread and disdain of poverty, in
the eager passion to become rich. The practical gospel of the age,
testified everywhere by faith and works, is that of money-getting; men
are estimated mainly by the amount of their wealth, take social rank
accordingly, and consequently bend all their energies to acquire that
which gains them esteem and influence. The result is that in the higher
departments of trade and commerce speculations of all sorts are eagerly
entered on, and that many people are kept in a continued state of
excitement and anxiety by the fluctuations of the money market. In the
lower branches of trade there is the same eager desire for petty gains;
and the continued absorption of the mind in these small acquisitions
generates a littleness of mind and meanness of spirit, where it does
not lead to actual dishonesty, which are nowhere displayed in a more
pitiable form than by certain petty tradesmen. The occupation which a
man is entirely engaged in does not fail to modify his character, and
the reaction upon the individual’s nature of a life which is being
spent with the sole aim of becoming rich, is most baneful. It is not
that the fluctuations of excitement unhinge the merchant’s mind and
lead to maniacal outbreaks, although that does sometimes happen; it is
not that failure in the paroxysm of some crisis prostrates his energies
and makes him melancholic, although that also is occasionally
witnessed; but it is that exclusiveness of his life-aim and occupation
too often saps the moral or altruistic element in his nature, makes him
become egoistic, formal, and unsympathetic, and in his person
deteriorates the nature of humanity. What is the consequence? If one
conviction has been fixed in my mind more distinctly than another by
observation of instances, it is that it is extremely unlikely such a
man will beget healthy children; on the contrary, it is extremely
likely that the deterioration of nature which he has acquired will be
transmitted as an evil heritage to his children. In several instances
in which the father has toiled upwards from poverty to vast wealth,
with the aim and hope of founding a family, I have witnessed the
results in a degeneracy, mental and physical, of his offspring, which
has sometimes gone as far as extinction of the family in the third or
fourth generation. When the evil is not so extreme as madness or
ruinous vice, the savour of a mother’s influence having been present,
it may still be manifest in an instinctive cunning and duplicity, and
an extreme selfishness of nature—a nature not having the capacity of a
true moral conception or altruistic feeling. Whatever opinion other
more experienced observers may hold, I cannot but think, after what I
have seen, that the extreme passion for getting rich, absorbing the
whole energies of life, does predispose to mental degeneration in the
offspring—either to moral defect, or to moral and intellectual
deficiency, or to outbreaks of positive insanity under the conditions
of life.” [1089]

We could cite a number of other competent authorities to prove that the
present economic system exacts from those who direct production also,
intellectual efforts such as the nervous system cannot endure
indefinitely. [1090]

Third. Syphilis. Aside from the fact that this malady is very probably
the cause of general paralysis, [1091] it takes its place among the
important factors of degeneracy to this extent, that the children of
syphilitics are often degenerates. This fact being generally recognized
we shall not dwell on it. The celebrated German specialist in syphilis,
Blaschko, says of it: “Syphilis leads to the birth of children who are
mentally and physically stunted, and often crippled and imbecile.”
[1092]

This would not be the time to speak of syphilis as a cause of
degeneracy, if the extension of this malady were not intimately bound
up with prostitution, which is, in its turn, determined by the economic
environment. Dr. Blaschko says of it: “The principal source of venereal
infection of course is, and remains, sexual intercourse outside of
wedlock, especially prostitution.” [1093]

As a social cause of the great extension of syphilis it is well to
point out the profound ignorance of the extent and the danger of
venereal diseases, [1094] to which less attention is paid than to
others (hospitals not receiving patients affected by them, relief funds
not aiding those having syphilis, etc.). Like other diseases these have
the most harmful consequences for those who live under bad conditions.
[1095]

Fourth. Alcoholism. Alcoholism undoubtedly belongs to the very
important causes of degeneracy. There are few questions upon which
competent authors are as unanimous as they are upon this. There is a
wealth of material for quotation but we will limit ourselves to the
words of Professor Dallemagne, who, after quoting the opinion of such
authorities as Morel, Magnan, and others concludes by saying: “Alcohol
is an essential factor of degeneracy. It can by itself create all the
degenerate and unbalanced states, and this question appears definitely
decided.” [1096] Dr. Legrain gives the following figures upon the
consequences of chronic alcoholism of the parents upon the children.
[1097] Out of 215 families of alcoholics in four generations (814
individuals) there were found: 42% of alcoholics, 60.9% of degenerates,
13.9% morally insane, 22.7% had had convulsions, 20% were hysterical or
epileptic, and 19% were insane. [1098] These are striking figures, and
banish all doubt of the harmful influence of alcohol!

It must still further be observed, that the very frequent adulteration
of alcohol leads to especially harmful consequences; [1099] and that
alcohol exerts an especially harmful effect upon the ill-nourished.
[1100]



We have come now to the end of our remarks upon the social and economic
causes of degeneracy. Although they are plainly not the only ones, yet
it is certain that their part in the etiology of degeneracy is very
important, and even preponderating.








CHAPTER VII.

CONCLUSIONS.


What are the conclusions to be drawn from what has gone before? When we
sum up the results that we have obtained it becomes plain that economic
conditions occupy a much more important place in the etiology of crime
than most authors have given them.

First we have seen that the present economic system and its
consequences weaken the social feelings. The basis of the economic
system of our day being exchange, the economic interests of men are
necessarily found to be in opposition. This is a trait that capitalism
has in common with other modes of production. But its principal
characteristic is that the means of production are in the hands of a
few, and most men are altogether deprived of them. Consequently,
persons who do not possess the means of production are forced to sell
their labor to those who do, and these, in consequence of their
economic preponderance, force them to make the exchange for the mere
necessaries of life, and to work as much as their strength permits.

This state of things especially stifles men’s social instincts; it
develops, on the part of those with power, the spirit of domination,
and of insensibility to the ills of others, while it awakens jealousy
and servility on the part of those who depend upon them. Further the
contrary interests of those who have property, and the idle and
luxurious life of some of them, also contribute to the weakening of the
social instincts.

The material condition, and consequently the intellectual condition, of
the proletariat are also a reason why the moral plane of that class is
not high. The work of children brings them into contact with persons to
associate with whom is fatal to their morals. Long working hours and
monotonous labor brutalize those who are forced into them; bad housing
conditions contribute also to debase the moral sense, as do the
uncertainty of existence, and finally absolute poverty, the frequent
consequence of sickness and unemployment. Ignorance and lack of
training of any kind also contribute their quota. Most demoralizing of
all is the status of the lower proletariat.

The economic position of woman contributes also to the weakening of the
social instincts.

The present organization of the family has great importance as regards
criminality. It charges the legitimate parents with the care of the
education of the child; the community concerns itself with the matter
very little. It follows that a great number of children are brought up
by persons who are totally incapable of doing it properly. As regards
the children of the proletariat, there can be no question of the
education properly so-called, on account of the lack of means and the
forced absence of one or both of the parents. The school tends to
remedy this state of things, but the results do not go far enough. The
harmful consequences of the present organization of the family make
themselves felt especially in the case of the children of the lower
proletariat, orphans, and illegitimate children. For these the
community does but little, though their need of adequate help is the
greatest.

Prostitution, alcoholism, and militarism, which result, in the last
analysis, from the present social order, are phenomena that have
demoralizing consequences.

As to the different kinds of crime, we have shown that the very
important group of economic criminality finds its origin on the one
side in the absolute poverty and the cupidity brought about by the
present economic environment, and on the other in the moral abandonment
and bad education of the children of the poorer classes. Then,
professional criminals are principally recruited from the class of
occasional criminals, who, finding themselves rejected everywhere after
their liberation, fall lower and lower. The last group of economic
crimes (fraudulent bankruptcy, etc.) is so intimately connected with
our present mode of production, that it would not be possible to commit
it under another.

The relation between sexual crimes and economic conditions is less
direct; nevertheless these also give evidence of the decisive influence
of these conditions. We have called attention to the four following
points.

First, there is a direct connection between the crime of adultery and
the present organization of society, which requires that the legal
dissolution of a marriage should be impossible or very difficult.

Second, sexual crimes upon adults are committed especially by unmarried
men; and since the number of marriages depends in its turn upon the
economic situation, the connection is clear; and those who commit these
crimes are further almost exclusively illiterate, coarse, raised in an
environment almost without sexual morality, and regard the sexual life
from the wholly animal side.

Third, the causes of sexual crime upon children are partly the same as
those of which we have been speaking, with the addition of
prostitution.

Fourth, alcoholism greatly encourages sexual assaults.

As to the relation between crimes of vengeance and the present
constitution of society, we have noted that it produces conflicts
without number; statistics have shown that those who commit them are
almost without exception poor and uncivilized, and that alcoholism is
among the most important causes of these crimes.

Infanticide is caused in part by poverty, and in part by the opprobrium
incurred by the unmarried mother (an opprobrium resulting from the
social utility of marriage).

Political criminality comes solely from the economic system and its
consequences.

Finally, economic and social conditions are also important factors in
the etiology of degeneracy, which is in its turn a cause of crime.

Upon the basis of what has gone before, we have a right to say that the
part played by economic conditions in criminality is preponderant, even
decisive.

This conclusion is of the highest importance for the prevention of
crime. If it were principally the consequence of innate human qualities
(atavism, for example), the pessimistic conclusion that crime is a
phenomenon inseparably bound up with the social life would be well
founded. But the facts show that it is rather the optimistic conclusion
that we must draw, that where crime is the consequence of economic and
social conditions, we can combat it by changing those conditions.



However important crime may be as a social phenomenon, however terrible
may be the injuries and the evil that it brings upon humanity, the
development of society will not depend upon the question as to what are
the conditions which could restrain crime or make it disappear, if
possible; the evolution of society will proceed independently of this
question.

What is the direction that society will take under these continual
modifications? This is not the place to treat fully of this subject. In
my opinion the facts indicate quite clearly what the direction will be.
The productivity of labor has increased to an unheard of degree, and
will assuredly increase in the future. The concentration of the means
of production into the hands of a few progresses continually; in many
branches it has reached such a degree that the fundamental principle of
the present economic system, competition, is excluded, and has been
replaced by monopoly. On the other hand the working class is becoming
more and more organized, and the opinion is very generally held among
working-men that the causes of material and intellectual poverty can be
eliminated only by having the means of production held in common.

Supposing that this were actually realized, what would be the
consequences as regards criminality? Let us take up this question for a
moment. Although we can give only personal opinions as to the details
of such a society, the general outlines can be traced with certainty.

The chief difference between a society based upon the community of the
means of production and our own is that material poverty would be no
longer known. Thus one great part of economic criminality (as also one
part of infanticide) would be rendered impossible, and one of the
greatest demoralizing forces of our present society would be
eliminated. And then, in this way those social phenomena so productive
of crime, prostitution and alcoholism, would lose one of their
principal factors. Child labor and overdriving would no longer take
place, and bad housing, the source of much physical and moral evil,
would no longer exist.

With material poverty there would disappear also that intellectual
poverty which weighs so heavily upon the proletariat; culture would no
longer be the privilege of some, but a possession common to all. The
consequences of this upon criminality would be very important, for we
have seen that even in our present society with its numerous conflicts,
the members of the propertied classes, who have often but a veneer of
civilization, are almost never guilty of crimes of vengeance. There is
the more reason to admit that in a society where interests were not
opposed, and where civilization was universal, these crimes would be no
longer present, especially since alcoholism also proceeds in large part
from the intellectual poverty of the poorer classes. And what is true
of crimes of vengeance, is equally true of sexual crimes in so far as
they have the same etiology.

A large part of the economic criminality (and also prostitution to a
certain extent) has its origin in the cupidity excited by the present
economic environment. In a society based upon the community of the
means of production, great contrasts of fortune would, like commercial
capital, be lacking, and thus cupidity would find no food. These crimes
will not totally disappear so long as there has not been a
redistribution of property according to the maxim, “to each according
to his needs”, something that will probably be realized, but not in the
immediate future.

The changes in the position of woman which are taking place in our
present society, will lead, under this future mode of production, to
her economic independence, and consequently to her social independence
as well. It is accordingly probable that the criminality of woman will
increase in comparison with that of man during the transition period.
But the final result will be the disappearance of the harmful effects
of the economic and social preponderance of man.

As to the education of children under these new conditions it is
difficult to be definite. However, it is certain that the community
will concern itself seriously with their welfare. It will see to it
that the children whose parents cannot or will not be responsible for
them, are well cared for. By acting in this way it will remove one of
the most important causes of crime. There is no doubt that the
community will exercise also a strict control over the education of
children; it cannot be affirmed, however, that the time will come when
the children of a number of parents will be brought up together by
capable persons; this will depend principally upon the intensity that
the social sentiments may attain.

As soon as the interests of all are no longer opposed to each other, as
they are in our present society, there will no longer be a question
either of politics (“a fortiori” of political crimes) or of militarism.

Such a society will not only remove the causes which now make men
egoistic, but will awaken, on the contrary, a strong feeling of
altruism. We have seen that this was already the case with the
primitive peoples, where their economic interests were not in
opposition. In a larger measure this will be realized under a mode of
production in common, the interests of all being the same.

In such a society there can be no question of crime properly so called.
The eminent criminologist, Manouvrier, in treating of the prevention of
crime expresses himself thus: “The maxim to apply is, act so that every
man shall always have more interest in being useful to his fellows than
in harming them.” It is precisely in a society where the community of
the means of production has been realized that this maxim will obtain
its complete application. There will be crimes committed by
pathological individuals, but this will come rather within the sphere
of the physician than that of the judge. And then we may even reach a
state where these cases will decrease in large measure, since the
social causes of degeneracy will disappear, and procreation by
degenerates be checked through the increased knowledge of the laws of
heredity and the increasing sense of moral responsibility.



“It is society that prepares the crime”, says the true adage of
Quetelet. For all those who have reached this conclusion, and are not
insensible to the sufferings of humanity, this statement is sad, but
contains a ground of hope. It is sad, because society punishes severely
those who commit the crime which she has herself prepared. It contains
a ground of hope, since it promises to humanity the possibility of some
day delivering itself from one of its most terrible scourges.








BIBLIOGRAPHY OF WORKS CITED


Acton, W. Prostitution, Considered in its Moral, Social and Sanitary
Aspects. London, 1870.

Adams-Lehmann, H. B. Das Weib und der Stier. Neue Zeit, 1900–1901, II.

Administration de la justice criminelle et civile de la Belgique
1881–1885. Bruxelles, 1888.

Agahd, K. Die Erwerbsthätigkeit schulpflichtiger Kinder im Deutschen
Reich. Archiv f. soz. Gesetzgeb. u. Statistik, XII.

Aguinaliedo, J. M. L., and de Quiros, C. B. Verbrechertum und
Prostitution in Madrid. Berlin, 1909.

Albanel, L. Le crime dans la famille. Paris, 1900.

Albrecht, P. La criminalité de l’homme au point de vue de l’anatomie
comparée. Actes du Ier Congrès d’anthropologie crim. Turin, 1886–1887.

Aletrino, A. Twee opstellen over crimineele anthropologie. Amsterdam,
1899.

—— Over ontoerekenbaarheid. Amsterdam, 1899.

—— La situation sociale de l’uraniste. Compte rendu du V Congr.
d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam, 1901.

—— Over eenige oorzaken des prostitutie. Amsterdam, 1901.

—— Handleiding bij de studie der crimineele anthropologie. Amsterdam,
I, II, 1903, 1904.

—— Is celstraf nog langer geoorloofd en gewenscht? Amsterdam, 1906.

Alimena, B. Naturalismo critico e diritto penale. Rivista di disciplina
carceraria, 1891.

Alsberg, M. Erbliche Entartung bedingt durch soziale Einflüsse. Cassel
und Leipzig, 1903.

Alterthum, P. Das Problem der Arbeitslosigkeit. Berlin, 1911.

Ammon, O. Ursprung der sozialen Triebe. Zeitschr. f. Soc. wissensch.,
IV.

Amschl, A. Aberglauben als Heilmittel. Archiv f. Krim. Anthr. u.
Kriminalistik, XV.

—— Das Verbrechen des Kindesmordes nach österreichischem Recht. Archiv
f. Krim. anthr. u. Krim., XXX.

Annuaire statistique de la France, V, VII, IX, XVI, XX. Paris, 1882
sqq.

Annual Report (1912–1913) of the National Society for the Prevention of
Cruelty to Children. London, 1913.

Annuario statistico italiano, 1900. Roma, 1900.

Arbeidersleven in Nederland. (Anonymous.) Amsterdam, 1908.

Arendt, H. Menschen die den Pfad verloren. Stuttgart, 1907.

—— Kleine Weisse Sklaven. Berlin-Charlottenburg, 1911.

Ariëns, A. Criminaliteit en drankmisbruik. Leiden, 1905.

Aschaffenburg, G. Alkoholgenuss u. Verbrechen. Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
Strafr. w., XX.

—— Zur Psychologie d. Sittlichkeitsverbrecher. Monatschr. f. Krim.
Psych. u. Strafr. ref., II.

—— Das Verbrechen und seine Bekämpfung. Heidelberg, 1906.

Aschrott. Critique on “Verbrechen u. Verbrecher in Preussen” of Starke.
Jahrbücher f. Gesetzgebung etc., 1884.

Aubry, P. De l’homicide commis par la femme. Archives d’anthropologie
crim., VI.

—— La contagion du meurtre. Paris, 1894.

—— De l’influence contagieuse de la publicité des faits criminels.
Archives d’anthr. crim., VIII.

—— et Corre, A. Documents de criminologie rétrospective. Paris, 1895.

Audiffrent. Quelques considérations sur l’infanticide. Arch. d’anthr.
crim. XVIII.

Auer, F. Soziales Strafrecht. München, 1903.

Augagneur, V. Les vraies causes et les vrais remèdes de l’alcoolisme.
Mouvement socialiste, 1900.

—— La prostitution des filles mineures. Arch. d’anthr. crim., II.

Aull. Alkohol und Verbrechen. Halle a/S, 1908.

Avé-Lallemant, F. C. B. Das deutsche Gaunerthum, II, III. Leipzig,
1858.



Baer, A. Der Alcoholismus. Berlin, 1878.

—— Der Verbrecher in anthropologischer Beziehung. Leipzig, 1893.

—— Der Selbstmord im kindlichen Lebensalter. Leipzig, 1901.

—— Ueber jugendliche Mörder und Todtschläger. Archiv. f. Krim. etc.,
XI.

Baere, L. del. De invloed van opvoeding en onderwijs op de
criminaliteit. Amsterdam, 1891.

Baernreither, J. M. Die Ursachen, Erscheinungsformen und die
Ausbreitung der Verwahrlosung von Kindern und Jugendlichen in
Oesterreich. Wien, 1906.

Baets, M. de. L’école d’anthropologie criminelle. Gand, 1893.

—— Les influences de la misère sur la criminalité. Gand, 1895.

Baker, J. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la criminalité.
Actes du congrès pénitentiaire intern. de Bruxelles 1900 IV. Bruxelles
et Berne, 1901.

Battaglia, B. La dinamica del delitto. Napoli, 1886.

Baumgarten, A. Die Beziehungen der Prostitution zum Verbrechen. Archiv
f. Krim. Anthr. etc., XI.

Bebel, A. Die Frau und der Sozialismus. Stuttgart, 1899. “Woman in the
Past, Present, and Future” (translation of above by Walther, New York,
1886).

Beccaria, C. Des délits et des peines. Tr. Ad. Hélie. Paris, 1870.

Bechterew, W. v. Das Verbrechertum im Lichte der objektiven
Psychologie. Wiesbaden, 1914.

Beer, M. Geschichte des Sozialismus in England. Stuttgart, 1913.

Belfort Bax, E. Ethics of Socialism. London.

Benedikt, M. Biologie u. Kriminalistik. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafr.
w., VII.

—— Die Vagabondage u. ihre Behandlung. Zeitschr. f. d. g. etc., XI.

Bennecke, H. Bemerkungen zur Kriminalstatistik des Grossherzogtums
Hessen, besonders zur Statistik des Bettels u. Landstreicherei.
Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., X.

Bentham, J. Traités de législation civile et pénale. Paris, 1802.

Berard, A. Les hommes et les théories de l’anarchie. Archives d’anthr.
crim., VII.

—— Le Vagabondage en France. Archives d’anthr. crim., XIII.

Bérard des Glajeux, M. Les passions criminelles. Paris, 1893.

Beretning om Rigets Strafarbeitsanstalter, 1897–1898, 1898–1899.
Kristiania, 1900, 1901.

Berg, H. Getreidepreise und Kriminalität in Deutschland seit 1882.
Berlin, 1902.

Berkusky, H. Die Blutrache. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., XII.

Bernard. De la criminalité en France depuis 1826, etc. Journal des
Economistes, 1856.

Bernard, P. Des viols et attentats à la pudeur sur adultes. Arch.
d’anthr. crim. II.

—— et R. Garraud. Des attentats à la pudeur et des viols sur les
enfants. Archives etc., I.

Bertrand, E. Essai sur la moralité comparative des diverses classes de
la population et principalement des classes ouvrières. Journal de la
soc. de stat. de Paris, 1871–1872.

Bertrin, G. De la criminalité en France dans les congrégations, le
clergé et les principales professions. Paris.

Berufliche und soziale Gliederung des Deutschen Volkes nach der
Berufszählung vom 14 Juni 1895. Stat. d. Deutschen Reiches N. F., III.
Berlin, 1899.

Binny, J., and Mayhew. The Criminal Prisons of London. London, 1862.

Birnbaum, K. Die psychopathischen Verbrecher. Berlin, 1914.

Blanc, L. Organisation du travail. Bruxelles, 1845.

Blaschko, A. Die moderne Prostitution. Neue Zeit, 1891–92, II.

—— Hygiene der Prostitution und venerischen Krankheiten. Jena, 1900.

—— Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert. Berlin, 1902.

—— Prostitution. (Handwörterbuch der Staatswissenschaften VI.) Jena,
1910.

Blatchford, R. Merrie England. London, 1895.

—— Dismal England. London, 1901.

—— Not Guilty. London, 1906.

Blau, B. Kriminalistische Untersuchung der Kreise Marienwerder und
Thorn. Berlin, 1903.

Bleibtreu, C. Der Militarismus im XIX Jahrhundert. Berlin, 1901.

Bloch, J. Das Sexualleben unserer Zeit. Berlin, 1907.

—— Die Prostitution, I, 1912.

Boas, K. W. F. Alkohol und Verbrechen nach neueren Statistiken. Archiv.
f. Krim. etc., XXIX.

Böhmert, K. Die sächsische Kriminalstatistik mit besonderer Rücksicht
auf die Jahre 1882–1887. Zeitschr. d. K. sächs. Stat. Bureaus, XXXV.

Boies, H. M. The Science of Penology. New York and London, 1901.

Bonger, W. A. Eene apologie van den oorlog. Nieuwe Tijd, XIII.

—— Misdaad en socialisme. Nieuwe Tijd, XVI.

—— Verbrechen und Sozialismus. Neue Zeit, XXX2.

—— Over de maatschappelijke factoren van de misdaad en hunne beteekenis
in vergelijking met de individueele oorzaken. Tijdschrift v.
Strafrecht, XXIII.

—— Geloof en misdaad. Leiden, 1913.

Bonhoeffer, K. Ein Beitrag zur Kenntnis des grossstädtischen Bettel-
und Vagabondentums. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., XXI.

—— Zur Kenntnis des grossstädtischen Bettel- und Vagabondentums.
Zweiter Beitrag: Prostituirte. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafr. w., XXIII.

—— Sittlichkeitsdelikt u. Körperverletzung. Monatschr. f. Krim. psych.
etc., II.

Booth, Ch. Life and Labour of the People in London. London, 1892.

—— Pauperism. London, 1892.

Bosco, A. Gli omicidi in alcuni stati d’ Europa. Bulletin de l’inst.
intern. de stat., IV.

—— Della statistica dell’ omicidio negli stati uniti d’ America.
Bulletin etc., X.

Bournet, A. De la criminalité en France et en Italie. Paris, 1884.

Brace, Ch. L. The Dangerous Classes of New York. New York, 1872.

Braun, A. Berliner Wohnungsverhältnisse. Berlin, 1893.

Braun, L. Die Frauenfrage. Leipzig, 1901.

Brissot de Warville, J. P. Théorie des loix criminelles. Utrecht, 1781.

—— Recherches philosophiques sur la propriété et le vol. (Bibliothèque
phil. du législateur, du politique, du jurisconsulte, VI.) Berlin,
1782.

Bromme, M. W. Th. Lebensgeschichte eines modernen Fabrikarbeiters. Jena
u. Leipzig, 1905.

Brusse, M. J. Boefje. Rotterdam, 1903.

—— Onder de menschen. N. Rotterd. Courant, 1903–1904.

—— Het rosse leven en sterven van de Zandstraat. Rotterdam, 1912.

Bücher, K. Die Entstehung der Volkswirtschaft. Tübingen, 1904.



Cabet, E. Voyage en Icarie. Paris, 1842.

Calwer, R. Die erbliche Belastung der Prostituirten. Neue Zeit,
1893–1894, II.

Carlier, F. Les deux prostitutions. Paris, 1887.

Carnevale, E. Una terza scuola di diritto penale. Rivista di disciplina
carceraria, 1891.

Carrara, M. Les petits criminels de Cagliari. Compte rendu du V Congr.
d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam, 1901.

Caserio en prison. (Anonymous.) Archives etc., XVI.

Catlin, G. Illustrations of the Manners, Customs and Condition of the
North American Indians. London, 1851.

Cavaglieri, G., and Florian, E. I vagabondi I, II. Torino, 1897, 1900.

Chaillon des Barres. L’influence du bien-être matériel sur la moralité
d’un peuple. Journ. d. Econ., 1846.

Charpentier, R., and Ley, A. Alcoolisme et criminalité. Bruxelles,
1910.

Cheinisse, L. Die Rassenpathologie und der Alkoholismus bei den Juden.
Zeitschr. f. Demogr. u. Statistik der Juden, VI.

Chiozza-Money, L. G. Riches and Poverty. London, 1911.

Clay, J. On the Effects of Good or Bad Times on Committals to Prison.
Journal of the Stat. Soc. of London, 1854, 1857.

Colajanni, N. La delinquenza della Sicilia e le sue cause. Palermo,
1885.

—— Oscillations thermométriques et délits contre les personnes. Arch.
d’anthr. crim., I.

—— L’alcoolismo. Catania, 1887.

—— La sociologia criminale. Catania, 1887.

—— L’homicide en Italie. Revue Socialiste, 1901.

—— Le socialisme et sa propagande en rapport avec la criminalité.
Compte Rendu V Congr. d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam, 1901.

—— Il socialismo. Palermo-Milano, 2e ed.

—— Socialismo e criminalità. Roma-Napoli, 1904.

Collard, W. L. A. De handel in blanke slavinnen. Amsterdam, 1900.

Commenge, O. La prostitution clandestine à Paris. Paris, 1897.

Compte général de l’administration de la justice criminelle en France,
1900, 1907. Paris, 1902, 1909.

Considérant, V. Théorie du droit de propriété et du droit au travail.
Paris, 1848.

Corne, A. Essai sur la criminalité. Journ. d. Econ., 1868.

Corre, A. Crime et suicide. Paris, 1891.

—— Aperçu général de la criminalité militaire en France. Archives
d’anthr. crim., VI.

—— et Aubry, P. Documents de criminologie rétrospective. Paris, 1895.

Coutagne, H. De l’influence des professions sur la criminalité. Actes
du II Congr. d’anthr. crim. Paris.

—— De l’influence des professions sur la criminalité. Actes du III
Congr. d’anthr. crim. Bruxelles, 1893.

Criminality Promoted by Distress. (Anonymous.) Economist, 1856.

Crimineele statistiek 1899, 1900, 1901, 1904, 1905, 1910. ’s
Gravenhage, 1900 sqq.

Cuénoud, J. La criminalité à Genève au XIX siècle. Genève, 1891.

Cunow, H. Die Verwandtschafts-organisationen der Australneger.
Stuttgart, 1874.

—— Die ökonomischen Grundlagen der Mutterherrschaft. Neue Zeit,
1897–98, I.

—— Arbeitstheilung und Frauenrecht. Neue Zeit, 1900–1901, I.

—— Zur Urgeschichte der Ehe und Familie. Ergänzungsheft. Neue Zeit,
1912–1913.



Dalhoff, N. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la criminalité.
Actes du congr. pénit. intern. de Bruxelles, 1900, IV. Bruxelles et
Berne, 1901.

Dallemagne. Dégénérés et déséquilibrés. Bruxelles et Paris, 1895.

—— Théorie de la criminalité. Paris.

Damme. Die Kriminalität und ihre Zusammenhänge in der Provinz
Schleswig-Holstein. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., XII.

Dargun, L. v. Ursprung und Entwicklungs-Geschichte des Eigenthums.
Zeitschr. f. vergl. Rechtswissensch., V.

—— Egoismus und Altruismus in der Nationalökonomie. Leipzig, 1885.

—— Mutterrecht und Vaterrecht. Leipzig, 1892.

Darwin, Ch. The Descent of Man. Chicago and New York. Rand, McNally &
Co.

Denis, H. L’influence de la crise économique sur la criminalité et le
penchant au crime de Quetelet. Bull. de la Soc. d’Anthr. de Bruxelles,
1885–1886.

—— La criminalité et la crise économique. Actes du III Congr. d’anthr.
crim. Bruxelles, 1893.

—— Le socialisme et les causes économiques et sociales du crime. Compte
rendu V Congr. d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam, 1901.

—— Les index numbers (nombres indices) des phénomènes moraux. Académie
royale de Belgique. II serie, Tome IV, 1911.

Després, A. La prostitution en France. Paris, 1883.

Dietz H., Die Militärstrafrechtspflege im Lichte der Kriminalstatistik.
Oldenburg, i/Gr. 1908.

Dix, A. Sozial-Moral. Leipzig, 1898.

—— Alkoholismus und Arbeiterschaft. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., N. F., II.

Dochow, F. Die Kriminalität im Amtsbezirk Heidelberg. Berlin, 1906.

Doehn, B. Der Anarchismus und seine Bekämpfung. Zeitschrift f. d. ges.
Strafr. w., XX.

Dostojewsky, F. M. Memoiren aus einem Totenhaus. Translated by Moses.
Leipzig.

Douglas, W. M. The Criminal: Some Social and Economic Aspects.
Proceedings of the Royal Philosophical Society of Glasgow, XXXIII.
Glasgow, 1902.

Drähms, A. The Criminal. New York, 1900.

Drill, D. Des principes fondamentaux de l’école d’anthr. criminelles.
Actes III Congr. d’anthr. crim. Bruxelles, 1893.

—— Les fondements et le but de la responsabilité pénale. Comptes rendus
IV Congr. d’anthr. crim. Genève, 1896.

Dubois, F. Le péril anarchiste. Paris, 1894.

Dubuisson, P. Les voleuses des grands magasins. Archives etc., XVI.

Du Camp, M. Les plaies sociales. La prostitution à Paris. Journ. d.
Econom., 1870.

Ducpetiaux, Ed. De la condition physique et morale des jeunes ouvriers
I. Bruxelles, 1843.

—— Mémoire sur le paupérisme dans les Flandres. Bruxelles, 1850.

Dugdale, R. L. The Jukes. New York and London, 1884.

Duprat, G. L. La criminalité dans l’adolescence. Paris, 1909.

Durkheim, E. Le suicide. Paris, 1897.

Dijck, G. van. Eenige beschouwingen over het misdrijf van Kindermoord.
Groningen, 1908.



Eggert. Not und Verbrechen. Jahresbericht der Rheinisch. Westf.
Gefängnis-Gesellschaft 1903/4. Düsseldorf.

Einiges über die Prostitution in Gegenwart und Zukunft. (Anonymous.)
Neue Zeit, 1891–1892, I.

Elliot, J. H. The Increase of Material Prosperity and of Moral Agents
Compared with the State of Crime and Pauperism. Journ. of the Stat.
Society of London, 1868.

Ellis, H. The Criminal. London, 1907.

—— Verbrecher und Verbrechen. Transl. Kurella. Leipzig, 1895.

—— Geschlecht und Gesellschaft II. Transl. Kurella. Würzburg, 1911.

Eltsbacher, P. Der Anarchismus. Berlin, 1900.

Embden, D. van. Darwinisme en demokratie. ’s Gravenhage, 1901.

Enfantin, B. P. Œuvres. Paris, 1868.

Engels, F. Die Lage der arbeitenden Klasse in England. Stuttgart, 1892.

—— The Condition of the Working Class in England. Transl.
Wischnewetzky. London, 1892.

—— Umrisse zu einer Kritik der Nationalökonomie. (Gesammelte Schriften
v. K. Marx u. F. Engels, 1841–1850, I. Stuttgart, 1902.)

—— Sur la conception matérialiste de l’histoire. Devenir social, III.

—— Der Ursprung der Familie, des Privateigenthums und des Staats.
Stuttgart, 1898.

—— und K. Marx. Die heilige Familie. (Gesammelte Schriften etc., II.
Stuttgart, 1902.)

Englands industrielle Reservearmee. (Anonymous.) Neue Zeit, 1884.

Enquête betreffende werking en uitbreiding der wet van 19 September
1874 en naar den toestand van fabrieken en werkplaatsen. ’s Gravenhage,
1887.

Enquête gehouden door de staatscommissie benoemd volgens de wet van 19
Januari 1890. ’s Gravenhage, 1890–1894.

Enthoren, F. Studie over het anarchisme van de daad. Amsterdam, 1901.

Ergebnisse der schweizerischen Kriminalstatistik während der Jahre
1892–1896. Bern, 1900.

Ergebnisse der Strafrechtspflege der im Reichsrate vertretenen
Königreichen und Ländern im Jahre 1899 Œsterreichische Statistik. Wien,
1903.

Ettinger, S. Das Verbrecherproblem. Bern, 1909.

Everest, R. On the Influence of Social Degradation in Producing
Pauperism and Crime, etc. Journal of the Stat. Soc. of London, 1855.

Evert, G. Zur Statistik rückfälliger Verbrecher in Preussen. Zeitschr.
d. k. preussischen stat. Bureaus, XXXIX. 1899.



Faucher, L. Mémoire sur le caractère et sur le mouvement de la
criminalité en Angleterre. Journ. des Econ., 1850.

—— Études sur l’Angleterre I. Paris, 1856.

Faure, Abbé. Souvenir de la Roquette. Paris.

Fehlinger, H. Erwerbsarbeit und Kriminalität von Kindern u. Frauen in
den Ver. Staaten. Archiv f. Krim. Anthr. etc., XLIX.

Feith, J. Misdadige Kinderen. Amsterdam, 1911.

Fekete, J. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la criminalité.
Actes du congr. pénit. intern. de Bruxelles. Bruxelles et Berne, 1901.

Feld, W. Die Kinder der in Fabriken arbeitenden Frauen und ihre
Verpflegung. Dresden, 1906.

Fenton, F. The Influence of Newspaper Presentations upon the Growth of
Crime and other Anti-social Activity. Chicago, 1911.

Féré, Ch. Dégénérescence et criminalité. Paris, 1888.

—— La famille névropathique. Paris, 1894.

Ferrante Capetti, L. Reati e psicopatie sessuali. Torino, 1910.

Ferrero, G. Le crime d’adultère. Archives etc., IX.

—— et C. Lombroso. La femme criminelle et la prostituée. Transl.
Meille. Paris, 1896.

Ferrero di Cavallerleone, L., et C. Placido. Essais de criminologie
militaire. Compt. rendus du VI Congr. d’anthr. crim. Turin, 1908.

Ferri, E. Studi sulla criminalità in Francia 1826–1878. Annali di
Statistica, 1881.

—— Socialismo e criminalità. Torino, 1883.

—— Variations thermométriques et criminalité. Archives d’anthr. crim.,
I.

—— La sociologie criminelle. Paris, 1893. Amer. ed. transl. Kelly and
Lisle, Boston, 1916 (Modern Criminal Science Series).

—— L’omicidio. Torino, 1895.

—— Atlante antropologico-statistico dell’ omicidio. Torino, 1895.

—— La théorie sociologique de M. Tarde. Devenir social, 1895.

—— Kriminelle Anthropologie u. Sozialismus. Neue Zeit, 1895–1896, II.

—— Le crime comme phénomène social. Annales de l’institut intern. de
sociologie, 1896.

—— Eine Verirrung des XIX Jahrhunderts. Neue Zeit, 1898–99, II.

—— Les criminels dans l’art et la littérature. Transl. Laurent. Paris.

Ferriani, L. La infanticida. Milano, 1886.

—— L’amore in tribunale Bologna. 1889.

—— Minderjährige Verbrecher. Autorisirte Ausgabe. Berlin, 1896.

—— Entartete Mütter. Autor. Ausgabe. Berlin, 1897.

—— Schlaue und glückliche Verbrecher. Aut. Ausg. Berlin, 1899.

Fiaux, L. La prostitution en Russie. Progrès médicale. 1893.

Finkelnburg, K. Die Bestraften in Deutschland. Berlin, 1912.

Fischer, E. Laienbemerkungen zur Reform des Strafrechts. Sozialistische
Monatshefte X1.

—— K. Denkwürdigkeiten und Erinnerungen eines Arbeiters. Jena u.
Leipzig, 1903–1904.

Fletcher, J. Moral and Educational Statistics of England and Wales.
Journ. of the Stat. Society of London, 1847, 1849.

Florian, E., and G. Cavaglieri. I vagabondi I, II. Torino, 1897, 1900.

Flynt, J. Tramping with Tramps. New York, 1899.

Foldes, B. Einige Ergebnisse der neueren Kriminalstatistik. Zeitschr.
f. d. ges. Strafr. w., XI.

Forel, A. Die sexuelle Frage. München, 1913.

—— Verbrechen und konstitutionelle Seelenabnormitäten. München, 1907.

Fornasari di Verce, E. La criminalità e le vicende economiche d’ Italia
1873–1890. Torino, 1894.

Fourier, Ch. Œuvres complètes I et III. Paris, 1841.

Francken, C. J. Wijnaendts. De evolutie van het huwelijk. Leiden, 1894.

Frank, F. Das Fürsorgeerziehungsgesetz in Preussen. Neue Zeit, XXVII1.

Frankenstein, K. Die Lage der Arbeiterinnen in den deutschen
Grossstädten. Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung etc., XII2.

Frassati, A. Die neue positive Schule in Russland. Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
Strafr., X.

Frauenstädt, P. Kriminalistische Heimatkunde. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., VI.

Frégier, H. A. Les classes dangereuses de la population dans les
grandes villes I. Paris, 1840.

Fröhlich, R. Ergebnisse einer Umfrage über den Alkoholgenuss der
Schulkinder in Niederösterreich. VIII Intern. Congress g. d.
Alkoholismus. Wien, 1901.

Fuld, L. Der Einfluss der Lebensmittelpreise auf die Bewegung der
strafbaren Handlungen. Mainz, 1881.



Gaedeken, P. Contribution statistique à la réaction de l’organisme sous
l’influence physico-chimique des agents météorologiques. Archives etc.,
XXIV.

Galle, J. Untersuchungen über die Kriminalität in der Provinz
Schlesien. Gerichtssaal, LXXI und LXXII.

—— Die Kriminalität in Stadt und Land in ihrer Beziehung zur
Berufsverteilung. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., XXX.

Galton, F. Inquiries into Human Faculty and its Development. London,
1883.

—— Hereditary Genius. London, 1892.

Garner, J. W. Homicide in American Cities. Journal of Crim. Law and
Criminology, III.

Garnier, P. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la criminalité.
Actes du congr. pénitentiaire à Bruxelles, IV. Bruxelles et Berne,
1901.

—— La criminalité juvénile. Compte rendu V congr. d’anthr. crim.
Amsterdam, 1901.

Garofalo, R. La criminologie. Paris, 1890. Amer. ed. transl. Millar,
Boston, 1914 (Modern Criminal Science Series).

—— La superstition socialiste. Transl. A. Dietrich. Paris, 1895.

—— L’influence des prédispositions et du milieu dans la criminalité.
Bericht über den VII Intern. Kongr. für Krim. Anthr. Heidelberg, 1912.

Garraud, R., et P. Bernard. Des attentats à la pudeur et des viols sur
les enfants. Archives etc., I.

Gaupp, R. Ueber den heutigen Stand der Lehre vom “geborenen”
Verbrecher. Monatschr. etc., I.

Gautier, A. Le procès Lucheni. Schweizerische Zeitschr. f. Strafrecht,
XI.

Gautier, E. Le monde des prisons. Archives etc., III.

Geill. Kriminal-anthropologische Untersuchungen dänischer
Sittlichkeitsverbrecher. Archiv. f. Krim. Anthr. etc., XX.

Genil-Perrin, G., et Ch. Vallon. Crime et altruisme. Archives etc.,
XXVIII.

Gerechtelijke Statistiek van het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden 1887–1899.
’s Gravenhage, 1888–1901.

Girguet, M. Mémoires. Paris, 1840.

Gizycki, P. v. Wie urteilen Schulkinder über Funddiebstahl? Zeitschr.
f. Kinderforschung, VIII.

Gleispach, W. Ueber Kindesmord. Archiv etc., XXVII.

Godwin, W. Inquiry Concerning Political Justice. London, 1796.

Goes, F. v. d. Socialisme en feminisme. Tweemaandelijksch Tijdschrift,
VI.

Göhre, P. Drie maanden fabrieksarbeider. Transl. H. Mercier. Amsterdam.

Gouzer, J. Psychologie de l’anarchiste. Archives etc., IX.

Graaf, H. T. de. Karakter en behandeling van veroordeelden wegens
landlooperij en bedelarij. Groningen, 1914.

Grabe, E. v. Prostitution, Kriminalität und Psychopathie. Archiv etc.,
XLVIII.

Gradnauer, G. Das Elend des Strafvollzugs. Berlin, 1905.

Granier, C. La femme criminelle. Paris, 1906.

Grosmolard, M. Criminalité juvénile. Archives etc. XVIII.

Grosse, E. Die Formen der Familie und die Formen der Wirtschaft.
Freiburg i/B u. Leipzig, 1896.

Grotjahn, A. Der Alkoholismus. Leipzig, 1898.

Gruber, G. B. Der Alkoholismus. Leipzig, 1911.

Gruhle, H. W. Ursachen der jugendlichen Verwahrlosung und Kriminalität.
Berlin, 1912.

Guerry, A. M. Essai sur la statistique morale de la France. Paris,
1833.

Gumplowicz, L. Das Verbrechen als soziale Erscheinung. (Soziologische
Essays. Innsbrück, 1899.)

—— Grundriss der Soziologie. Wien, 1905.

Guyot, J. La prostitution. Paris, 1882.

Gystrow, E. (Pseudonym of W. Hellpach.) Sozialpathologische Probleme
der Gegenwart. Soz. Monatshefte V1.

—— Liebe u. Liebesleben im XIX Jahrhundert. Berlin, 1902.



Hamel, G. A. van. De tegenwoordige beweging op het gebied van het
strafrecht. (Verspreide opstellen, I. Leiden, 1912.)

—— L’anarchisme et le combat contre l’anarchisme au point de vue de
l’anthropologie criminelle. Actes du IV Congr. d’anthr. crim. Genève,
1896.

—— J. A. van. Strafrechtspolitiek van voor honderd jaar. (Gids, 1909,
II.)

Hamon, A. De la définition du crime. Archives etc., VIII.

—— Psychologie de l’anarchiste-socialiste. Paris, 1895.

—— Psychologie du militaire professionnel. Paris, 1904.

Hatzig, K. Der Mädchenhandel. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafr. w., XX.

Haury. La paresse pathologique. Archives etc., XXVIII.

Haussonville, d’. Le combat contre le vice, II “La criminalité.” Revue
des deux mondes, 1887.

Heim, H. Die jüngsten und die ältesten Verbrecher. Berlin, 1897.

Helie, J. Le vagabondage des mineurs. Mayenne, 1899.

Hellpach, W. Soziale Ursachen und Wirkungen der Nervosität. Politisch.
Anthrop. Revue, I.

—— Der Kampf gegen die Geschlechtskrankheiten. Soz. Monatshefte, VII.

—— See also: Gystrow.

Hellwig, A. Verbrechen und Aberglaube. Leipzig, 1908.

—— Die Beziehungen zwischen Schundlitteratur, Schundfilms u.
Verbrechen. Archiv etc., LIII.

Helvetius, C. A. De l’homme. (Œuvres. Paris, 1795.)

Henderson, Ch. Richmond. Introduction to the Study of the Dependent,
Defective and Delinquent Classes. Boston, 1909.

Herkner, H. Die Arbeiterfrage. Berlin, 1905.

Hermann, T. Die Prostitution und ihr Anhang. Leipzig, 1905.

Herz, H. Die Kriminalität des Weibes nach den Ergebnissen der neueren
oesterreichischen Statistik. Archiv etc., XVIII.

—— Verbrechen und Verbrechertum in Oesterreich. Tübingen, 1908.

Hesse, R. Les criminels peints par eux-mêmes. Paris, 1912.

Hessen, R. Die Prostitution in Deutschland. München, 1910.

Hirsch, P. Verbrechen und Prostitution. Berlin, 1897.

Hirschberg. Soziale Lage der arbeitenden Klasse in Berlin. Berlin,
1897.

Hirschfeld, M. Ursachen und Wesen des Uranismus. Jahrbuch f. sexuelle
Zwischenstufen V.

—— Die historische Entwicklung des Alkoholmissbrauchs. VIII Intern.
Congr. g. d. Alkoholismus.

—— Die Homosexualität des Mannes und des Weibes. Berlin, 1914.

Hobhouse, L. T. Morals in Evolution. London, 1908.

Hoegel, H. Die Straffälligkeit der Jugendlichen. Archiv etc., X.

—— Die Straffälligkeit der Weibes. Archiv etc., V.

—— Die Grenzen der Kriminalstatistik. Statistische Monatschrift.
XXXIII.

—— Kriminalstatistik und Kriminalaetiologie. Monatschrift etc., VIII.

Holbach. Système social. Londres, 1773.

Holmes, Th. Pictures and Problems from London Police Courts. London,
1902.

Holtz, L. Les crimes passionels. Paris, 1904.

Holzendorff, Fr. v. Die Psychologie des Mordes. (Sammlung
gemeinverständlicher Vorträge, X.)

Homburger, M. Der Einfluss der Schundlitteratur auf jugendliche
Verbrecher und Selbstmörder. Monatschr. etc., VI.

—— Ueber den Zusammenhang zwischen den Zahlen der in den Fabriken
beschäftigten Personen unter 18 Jahren und der Zahl der Verbrechen
solcher Personen. Monatschrift etc., VII.

—— Lebensschicksale geisteskranker Strafgefangene. Berlin, 1912.

Hoofdstuk, Een vergeten. (Anonymous.) Amsterdam, 1898.

Hoppe, A. Alkohol und Kriminalität. Wiesbaden, 1906.

Hotter, C. Alkohol und Verbrechen in Niederbayern. Monatschrift etc.,
VIII.

Hübner, A. H. Ueber Prostituirte und ihre strafrechtliche Behandlung.
Monatschr. etc., III.

Hügel, Fe. S. Zur Geschichte, Statistik, und Regelung der Prostitution.
Wien, 1865.

Hugo, C. Kind und Gesellschaft. Neue Zeit, 1894–95, I.

Hulzen, G. v. Van de zelfkant der samenleving. Gids, 1903.

Hunter, R. Das Elend der neuen Welt. Transl. Südekum. Berlin, 1908.



Illing, J. Die Zahlen der Kriminalität in Preussen, 1854–1884.
Zeitschr. d. k. preussischen stat. Bureaus, 1885.



Jaarcijfers voor het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden. Rijk in Europa 1901.
’s Gravenhage, 1902.

Jacquart, C. La criminalité belge 1868–1909. Louvain, 1912.

Jacquetty, G. Étude statistique de la criminalité juvénile en France.
Lyon-Paris, 1912.

Jaeger, J. Zunahme der Verbrechen und Abhilfe. Leipzig, 1898.

Jeannel, J. De la prostitution dans les grandes villes au XIXe siècle
et de l’extinction des maladies vénériennes. Paris, 1874.

Jelgersma, G. De geboren misdadiger. Tijdschrift v. Strafrecht, 1891.

Jellinek, C. Kellnerinnenelend. Archiv f. Socialw. und Socialpolitik,
XXIV.

Jhering, R. v. Der Zweck im Recht, I. Leipzig, 1884.

Joly, H. Le crime. Paris, 1888.

—— La France criminelle, 1889.

—— L’enfance coupable. Paris, 1904.

—— La Belgique criminelle. Paris, 1907.

Jörger, J. La famille “Zéro.” Archives etc., XXIII.

Judicial Statistics, England and Wales. Part I, Criminal Statistics,
1894–1900, 1905. London, 1896–1902, 1907.

Judicial Statistics, Ireland. Part I, Criminal Statistics. Dublin,
1906.

Jugendgeschichte einer Arbeiterin. (Anonymous.) München, 1907.



Kampffmeyer, P. Geschichte der modernen Gesellschaftsklassen in
Deutschland. Berlin, 1896.

—— Das Wohnungselend der Grossstädte und seine Beziehungen zur
Verbreitung der Geschlechtskrankheiten und zur Prostitution.
Verhandlungen d. 1en Kongresses d. deutschen Gesellsch. z. Bekämpfung
der Geschlechtskrankheiten. Leipzig, 1903.

—— Die Wohnungsmissstände im Prostitution- und im Schlafgängerwesen und
ihre gesetzliche Reform. Zeitschr. z. Bekämpfung d.
Geschlechtskrankheiten III.

—— Die Prostitution als soziale Klassenerscheinung und ihre
sozialpolitische Bekämpfung. Berlin, 1905.

Kan, J. v. Les causes sociales de la criminalité. Compte rendu V Congr.
d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam. 1901.

Kan, J. v. Les causes économiques de la criminalité. Paris-Lyon, 1903.

Kauffmann, M. Psychologie des Verbrechens. Berlin, 1912.

Kautsky, K. Die sozialen Triebe in der Tierwelt. Neue Zeit, 1883.

—— Die sozialen Triebe in der Menschenwelt. Neue Zeit, 1884.

—— Die Indianerfrage. Neue Zeit, 1885.

—— Die Entstehung des Christentums. Neue Zeit, 1885.

—— Thomas More und seine Utopie. Stuttgart, 1888.

—— Der Alcoholismus und seine Bekämpfung. Neue Zeit, 1890–1891, I.

—— Das Erfurter Programm. Stuttgart, 1892.

—— Eine Naturgeschichte des politischen Verbrechers. Neue Zeit,
1892–93, II.

—— Lombroso und seine Vertheidiger. Neue Zeit, 1893–94, II.

—— Die materialistische Geschichtsauffassung und der psychologische
Antrieb. Neue Zeit, 1895–96, II.

—— Karl Marx, oekonomische Lehren. Stuttgart, 1898.

—— Geschichte des Socialismus in Einzeldarstellungen, Ersten Band,
Zweiter Theil. Stuttgart, 1895.

—— Sozialreform und soziale Revolution. Berlin, 1902.

—— Ethik und materialistische Geschichtsauffassung. Stuttgart, 1906.

Kelleo-Kranz, C. de. Formes primitives de la famille. Revue
internationale de sociologie, VIII.

Kempf, R. Das Leben der jungen Fabrikmädchen in München. Leipzig, 1911.

Kende, M. Die Entartung des Menschengeschlechts.

Key, E. Das Jahrhundert des Kindes. Auth. transl. Berlin, 1902.

Kinberg, O. Alcool et criminalité. Archives etc., XXVIII.

Knoblauch, F. Bettel und Landstreicherei im Königreiche Bayern
1893–1899. München, 1910.

Kohler, J. Shakespeare vor dem Forum der Jurisprudenz. Würzburg, 1883.

Kolb, G. F. Handbuch der vergleichenden Statistik. Leipzig, 1860.

Korn, A. Strafrechtsreform oder Sittenpolizei. Jahrbuch f. Gesetzgebung
etc., XXI3.

Korner. Critic on “Verbrechen und Verbrecher in Preussen 1854–1878” of
Starke. Jahrbücher f. Nat. oek. u. Stat., N. F., XIII.

Kovalevsky, M. Tableau des origines et de l’évolution de la famille et
de la propriété. Stockholm, 1890.

—— Les origines du devoir. Revue intern. de sociologie, II.

—— P. La psychologie criminelle. Paris, 1903.

Krafft-Ebing, R. v. Psychopathia sexualis. Stuttgart, 1898.

Kräpelin, E. Psychiatrie I.

Krauss, A. Die Psychologie des Verbrechens. Tübingen, 1884.

Krauss, F. A. K. Der Kampf gegen die Verbrechensursachen. Paderborn,
1905.

Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1888, 1894–1896, 1898–1900, 1908, 1911.
Statistik des Deutschen Reichs, N. F., 1888, etc.

Kritschewsky, B. Die Korruption in der französischen Demokratie. Neue
Zeit, XXVIII2.

Kropotkin, P. Paroles d’un révolté. Paris.

—— Mutual Aid among Animals. Nineteenth Century, 1890.

—— Mutual Aid among Savages. Nineteenth Century, 1891.

—— Mutual Aid among the Barbarians. Nineteenth Century, 1892.

—— Mutual Aid. London, 1908.

Kühn, J. Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert. Leipzig, 1871.

Kulischer. Der Dualismus der Ethik bei den primitiven Völkern.
Zeitschr. f. Ethnologie, 1885.

Kummer, F. Die Geschichte des grossen amerikanischen Vermögen. Neue
Zeit, XXX2.

Kürbitz-Sonnenschein, W. Der Geisteszustand der Kindermörderinnen.
Archiv f. Krim. Anthr. etc., LII.

Kurella, H. Naturgeschichte des Verbrechers. Stuttgart, 1893.

—— Zurechnungsfähigkeit, Kriminalanthropologie. Halle a/S 1903.

—— Anthropologie und Strafrecht. Würzburg, 1912.

Kürz, E. Zur Prophylaxe der Roheitsdelikte. Monatschr. etc., II.



Lacassagne, A. Marche de la criminalité en France 1825–1880. Revue
Scientifique, 1881.

—— Les vols à l’étalage et dans les grands magasins. Actes IVe congr.
d’anthr. crim. Genève, 1896.

—— L’assassinat du président Carnot. Archives etc., IX.

—— et E. Martin. Des résultats positifs et indiscutables que
l’anthropologie criminelle peut fournir à l’élaboration ou
l’application des lois. Compte rendu Ve Congr. d’anthr. crim.
Amsterdam, 1901.

Lacaze, H. De la criminalité féminine en France. Lyon, 1910.

Ladame, P. De la prostitution dans ses rapports avec l’alcoolisme, le
crime, et la folie. Neuchâtel, 1884.

—— et E. Régis. Le régicide Lucheni. Archives etc., XXII.

Lafargue, P. Der wirtschaftliche Materialismus. Höttingen-Zürich, 1886.

—— Der Ehebruch in Gegenwart und Vergangenheit. Neue Zeit, 1889.

—— Die Kriminalität in Frankreich 1840–1886. Neue Zeit, 1890.

—— Der Ursprung der Idee des Gerechten und Ungerechten. Neue Zeit,
1898–99, II.

Lanessan, J. L. de. La lutte contre le crime. Paris, 1910.

Lang, O. Alkoholgenuss und Verbrechen. Basel, 1895.

Laschi, R. Le crime financier. Lyon-Paris, 1901.

—— und C. Lombroso. Der politische Verbrecher und die Revolutionen.
Auth. transl. Kurella. Hamburg, 1892.

Laspeyres, E. Der Einfluss der Wohnung auf die Sittlichkeit. Berlin,
1869.

Lassalle, F. Die Feste, die Presse und der Frankfurter Abgeordnetentag.
Reden und Schriften, II. Berlin, 1893.

—— Offenes Antwort-Schreiben. Reden etc., II.

Laurent, E. Les habitués des prisons de Paris. Paris, 1890.

—— La criminalité infantile. Paris, 1908.

—— Le criminel. Paris, 1908.

Leale, H. De la criminalité des sexes. Archives etc., XXV.

Lecour, C. J. La prostitution à Paris et à Londres. Paris, 1870.

Legrain. Conséquences sociales de l’alcoolisme des ascendants au point
de vue de la dégénérescence, de la morale et de la criminalité. Actes
IV Congr. d’anthr. crim. Genève, 1896.

Lenz, A. Die Zwangserziehung in England. Stuttgart, 1894.

Lepel, V. v. Prostitution beim Theater. Zürich.

Leppmann, F. Die Sittlichkeitsverbrecher. Vierteljahrschrift f.
gerichtl. Medizin etc., XXIX, XXX.

Letourneau, Ch. L’évolution de la morale. Paris, 1887.

—— L’évolution du mariage et de la famille. Paris, 1888.

—— L’évolution de la propriété. Paris, 1889.

—— L’évolution juridique. Paris. 1891.

Leuss, H. Aus dem Zuchthause. Berlin, 1903.

Levasseur, E. La population française II. Paris, 1891.

Ley, A., et R. Charpentier. Alcoolisme et criminalité. Bruxelles, 1910.

Lindenau, H. Beruf und Verbrechen. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafr. w.,
XXIV.

Lindenberg, G. Die Ergebnisse der deutschen Kriminalstatistik
1882–1892. Jahrb. f. Nat. oek. etc., III. Folge, VIII.

Linguet, S. N. H. Théorie des loix civiles. Londres, 1767.

Lippert, H. Die Prostitution in Hamburg. Hamburg, 1848.

Liszt, F. v. Die sozialpolitische Auffassung des Verbrechens.
Sozialpolitisches Centralblatt, 1892.

—— Die gesellschaftlichen Ursachen des Verbrechens. Sozialpolitisches
Centralblatt, 1872.

—— Das Verbrechen als Social-pathologische Erscheinung. Dresden, 1899.

—— Das gewerbmässige Verbrechen. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafr. w., XXI.

—— Die gesellschaftlichen Faktoren der Kriminalität. Zeitschr. etc.,
XXIII.

—— Die psychologischen Grundlagen der Kriminalpolitik. Zeitschr. etc.,
XVI.

—— Kriminal-politische Ausgaben. Zeitschr. etc., IX, X, XII.

Logan, W. The Great Social Evil. London, 1871.

Lombroso, C. Der Verbrecher. Transl. Fränkel. Hamburg, 1894.

—— Les palimpsestes des prisons. Lyon-Paris, 1894.

—— Le crime, causes et remèdes. Paris, 1899.

—— Crime, Its Causes and Remedies. Transl. Horton. Boston, 1910.

—— et G. Ferrero. La femme criminelle et la prostituée. Transl. L.
Meille. Paris, 1896.

—— und R. Laschi. Der politische Verbrecher und die Revolutionen.
Autorisirte Uebersetzung von H. Kurella. Hamburg, 1892.

Longard, J. Ueber “moral insanity.” Monatschr. etc., II.

Loosjes, C. Bijdrage tot de studie van de criminaliteit der vrouw.
Haarlem, 1894.

Löwe, Ph. Die Prostitution aller Zeiten und Völker mit besonderer
Berücksichtigung von Berlin. Berlin, 1852.

Löwenstimm, A. Aberglaube und Strafrecht. Berlin, 1897.

—— Fanatismus und Verbrechen. Berlin, 1901.

—— Aberglaube und Verbrechen. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., VI.

—— Aberglaube und Gesetz. Archiv etc., XXV.

Lux, H. Die Prostitution. Berlin, 1892.

Lux, H. Socialpolitisches Handbuch. Berlin, 1892.

—— Die Sittlichkeitsverbrechen in Deutschland in kriminalstatistischer
Beleuchtung. Archiv für sociale Gesetzgeb. u. Stat. V.



Mably. De la législation ou principes des loix. Paris, 1792.

Mackirdy, A., and W. N. Willis. The White Slave Market. London.

Magnan. De l’enfance des criminels dans ses rapports avec la
prédisposition naturelle au crime. Actes du II Congr. d’anthr. crim.
Paris.

Maine, H. S. Village Communities in the East and West. London, 1876.

Makarewicz, J. L’évolution de la peine. Archives etc., XIII.

—— Einführung in die Philosophie des Strafrechts. Stuttgart, 1906.

Malarce, M. A. de. Moralité comparée des diverses parties de la France
d’après la criminalité. Journal de la Société de statistique de Paris,
1860.

Malgat, J. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la criminalité.
Actes du congr. pénitent. intern. de Bruxelles, 1900, IV. Bruxelles et
Berne, 1901.

Mandl, H. Die Wiener Presskorruption. Neue Zeit, 1884.

Manes, C. Capitalismo e criminalità. Roma, 1912.

Manouvrier, L. Les crânes des suppliciés. Archives etc., I.

—— Les aptitudes et les actes. L’ère nouvelle, 1893.

—— La genèse normale du crime. Bulletin de la Société d’anthropologie
de Paris, 1893.

—— L’atavisme et le crime. L’ère nouvelle, 1894.

—— Existe-t-il des caractères anatomiques propres aux criminels? Les
criminels présentent-ils en moyenne certains caractères anatomiques
particuliers? Comment doit-on interpréter ces caractères? Actes II
Congr. d’anthr. crim. Paris.

—— Quelques cas de criminalité juvénile et commençante. Archives etc.,
XXVII.

Manzini, V. Le varie specie di furto nella storia e nella sociologia
III. Torino, 1913.

Marambat, V. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la
criminalité. Actes Congr. pénitent. intern. de Bruxelles, 1900, IV.
Bruxelles et Berne, 1901.

Marat, J. P. Plan de la législation criminelle. Paris, 1790.

Marie, A., et R. Meunier. Les vagabonds. Paris, 1908.

Marro, A. I caratteri dei delinquenti. Torino, 1887.

Martin, E. Études sur l’enfance coupable. Archives etc., XXVIII.

—— et A. Lacassagne. Des résultats positifs et indiscutables que
l’anthropologie criminelle peut fournir à l’élaboration ou
l’application des lois. Compte rendu V congr. d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam,
1901.

Martineau, L. La prostitution clandestine. Paris, 1885.

Marx, K. Zur Kritik der politischen Oekonomie. Stuttgart, 1897.

—— Das Kapital I. Hamburg, 1900.

—— und F. Engels. Die heilige Familie. (Gesammelte Schriften etc., II.
Stuttgart, 1902.)

Masoin, M. L’alcoolisme dans ses rapports avec la criminalité. Bull. de
l’ac. royale de médecine de Belgique, 1896. Bruxelles, 1896.

Maudsley, H. The Physiology and Pathology of Mind. London, 1868.

Maxwell, J. Le crime et la société. Paris, 1912.

Mayhew, A., and J. Binny. The Criminal Prisons of London. London, 1862.

Mayr, G. v. Statistik der gerichtlichen Polizei im Königreiche Bayern.
München, 1867.

—— Die Gesetzmässigkeit im Gesellschaftsleben. München, 1877.

—— Statistik und Gesellschaftslehre II, III, Freiburg i/B, 1897.
Tübingen, 1910.

—— Forschungsgebiet und Forschungsziele der Kriminalstatistik.
Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., XXXII.

—— Kriminalstatistik und Kriminalaetiologie. Monatschr. etc., VIII.

—— Nochmals Kriminalstatistik und Kriminalaetiologie. Monatschr. etc.,
IX.

Mercier, E. L’influence du bien-être matériel sur la criminalité.
Paris, 1854.

Merens, A. H. J. Over het onderzoek naar den invloed der dronkenschap
op de criminaliteit. Haarlem, 1902.

Mesdag, S. V. Iets over landloopers en bedelaars. Tijdschrift v.
Strafrecht, XV.

Meslier, J. Le testament de. Amsterdam, 1864.

Meunier, R., et A. Marie. Les vagabonds. Paris, 1908.

Meyer. Schundlitteratur und Schundfilms. Archiv etc., LIII.

—— A. Die Verbrechen in ihrem Zusammenhang mit den wirtschaftlichen und
sozialen Verhältnissen in Kanton Zürich. Jena, 1895.

Minovici, M. Remarques sur la criminalité en Roumanie. Comptes rend. VI
congr. d’anthr. crim. Turin, 1908.

Mischler. Hauptergebnisse in moralischer Hinricht. Handbuch d.
Gefängniswesens II. Hamburg, 1888.

Misdadige jeugd in het havenbedrijf. (Anonymous.) Rotterdam, 1904.

Mittelstaedt. Critic on Starke. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., IV.

Moll, A. Handbuch der Sexualwissenschaften. Leipzig, 1912.

Mönkemöller, O. Korrektionsanstalt und Landarmenhaus. Leipzig, 1908.

—— Zur Kriminalität des Kindesalters. Archiv etc., XL.

—— Die Kriminalität der Korrigendin. Monatschr. etc., V.

Moquette, J. J. R. Onderzoekingen over volksvoeding in de gemeente
Utrecht. Utrecht, 1907.

Moreau, G. Le monde des prisons. Paris, 1887.

—— Souvenirs de la petite et de la grande Roquette. Paris.

Moreau (de Tours), P. L’homicide commis par les enfants. Paris, 1882.

Moreau-Christophe, L. M. Du problème de la misère, III. Paris, 1851.

—— Le monde des coquins. Paris, 1863.

Morel, J. La prophylaxie et le traitement du criminel récidiviste.
Compte rend. V congr. d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam, 1901.

Morelly. Code de la nature. 1755.

Morgan, L. H. Houses and House-life of the American Aborigines.
Washington, 1881.

—— Ancient Society, N. Y. 1878. Transl. Eichhoff. Die Urgesellschaft.
Stuttgart, 1891.

Morrison, W. D. Crime and Its Causes. London, 1891.

—— Juvenile Offenders. London, 1896.

—— The Interpretation of Criminal Statistics. Journal of the Stat. Soc.
of London, 1897.

More, Th. Utopia. Transl. Ralph Robynson. Cambridge (Eng.), 1891.

Mosse, M., und G. Tugendreich. Krankheit und soziale Lage. München,
1912–1913.

Motet, M. De l’éducation correctionnelle. Actes II congr. d’anthr.
crim. Paris.

Muller, N. Biografisch-aetiologisch onderzoek over recidive bij
misdrijven tegen den eigendom. Utrecht, 1908.

Müller, Fr. W. De prostitutie. Zutphen, 1870.

Müller, H. Untersuchungen über die Bewegung der Criminalität in ihrem
Zusammenhang mit den wirtschaftlichen Verhältnissen. Halle a. S., 1899.

Müller-Lyer, F. Formen der Ehe. München, 1911.

—— Die Familie. München, 1912.

—— Phasen der Liebe. München, 1913.



Näcke, P. Verbrechen u. Wahnsinn beim Weibe. Wien u. Leipzig, 1894.

—— Die neueren Erscheinungen auf kriminal-anthropologischen Gebiete und
ihre Bedeutung. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafr. w., XIV.

—— Emile Zola. In memoriam. Seine Beziehungen zur
Kriminal-anthropologie und Soziologie. Archiv, etc., XI.

—— Ein Besuch bei den Homosexuellen in Berlin. Archiv etc., XV.

—— Critic on “Criminalité et conditions économiques” of Bonger. Archiv,
etc., XXI.

—— Die Ueberbleibsel der Lombrosischen kriminalanthropologischen
Theorien. Archiv etc., L.

Nansen, F. Eskimoleben. Leipzig und Berlin, 1903.

—— Eskimo Life. Transl. Archer. London, 1894.

Neher, A. Die geheime und öffentliche Prostitution in Stuttgart,
Karlsruhe und München. Paderborn, 1912.

Neumann, H. Die jugendlichen Berliner unehelicher Herkunft. Jahrb. f.
Nat. oek. u. Stat. III. Folge, VIII.

Niceforo, A. Criminalità e condizioni economiche in Sicilia. Rivista di
scient. di diritto 1897.

—— Les transformations du crime et la civilisation moderne. Scuola
positiva, XI.

—— Anthropologie der nichtbesitzenden Klassen. Transl. Michels. Leipzig
und Amsterdam, 1910.

Nieboer, H. J. Slavery as an Industrial System. The Hague, 1910.

Nieuwenhuis, F. Domela. Zur Frage der Prostitution. Neue Zeit, 1884.

Noorduyn, J. P. F. A. De observatie, na de invoering der Kinderwetten,
in het Rijksopvoedingsgesticht te Alkmaar. Tijdschrift v. Strafrecht,
XXIII.

Nordau, M. Die conventionnellen Lügen der Kulturmenschheit.

Not des vierten Standes, Die. (Anonymous.) Leipzig, 1894.

Notizie complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali degli anni
1890–1895, 1896–1900. Roma, 1899, 1909.



Odin, A. Genèse des grands hommes. Paris, 1895.

Oettingen, A. v. Moralstatistik. Erlangen, 1882.

Onderzoek naar den fabrieksarbeid van gehuwde vrouwen in Nederland. ’s
Gravenhage, 1911.

Onderzoekingen naar de toestanden in de Nederlandsche huisindustrie. ’s
Gravenhage, 1911–1912.

Onmatig lange arbeidstijd en misbruik van sterken drank. (Anonymous.)
Utrecht, 1895.

Oppenheimer, F. Der Staat. Frankfurt a. M., 1907.

Orchanski. Les criminels russes. Actes II congr. d’anthr. crim. Paris.

O. S. Die Verbrecherwelt von Berlin. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., IV, V.

Ostwald, H. Das Leben der Wanderarmen. Archiv etc., XIII.

—— Das Zuhältertum in Berlin. (Grossstadt-Dokumente.) Berlin-Leipzig.

Owen, R. The Book of the New Moral World. London, 1849.

—— A New View on Society; or Essays on the Principle of the Formation
of the Human Character. Life of Robert Owen. Appendix B. London, 1857.

—— Reports of the Proceedings at the several Public Meetings held in
Dublin.



Pagnier, A. Le vagabond. Paris, 1910.

Pappritz, A. Die wirtschaftlichen Ursachen der Prostitution. Berlin,
1903.

—— Die Welt, von der man nicht spricht. Leipzig, 1907.

Parent-Duchatelet. De la prostitution dans la ville de Paris. Paris,
1857.

Pashitnow, K. A. Die Lage der arbeitenden Klasse in Russland.
Stuttgart, 1907.

Patijn, J. G. Misdaad en atavisme. Tijdschr. v. Strafr., 1891.

Pecqueur, C. Des améliorations matérielles. Paris, 1841.

Pelman, C. Psychische Grenzzustände. Bonn, 1912.

Pestalozzi, H. Ueber Gesetzgebung und Kindermord. (Sämmtliche Schriften
VII, VIII.) Stuttgart und Tübingen, 1821.

Peter, H. Zur Lage der Kellnerinnen im Grossherzogtum Baden. Archiv f.
Socialw. u. Socialpol., XXIV.

Peterselie, E. Untersuchungen über die Kriminalität in den Provinz
Sachsen. Beilageheft zur Band LXIV Gerichtssaal. Stuttgart, 1904.

Pfeiffer. Das Wohnungselend der grossen Städte und seine Beziehungen
zur Prostitution und den Geschlechtskrankheiten. Verhandlungen d. 1en
Kongr. d. deutschen Gesellsch. z. Bekämpfung d. Geschlechtskrankheiten.
Leipzig, 1903.

Philippovich, E. v. Wiener Wohnungsverhältnisse. Archiv f. soz.
Gesetzgeb. u. Stat., VII.

Pike, L. O. History of Crime in England. London, 1873/1876.

Pinsero, N. Miseria e delitto. Scuola Positiva, 1898.

Pistolese, A. Alcoolismo e delinquenza. Torino, 1907.

Placido, C., et L. Ferrero di Cavallerleone. Essais de criminologie
militaire. Compte rendu VI congr. d’anthr. crim. Turin, 1908.

Plasz, L. Fürsorgeerziehung. Woche No. 51, V.

Platon. La république ou l’état. Paris, 1873.

Plechanow, G. Anarchismus und Sozialismus. Berlin, 1894.

—— Beiträge zur Geschichte des Materialismus. Stuttgart, 1896.

Plötz, A. Die Tüchtigkeit unsrer Rasse und der Schutz der Schwachen.
Berlin, 1895.

Pollitz, P. Psychologie der Verbrechers. Leipzig, 1909.

Porter, G. R. The Influence of Education shown by Facts Recorded in the
Criminal Tables for 1845 and 1846. Journal of the Stat. Soc. of London,
1847.

Post, A. H. Die Geschlechtsgenossenschaft der Urzeit und die Entstehung
der Ehe. Oldenburg, 1875.

—— Der Ursprung des Rechts. Oldenburg, 1876.

—— Bausteine für eine allgemeine Rechtswissenschaft. Oldenburg, 1880.

—— Grundriss der ethnologischen Jurisprudenz. Oldenburg und Leipzig,
1895.

—— Die Grundlagen des Rechts.

Prins, A. Criminalité et répression. Bruxelles, 1886.

Prinzing, Fr. Soziale Faktoren der Kriminalität. Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
etc., XXII.

—— Der Einfluss der Ehe auf die Kriminalität des Mannes. Zeitschr. f.
Socialwissensch., II.

—— Die Erhöhung der Kriminalität des Weibes durch die Ehe. Zeitschr. f.
Socialw., II.

—— Die soziale Lage der Witwe in Deutschland. Zeitschr. f. Socialw.,
III.

—— Ueber frühzeitige Heiraten, deren Vorzüge und Nachteile. Jahrb. f.
Nat. oek. u. Stat. III. Folge, XV.

Proal, L. Le crime et la peine. Paris, 1892.

Process gegen den Anarchisten Hermann Stellmacher. (Anonymous.) Berlin,
Wien, Leipzig.

Prostitution in Berlin und ihre Opfer. (Anonymous.) 1846.

Proudhon, J. P. De la justice dans la révolution et dans l’église.
Paris, 1858.

Puilaraud, L. Les malfaiteurs de profession. Paris.



Quack, H. P. G. De socialisten. II and suppl. volume. Amsterdam, 1899,
1904.

Quanter, R. Die Sittlichkeitsverbrechen. Berlin, 1911.

Quetelet, A. Physique sociale. St.-Pétersbourg, 1869.

Quiros, C. B. de, und J. M. L. Aguinaliedo. Verbrechertum und
Prostitution in Madrid. Berlin, 1909.



Rae, J. Der Achtstunden-Tag. Weimar, 1897.

Rapport der commissie belast met het onderzoek naar den toestand der
kinderen in fabrieken arbeidende. ’s Gravenhage, 1872.

Rapport sur l’administration de la justice criminelle de 1881 à 1900.
(Compte général de l’administration de la justice criminelle pendant
l’année 1900.)

Raux, M. Nos jeunes détenus. Lyon-Paris, 1890.

—— Les actes, l’attitude et la correspondance de Caserio en prison.
Archives etc., XVIII.

—— Étude psychologique sur Ravachol. Archives etc., XVIII.

Régis, E. Les régicides. Lyon-Paris, 1890.

—— Le régicide Caserio. Archives etc., X.

—— et P. Ladame. Le régicide Lucheni. Archives etc., XXII.

Rehbein, Fr. Das Leben eines Landarbeiters. Jena, 1911.

Reich, E. Criminalität und Altruismus. Arnsberg, 1900.

Rein, W. Jugendliches Verbrecherthum. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., III.

Report of the Departmental Committee on the Employment of Children. Act
1903. London, 1909.

Report on the Judicial Statistics of Scotland for the year 1908, 1910.
Edinburgh, 1909, London, 1911.

Reports from the Select Committee of the House of Lords on the law for
the Protection of Young Girls. Sessions, 1881 and 1882.

Rettich. Die Würtembergische Kriminalität. Würtembergische Jahrbücher
f. Stat. u. Landeskunde, 1894.

Reuss, H. Noth und Verbrechen. Preussische Jahrbücher, 1901.

Richard, G. Les crises sociales et la criminalité. Année sociologique,
III.

Richelot, G. La prostitution en Angleterre. (Tome II, “De la
prostitution dans la ville de Paris” de A. J. B. Parent-Duchatelet.)
Paris, 1857.

Riebeth. Ueber den geistigen und körperlichen Zustand der Korrigendin.
Monatschrift etc., V.

Rivière, L. Mendiants et vagabonds. Paris, 1902.

Roest v. Limburg, Th. M. In den strijd tegen de ontucht. Rotterdam,
1910.

Rohden, G. v. Von den sozialen Motiven des Verbrechens. Zeitschr. f.
Soc. w., VII.

—— Der Kampf gegen die Verbrechensursachen. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., IX.

Röhrmann, C. Der Sittliche Zustand von Berlin. Leipzig.

Roland-Holst, v. d. Schalk, H. Kapitaal en arbeid in Nederland.
Amsterdam, 1902.

—— Arbeiders en alkohol. Nieuwe Tijd., VII.

Rollet, H., et G. Tomel. Les enfants en prison. Paris, 1892.

Roos, J. R. B. de. De strafmiddelen in de nieuwere
strafrechtswetenschap. Amsterdam, 1900.

—— Inleiding tot de beoefening der crimineele aetiologie. Haarlem,
1908.

—— Quelques recherches sur les causes de l’augmentation des vols
pendant l’hiver et des coups et blessures pendant l’été. Compte rendu
VI congr. d’anthr. crim. Turin, 1908.

—— De sexueele criminaliteit. ’s Gravenhage, 1909.

—— Parallelismen tusschen alkoholisme en criminaliteit. Tijdschr. v.
Strafrecht, XXIII.

Rosenfeld, E. Die dritte Schule. Mitteilungen der intern. krim.
Vereinigung, IV.

Rossi, V. Influence de la température et de l’alimentation sur la
criminalité en Italie, 1875–1883. Actes I congr. d’anthr. crim. Turin,
1886–1887.

Rossi, V. Il fattore economico nei moti rivoluzionari. Archivio di
psichiatria, scienze penali ed antropologia criminale, IX.

Rotering. Das Landstreichertum der Gegenwart. Monatschr. etc., III.

Rousseau, J. J. Discours sur l’origine et les fondements de l’inégalité
parmi les hommes. Amsterdam, 1762.

Rowntree, B. B. Poverty. London, 1903.

Royen, J. A. van. Wetgeving en armoede beschouwd in betrekking tot het
misdrijf. Zwolle, 1846.

Rühle, O. Das proletarische Kind. München, 1911.

Russell, W. Abstract of the Statistics of Crime in England and Wales
from 1839 to 1843. Journ. of the Stat. Soc. of London, 1847.

Ryckère, R. de. La servante criminelle. Paris, 1908.

Rylands, L. Gordon. Crime, Its Causes and Remedy. London, 1889.



Sacker, J. Der Rückfall. Berlin, 1892.

Sauer, A. Frauenkriminalität im Amtsbezirk Mannheim. Breslau, 1912.

Scandales de Londres, publiés par la Pall Mall Gazette. Paris, 1885.

Schäffle, A. C. Fr. Bau und Lebendes socialen Körpers I, IV. Tübingen,
1875, 1878.

Schaffroth, G. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la
criminalité. Actes congr. pénit. intern. de Bruxelles, 1900, IV.
Bruxelles et Berne, 1901.

Schallmayer, W. Soziale Massnahmen zur Besserung des
Fortpflanzungsauslese. (Krankheit und soziale Lage. München, 1910.)

Scheel, H. v. Kriminalstatistik. (Handwörterbuch der
Staatswissenschaften, VI. Jena, 1910.)

Schippel, M. Das moderne Elend und die moderne Ueberbevölkerung.
Stuttgart, 1888.

Schlesinger-Eckstein, Th. Die Frau im XIX Jahrhundert. Berlin.

Schnapper-Arndt, G. Sozialstatistik. Leipzig, 1908.

Schneider, C. K. Die Prostituirte und die Gesellschaft. Leipzig, 1908.

Schönfeldt, G. Beiträge zur Geschichte des Pauperismus und der
Prostitution in Hamburg. Zeitschr. f. Social- und
Wistschaftsgeschichte, 1897.

—— Die heutige Arbeiterfamilie und die öffentliche Erziehung
vorschulpflichtiger Kinder. Neue Zeit, 1898–99, I.

Schönlank, B. Zur Lage der in der Wäschefabrikation und der
Konfektionsbranche Deutschlands beschäftigten Arbeiterinnen. Neue Zeit,
1885.

—— Die Syphilis und die Socialzustände. Neue Zeit, 1887.

—— Zur Psychologie des Kleinbürgerthums. Neue Zeit, 1890.

—— Zur Statistik der Prostitution in Berlin. Archiv f. soz. Gesetzgeb.
u. Stat., VII.

Schröder, P. Das Fortlaufen der Kinder. Monatschrift etc., VIII.

Schurtz, H. Altersklassen und Männerbünde. Berlin, 1902.

Seuf, M. R. Geschlechtstrieb und Verbrechen. Archiv etc., XLVIII.

Seuffert, H. Anarchismus und Strafrecht. Berlin, 1899.

S. G. Die weibliche Lohnarbeit und ihr Einfluss auf die Sittlichkeit
und Kriminalität. Neue Zeit, 1899–1900, II.

Sichart, G. Ueber individuelle Faktoren der Verbrechens. Zeitschr. f.
d. ges. Str. w., X.

Sighele, S. La foule criminelle. Paris, 1892.

—— Le crime à deux. Lyon-Paris, 1893.

—— Psychologie des sectes. Paris, 1898.

—— Littérature et criminalité. Paris, 1908.

Smidt, H. J. Geschiedenis van het wetboek van strafrecht II. Haarlem,
1881.

S(midt), J. Zur Verwahrlosung der Kinder in der Kapitalistischen
Gesellschaft. Neue Zeit, 1893–94, II.

—— Aus den Ergebnissen der sächsischen Armenstatistik. Neue Zeit,
1894–95, II.

—— Einfluss der Krisen und der Steigerung der Lebensmittelpreise auf
das Gesellschaftsleben. München, 1894.

Social Evil in Chicago. (Report of the vice commission.) Chicago, 1912.

Socquet, J. Contribution à l’étude statistique de la criminalité en
France de 1826 à 1880. Paris, 1884.

Spann, O. Untersuchungen über die uneheliche Bevölkerung in Frankfurt
a/M. Dresden, 1912.

—— Die unehelichen Mündel des Vormundschaftsgerichtes in Frankfurt a/M.
Dresden, 1909.

—— Die geschlechtlich-sittlichen Verhältnisse im Dienstboten- und
Arbeiterinnenstande. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., VII.

Spencer, H. Principles of Sociology. London-Edinburgh, 1877.

—— Descriptive Sociology. No. 6. American Races. London-Edinburgh,
1878.

—— Psychology. London-Edinburgh, 1881.

Starcke, C. N. Die primitive Familie. Leipzig, 1888.

Starke, W. Verbrechen und Verbrecher in Preussen 1854–1878. Berlin,
1884.

—— Des éléments essentiels qui doivent figurer dans la statistique
criminelle et des moyens de les rendre comparables. Bulletin de
l’instit. intern. de statistique, 1889.

Statesman’s Year Book for the years 1902, 1910. London, 1902, 1910.

Statistica giudiziaria penale per l’anno 1881, 1889, 1894. Roma, 1884,
1891, 1896.

Statistik der Reichstagswahlen von 1898. Ergänzungsheft zu den
Vierteljahrsheften z. Stat. d. Deutschen Reichs, 1898, II.

Statistique pénitentiaire (de la France), 1882–1898. Melun, 1882–1901.

Statistische Uebersicht der Verhältnisse der Oesterreichischen
Strafanstalten und der Gerichtsgefängnisse 1883, 1884. Wien, 1886,
1888.

Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich, V, X, XV, XVII, XVIII,
XIX, XXII, XXIV. Berlin, 1884 sqq.

Steinmetz, S. R. De “Fosterage.” Tijdschrift v. L. Kon. Ned.
aardrijkskundig Genootschap, 1893.

—— Ethnologische Studien zur ersten Entwicklung der Strafe I, II.
Leiden-Leipzig, 1894.

—— Das Verhältniss zwischen Eltern und Kindern bei den Naturvölkern.
Zeitschr. f. Socialw., I.

Steinmetz, S. R. Der Krieg als sociologisches Problem. Amsterdam, 1899.

—— Die neueren Forschungen zur Geschichte der menschlichen Familie.
Zeitschr. f. Socialw., II.

—— De ziekten der maatschappij. Vragen des Tijds., 1900.

—— Classification des types sociaux et catalogue des peuples. Année
sociologique, III.

—— L’ethnologie et l’anthropologie criminelle. Compte rendu V congr.
d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam, 1901.

—— Die Philosophie des Krieges. Leipzig, 1907.

Stelzner, H. F. Die psychopathischen Konstitutionen und ihre
sociologische Bedeutung. Berlin, 1911.

Stern, J. Einfluss der sozialen Zustände auf alle Zweige des
Kulturlebens. Stuttgart, 1891.

—— Thesen über den Sozialismus. Stuttgart, 1911.

Stevens, J. Les prisons cellulaires en Belgique. Bruxelles, 1878.

Stier, E. Wandertrieb und pathologisches Fortlaufen bei Kindern. Jena,
1913.

Stinea. Le milieu social comme facteur pathologique. L’ère nouvelle,
1894.

Stirner, M. (Kaspar Schmidt.) Der Einzige und sein Eigenthum. Leipzig.

Stöwesand, W. Die Kriminalität in der Provinz Posen und ihre Ursachen.
Beilageheft zu Band LXXVII Gerichtssaal. Stuttgart, 1910.

Struntz, K. Die erwerbsmässige Kinderarbeit und die Schule. Neue Zeit,
1898–1899, I.

Stursberg, H. Die Zunahme der Vergehen und Verbrechen und ihre
Ursachen. Düsseldorf, 1878.

—— Die Prostitution in Deutschland und ihre Bekämpfung. Düsseldorf,
1887.

Sullivan, W. C. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la
criminalité. Actes du congr. pénitent. intern. de Bruxelles, 1900, IV.
Bruxelles et Berne, 1901.

Sutherland, A. The Origin and Growth of Moral Instinct. London, 1898.

—— Résultats de la déportation en Australie. Compte rendu V congr.
d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam, 1901.



Tarde, G. La criminalité comparée. Paris, 1890.

—— La philosophie pénale. Paris, 1890. Amer. ed. transl. Howell,
Boston, 1913 (Modern Criminal Science Series).

—— Misère et criminalité. Revue philosophique, 1890, I.

—— Les crimes de haine. Essais et mélanges sociologiques. Lyon-Paris,
1895.

—— Les délits impoursuivis. Essais etc. Lyon-Paris, 1895.

—— Les transformations de l’impunité. (Lacassagne, Vacher l’éventreur
et les crimes sadiques.) Lyon–Paris, 1899.

—— La criminalité et les phénomènes économiques. Compte rendu V congr.
d’anthr. crim. Amsterdam, 1901.

Tardieu, A. Étude médico-légale sur les attentats aux mœurs. Paris,
1878.

Tarnowsky. Prostitution und Abolitionismus. Hamburg und Leipzig, 1890.

—— E. La delinquenza e la vita sociale in Russia. Rivista italiana di
sociologia, 1898.

—— Le mouvement de la criminalité en Russie. Archives d’anthr. etc.,
XIII.

—— Répartition géographique de la criminalité en Russie. Archives etc.,
XVI.

—— Les crimes politiques en Russie. Archives etc., XXII.

Taxil, L. La corruption fin-de-siècle. Paris.

Teifen, T. W. Das sociale Elend und die besitzenden Klassen in
Oesterreich. Wien, 1894.

Tex, C. J. A. den. De causis criminum. Amsterdam, 1847.

—— G. M. den. Verkorting van den arbeidsdag. Amsterdam, 1894.

Thompson, W. An Inquiry into the Principles of the Distribution of
Wealth. London, 1850.

Thomsen, A. Betrachtungen über ein Sammeln der verbrecherischen Motive.
Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., XVII.

Thót, L. v. Die positive Strafrechtsschule in einigen europäischen
Ländern. Monatschr. etc., VIII.

Tomel, G., et H. Rollet. Les enfants en prison. Paris, 1892.

Tónnies, F. Jugendliche Kriminalität und Verwahrlosung in
Grossbritannien. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc., XIII.

—— Das Verbrechen als soziale Erscheinung. Archiv f. soz. Gesetzgeb. u.
Stat., VIII.

Topinard, P. L’anthropologie criminelle. Revue d’anthropologie, 1887,
II.

Toulouse, E. Les causes de la folie.

Tugan-Baranowsky, M. Die sozialen Wirkungen der Handelskrisen in
England. Archiv f. soz. Gesetzgeb. etc., XV.

—— Studien zur Theorie und Geschichte der Handelskrisen in England.
Jena, 1901.

Tugendreich, G., und M. Mosse. Krankheit und soziale Lage. München,
1912–1913.

Turati, F. Il delitto e la questione sociale. Milano, 1883.

Túrkel, S. Einfluss der Lektüre auf die Delikte phantastischer
jugendlicher Psychopathen. Archiv f. Krim. anthr. etc., XLII.



Uitkomsten der 7e en 8e tienjaarlijksche volkstelling. ’s Gravenhage,
1891 en 1901.

—— der beroepstelling in het koninkrijk der Nederlanden gehouden op 31
December 1899. ’s Gravenhage, 1901.

—— der Woningstatistiek voor het koninkrijk der Nederlanden.
Volkstelling 30 December 1899. ’s Gravenhage, 1903.



Vaccaro, M. A. Genesi e funzione delle leggi penali. Roma, 1889.

Valentini, H. v. Das Verbrecherthum im preussischen Staat. Leipzig,
1869.

Vallon, Ch., et G. Genil-Perrin. Crime et altruisme. Archives etc.,
XXVIII.

Vandervelde, E. Het alcoholisme en de arbeidsvoorwaarden in België.
Nieuwe Tijd., IV.

—— Die oekonomischen Faktoren des Alkoholismus. Neue Zeit, 1901–1902,
I.

—— Le socialisme et l’alcool. (Essais socialistes.) Paris, 1906.

Vaucleray. Influence de l’hérédité alcoolique sur la folie et la
criminalité. Actes III congr. d’anthr. crim. Bruxelles, 1893.

Varennes, H. De Ravachol à Caserio. Paris.

Verhaeghe, D. Le parti socialiste et la lutte contre l’alcool.
Mouvement socialiste. 1900.

—— De l’alcoolisation. Paris, 1900.

Verrijn Stuart, C. A. Inleiding tot de beoefening der Statistiek II.
Haarlem, 1913.

Verslagen over de verrichtingen aangaan de het armbestuur over 1898 en
1899. Bijlage E. Handelingen 2e Kamer des Staten-Generaal 1899–1900,
1900–1901.

Vierkandt, A. Das Problem der Familien- und Stammesorganisation der
Naturvölker. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., XI.

Vries, H. de. Eenheid in veranderlijkheid. Haarlem, 1898.



Wachholz, L. Zur Lehre von den sexuellen Delikten. Vierteljahrschrift
f. Gerichtl. Medizin etc., XXXVIII.

Wadler, A. Die Verbrechensbewegung im östlichen Europa I. Die
Kriminalität der Balkanländer. München, 1908.

—— Die politische Verbrecher in Russland. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc.,
XXIX.

—— Erkenntnistheorie und Kriminalstatistik. Zeitschr. f. d. ges. etc.,
XXXI.

Wagener, H. Der Mädchenhandel. Berlin-Lihterfelde, 1911.

Wagner, C. Die Sittlichkeit aus den Lande. Leipzig, 1896.

—— und H. Wittenberg. Die geschlechtlich-sittlichen Verhältnisse der
evangelischen Landbewohner im Deutschen Reiche. Leipzig, 1897.

Waitz, Th. Anthropologie der Naturvölker III. Leipzig, 1862.

Wallace, A. R. The Malayo Archipelago. London, 1869.

—— Menschliche Auslese. Zukunft, 1894.

Walsh, R. H. A Deduction from the Statistics of Crime for the Last Ten
Years. Journ. Stat. Soc. of London, 1857.

Wappäus, J. E. Allgemeine Bevölkerungsstatistik II. Leipzig, 1861.

Wassermann, R. Beruf, Konfession und Verbrechen. München, 1907.

—— Begriff und Grenzen der Kriminalstatistik. Leipzig, 1909.

—— G. v. Mayr als Kriminalstatistiker und Kriminalsoziologe und die
moderne Methodenlehre. Monatschrift etc., VII.

Weber, M. Ehefrau und Mutter in der Rechtsentwicklung. Tübingen, 1907.

Weidemann, W. Die Ursachen der Kriminalität im Herzogtum
Sachsen-Meiningen. Berlin, 1903.

Weinberg, S. Der werdende Verbrecher. Neue Zeit, 1902–1903, II.

Weiss, B. Ueber einige wirtschaftliche und moralische Wirkungen hoher
Getreidepreise. Jahrb. f. Nat. oek. u. Stat., 1881.

Weitling, W. Garantien der Harmonie und Freiheit. 1842.

—— Die Menschheit wie sie ist und wie sie sein sollte. München, 1895.

—— Das Evangelium eines armen Sünders. München, 1896.

Wellenbergh, P. Contribution à l’étude de la question de l’influence de
la vieillesse sur la criminalité. Compte rendu V congr. d’anthr. crim.
Amsterdam, 1901.

Werthauer, J. Sittlichkeits-Delikte der Gross-Stadt. Berlin.

Westermarck, E. The History of Human Marriage. London, 1891.

—— Der Ursprung der Strafe. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., III.

—— Ursprung und Entwicklung der Moral begriffe. Transl. Katscher.
Leipzig, 1907/1909.

Westgarth, W. Statistics of Crime in Australia. Journ. Stat. Soc. of
London, 1864.

Wetzker, H. Die Zunahme der Verbrechen. Sozialist. Monatsch., 1902, II.

Wieselgren, S. Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la
criminalité. Actes du congr. pénitent. intern. de Bruxelles, 1900, IV.
Bruxelles et Berne, 1901.

Willis, W. N. The White Slaves of London. London, 1912.

—— and A. Mackirdy. The White Slave Market. London.

Wilmanns, K. Zur Psychopathologie des Landstreichers. Leipzig, 1906.

—— Das Landstreichertum. Monatschr. etc. I.

Winkler, C. Iets over crimineele anthropologie. Geneeskundige Bladen,
1895.

Winter, A. The New York State Reformatory in Elmira. London, 1871.

Wittenberg, H., und C. Wagner. Die geschlechtlich-sittlichen
Verhältnisse der evangelischen Landbewohner im Deutschen Reiche.
Leipzig, 1897.

Wolf, J. Das Verhältnis von Eltern und Kindern bei dem Landvolk in
Deutschland. Zeitschr. f. Soc. w., I.

Woltmann, L. Die Darwinsche Theorie und der Socialismus. Düsseldorf,
1899.

Wright, Carrol D. The Relation of Economic Conditions to the Causes of
Crime. Philadelphia, 1900.

Wulffen, E. Psychologie des Verbrechers. Grosslichterfelde-Ost, 1908.

—— Gauner- und Verbrechertypen. Berlin-Grosslichterfelde, 1910.

—— Der Sexualverbrecher. Berlin-Grosslichterfelde, 1910.

Wurm, E. Die Alkoholfrage. Protokoll über die Verhandlungen des
Parteitags der Soz. dem. Partei Deutschlands zu Essen. Berlin, 1907.

Würzburger, E. Ueber die Vergleichbarkeit kriminalstatistischer Daten.
Jahrb. f. Nat. oek. u. Stat., 1887.



Yearbook of New York State Reformatory, 1881–1886, 1888–1897.
Albany-Elmira.

Yvernès, M. L’alcoolisme et la criminalité. Archives etc., XXVII.



Zadek, I. Der Achtstundentag eine gesundheitliche Forderung. Berlin,
1904.

Zerboglio, A. Les inconvénients de l’honnêteté. L’ère nouvelle, 1894.

—— L’alcoolisme: causes et remèdes. Devenir social, I.

—— La fin de la névrose. Devenir social, I.

—— La lutte de classe dans la législation pénale. Devenir social, II.

—— Les bases économiques de la santé. Devenir social, III.

Zetkin, C. Geistiges Proletariat, Frauenfrage und Sozialismus. Berlin,
1902.

—— Die Arbeiterinnen- und Frauenfrage der Gegenwart. Berlin.

Zetkin, O. Die barfüssige Bande. Neue Zeit, 1885.

Ziehen, Th. Die Erkennung der psychopathischen Konstitutionen und die
öffentliche Fürsorge für psychopathisch veranlagte Kinder. Berlin,
1912.

Žižek, F. Soziologie und Statistik. München und Leipzig, 1912.

Zoccoli, H. Die Anarchie. Transl. Nacht. Leipzig–Amsterdam, 1909.

Zola, E. Au bonheur des dames. Paris.

—— L’argent. Paris.








NOTES


[1] Chief Justice of the Supreme Court of Nevada; Vice-President of the
American Institute of Criminal Law and Criminology.

[2] [Note to the American Edition: In my opinion, More is the first
author who has noted in a scientific way the relation between
criminality and economic conditions. Before him there were other
authors, to whom this relationship did not remain totally unperceived;
but they treated the subject by chance, as it were, and in a very
superficial way. Cf. J. van Kan, “Les Causes économiques de la
Criminalité”, pp. 15 ff.]

[3] Pp. 28–36.

[4] “Le testament de J. Meslier.”

[5] Pp. 210–212.

[6] Pp. 214, 215.

[7] P. 67.

[8] Pp. 79, 80.

[9] Pp. 144, 145. See also pp. 38 ff., and pp. 150 ff.

[10] P. 9.

[11] P. 10.

[12] P. 167.

[13] Pp. 284–288.

[14] Pp. 186–189. See also pp. 199, 200, and 207–209.

[15] Pp. 33, 34.

[16] Pp. 36, 37.

[17] Pp. 47, 48. See also pp. 72 ff.

[18] Pp. 37–39.

[19] Pp. 43–45.

[20] Pp. 74, 75.

[21] Pp. 331–333.

[22] Pp. 333, 334.

[23] Pp. 15, 16.

[24] Pp. 455–458.

[25] See also the work entitled: “An Inquiry into the Principles of the
Distribution of Wealth” (Chapters II and III), by W. Thompson, a
disciple of Owen. On page 17 he says: “The unrestrained tendency of the
distribution of wealth, being so much toward equality, excessive wealth
and excessive poverty being removed, almost all the temptations, all
the motives, which now urge to the commission of crime, would be also
removed.” In general, the English socialists from the commencement of
the nineteenth century (e.g. Charles Hall, Thomas Hodgskin, Charles
Bray, and others) have had a notion, more or less clear, of the
relation between the nascent industrial capitalism and criminality.
Upon these authors cf. Quack, “De Socialisten” (Tome Supplémentaire),
and Beer, “Geschichte des Sozialismus in England”, I.

[26] See his “Essays on the Formation of Character”; and “Reports of
the Proceedings at the Several Public Meetings held in Dublin.”

[27] One of the laws which, according to Owen, should produce the
change from modern society to the society of the future.

[28] Pp. 40–45. It is well known that Owen put his theories into
practice when he founded the village of New Lanark. The disastrous
consequences of industrial capitalism, such as excessive hours of
labor, insufficient nourishment, unsanitary housing, the lack of
education for children, etc., were diminished there or altogether
avoided. Among the population of the colony, though originally
alcoholized and demoralized by capitalism, little by little the
favorable environment made itself felt, so that for nineteen years
there was no judicial prosecution, and drunkenness and illegitimate
births disappeared. (See Denis, “Le socialisme et les causes
économiques et sociales du crime”, p. 283, and Quack, “De Socialisten”,
II, pp. 279 ff.)

[29] Pp. 315–317.

[30] Pp. 128–131. See also: F. Engels, “Umrisse zu einer Kritik der
Nationalökonomie”, pp. 449 and 459; F. Engels and K. Marx, “Die heilige
Familie oder Kritik der kritischen Kritik”, pp. 239–241. See also, the
following: Plato, “The Republic”, I. 5.; C. A. Helvetius, “De l’homme”,
X. p. 49; J. P. Marat, “Plan de la législation criminelle”, pp. 18 ff.;
J. Bentham, “Traités de la législation civile et pénale”, III ch. V,
pp. 45 ff.; Ch. Fourier, “Théorie des quatre Mouvements”, III; “Théorie
de l’unité universelle” (“Traité de l’association
domestique-agricole”), Introduction. 2. p. 51; “Le nouveau monde
industriel et sociétaire”, Sect. VI; B. P. Enfantin, “Les
enseignements”, pp. 92, 93; W. Weitling, “Die Menschheit wie sie ist,
und wie sie sein sollte”, p. 47; “Garantien der Harmonie und Freiheit”,
pp. 53, 54, and 104, 105; “Das Evangelium eines armen Sünders”, p. 102;
V. Considérant, “Théorie du droit de propriété et du droit au travail”,
p. 33; L. Blanc, “Organisation du travail”, pp. 57 ff.; C. Pequeur,
“Des améliorations matérielles”, pp. 86–88, 232–234, 239–241; J. A. van
Royen, “Wetgeving en armoede beschouwd in betrekking tot het misdrijf”,
pp. 9 ff.; C. J. A. den Tex, “De causis criminum”, pp. 84 ff.; Chaillou
des Barres, “L’influence du bien-être matériel sur la moralité d’un
peuple” (“Journal des Economistes”, 1846); E. Mercier, “Influence du
bien-être matériel sur la criminalité”; P. J. Proudhon, “De la justice
dans la révolution et dans l’église”, pp. 533–534.

[Note to the American Edition: For the opinions of the scientific world
of Holland at the end of the eighteenth century and the beginning of
the nineteenth: J. A. v. Hamel, “Strafrechtspolitiek van voor honderd
jaar” (Gids, 1909, II).

See for the same period in England: L. von Thót, “Die positive
Strafrechtsschule in einigen europäischen Ländern”, pp. 407 ff.
(“Monatschr. f. Kriminal-Psychologie u. Strafrechts-reform”, VIII).]

[31] Pp. 42, 43.

[32] P. 94, I.

[33] Pp. 95–97, I.

[34] Pp. 278, 279.

[35] P. 281.

[36] Pp. 39–46.

[37] P. 47.

[38] “Du Problème de la Misère et de sa solution chez les peuples
anciens et modernes”, III (“Peuples modernes”). See also by the same:
“Le monde des coquins.”

[39] Pp. 222–224.

[40] P. 2.

[41] [The charts being unnecessarily detailed for the purposes of this
work, and the results being sufficiently summed up in the paragraphs
which follow, they are omitted in this translation, though given by Dr.
Bonger.—Transl.]

[42] Pp. 136, 137.

[43] Pp. 160, 161.

[44] [To avoid awkwardness of expression the term assault will be used
for assaults other than those peculiarly against women, the original
being about equivalent to our “assault and battery.”—Transl.]

[45] “Essai sur la criminalité” (“Journal des Economistes”, 1868).

[46] P. 64.

[47] P. 82.

[48] See Part II of this work, where I have shown that in my opinion
the influence of property upon morality is much more complex than Corne
has suggested, and quite different.

[49] Pp. 89, 90.

[50] See Guerry, “Essai sur la statistique morale de la France,” p. 51,
and L. del Baere, “De invloed van opvoeding en onderwijs.”

[51] P. 93.

[52] P. 10.

[53] P. 24.

[54] P. 58.

[55] [“Arpents de Magdebourg.”—Transl.]

[56] P. 57.

[57] “Die Moralstatistik in ihrer Bedeutung für eine Socialethik.”

[58] P. 239.

[59] On p. 442 of his “Moralstatistik,” von Oettingen criticises
Stursberg for basing his comparison upon the year 1871 in which the
figures were very low as a consequence of the war, and for not having
taken into account that in the year 1876 the new penal code was put
into effect.

[60] P. 58.

[61] “Ueber einige wirthschaftliche und moralische Wirkungen hoher
Getreidepreise.”

[62] “Verbrechen und Verbrecher in Preussen 1854–1878.” This book
(especially the statistical material) has been severely criticized by
Mittelstadt (“Zeitschrift für die ges. Strafrechtswissenschaft”, 1884),
Aschrott (“Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, etc.” von Schmoller, 1884), and
Illing (“Zeitschrift des Königlich Preussischen statistischen Bureaus”,
1885). Körner has refuted their views (“Jahrbücher für d. Nat. Oek. u.
Stat. Neue Folge”, Vol. XIII).

[63] It is not possible for me to treat this question at length here.
The reader is referred to my studies: “Misdaad en socialisme. Tegelijk
eene bijdrage tot de studie der criminaliteit in Nederland” (“Nieuwe
Tijd”, XVI), and “Verbrechen und Sozialismus. Zugleich ein Beitrag zum
Studium der Kriminalität in Deutschland” (“Neue Zeit”, XXX, 2), where I
have proved in a decisive manner, as it seems to me, that the
socialistic movement is not productive of crime, but the contrary.

[64] P. 88.

[65] P. 94.

[66] “Die Würtembergische Kriminalität.”

[67] P. 360.

[68] See upon this book the criticism of Professor F. Tönnies in
“Archiv für soziale Gesetzgebung und Statistik”, 1896.

[69] P. 41.

[70] P. 57.

[71] P. 61.

[72] P. 66.

[73] P. 67.

[74] Cf. by the same: “Studien zur Theorie und Geschichte der
Handelskrisen in England”, II, Chap. I, where still more explicit data
are given.

[75] “La delinquenza e la vita sociale in Russia.” Another publication
by the same author is entitled: “Upon the relations between criminality
and the price of cereals” (published in Russian). Cf. also: “Le
mouvement de la criminalité en Russie, 1874–1894” (“Archives d’anthr.
crim.”, XIII.), and “Répartition géographique de la criminalité en
Russie” (“Arch. d’anthr. crim.”, XVI.).

[76] P. 4.

[77] Pp. 24, 25.

[78] See Lafargue, “Die Kriminalität in Frankreich, 1840–86.” In France
the development of manufacturing did not receive an impetus till 1874,
from which year the decrease in crime dates.

[79] P. 56.

[80] Pp. 60, 61.

[81] Pp. 65, 66.

[82] Cf. H. Berg, “Getreidepreise und Kriminalität in Deutschland seit
1882”, and my study already cited, “Verbrechen und Socialismus”, pp.
805, 806.

See also: Whitworth Russell, “Abstract of the Statistics of Crime in
England and Wales, from 1839 to 1843”; J. Fletcher, “Moral and
Educational Statistics of England and Wales”; G. R. Porter, “The
Influence of Education Shown by Facts Recorded in the Criminal Tables
for 1845 and 1846”; L. Faucher, “Mémoire sur le caractère et sur le
mouvement de la criminalité en Angleterre”; J. Clay, “On the Effect of
Good or Bad Times on Committals to Prison”; R. Everest, “On the
Influence of Social Degradation in Producing Pauperism and Crime, as
Exemplified in the Free Coloured Citizens and Foreigners in the United
States”; “Criminality Promoted by Distress” (“The Economist”, 1856); R.
H. Walsh, “A Deduction from the Statistics of Crime for the Last Ten
Years”; W. Westgarth, “Statistics of Crime in Australia”; Bernard, “De
la criminalité en France depuis 1826 et de la répression pénale au
point de vue de l’amendement des prisonniers”; J. H. Elliot, “The
Increase of Material Prosperity and of Moral Agents Compared with the
State of Crime and Pauperism”; E. Levasseur, “La population française”,
II pp. 442–444; Prof. Dr. B. Földes, “Einige Ergebnisse der neueren
Kriminalstatistik”, pp. 544 ff.; G. F. Kolb, “Handbuch der
vergleichenden Statistik”, pp. 516, 517; M. A. de Malarce, “Moralité
comparée des diverses parties de la France d’après la criminalité”; J.
E. Wappäus, “Allgemeine Bevölkerungsstatistik”, II, pp. 429, 430;
Mayhew and Binny, “The Criminal Prisons of London”, pp. 450, 451; E.
Bertrand, “Essai sur la moralité comparative des diverses classes de la
population et principalement des classes ouvrières”; G. Lindenberg,
“Ergebnisse der deutschen Kriminalstatistik”, 1882–1892, pp. 718 ff.

[Note to the American Edition: See the following recent statistical
studies: For Germany: H. Berg, “Getreidepreise und Kriminalität in
Deutschland seit 1882”; R. Wassermann, “Beruf, Konfession, und
Verbrechen”; G. Schnapper-Arndt, “Sozialstatistik”, pp. 624 ff.; P.
Alterthum, “Das Problem der Arbeitslosigkeit und die Kapitalistische
Wirtschaftsentwicklung”, pp. 47 ff.; W. A. Bonger, “Verbrechen und
Sozialismus.” For Austria: H. Herr, “Verbrechen und Verbrechertum in
Oesterreich.” For the Balkan States: A. Wadler, “Die
Verbrechensbewegung im östlichen Europa”, I. For Belgium: C. Jacquart,
“La criminalité Belge, 1868–1909.” For the Netherlands: J. R. B. de
Roos, “Inleiding tot de beoefening der crimineele aetiologie”; W. A.
Bonger, “Misdaad en Socialisme, etc.”; C. A. Verrijn Stuart, “Inleiding
tot de beoefening der statistiek”, II, pp. 223 ff.]

[83] See Wulffen, “Psychologie des Verbrechers”, I, p. 369.

[84] See (with regard to the social factors of crime and their
importance in comparison with individual causes) my study: “Over de
maatschappelijke factoren van de misdaad en hunne beteekenis in
vergelijking met de individueele oorzaken” (“Tijdschrift v.
Strafrecht”, XXIII, pp. 413 ff.).

[85] See further H. v. Schul, “Kriminalstatistik” (“Handwörterbuch der
Staatswissenschafte”, VI, p. 246).

[86] See v. Liszt, “Kriminalpolitische Aufgaben” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
Strafrw.”, IX).

[87] See Levasseur, “La population française”, p. 445; also v.
Oettingen, “Moralstatistik”, p. 445; Dr. E. Würzburger, “Ueber die
Vergleichbarkeit kriminalstatistischer Daten” (“Jahrb. f.
Nationalökonomie u. Statistik”, 1887); Tarde, “Penal Philosophy”, pp.
72, 73 (The Modern Criminal Science Series, Little, Brown, & Co.,
1912); Földes, “Einige Ergebnisse der neueren Kriminalstatistik”
(“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.”, XI, pp. 517–518); de Roos, op. cit.,
pp. 192 ff.

[88] The opinions of partisans of the Italian school with regard to the
correlation between criminality and economic conditions are very
different. Garofalo and Ferri especially are not in agreement upon this
point. Nevertheless, I have thought that I ought to class them
together, because of the uniformity of their point of view with regard
to criminality in general.

[89] The Modern Criminal Science Series. Translated by Horton. Boston,
Little, Brown, & Co., 1911.

[90] P. 81.

[91] See Battaglia, “La dinamica del delitto”, pp. 227, 228.

[92] Bodio includes rural thefts.

[93] P. 121.

[94] P. 122.

[95] As the author himself observes, the conclusions drawn from this
table must be taken with reserve, because of the great difference in
the penal laws of these countries.

[96] My exposition would be too long if I should examine this
explanation (which seems insufficient to me) at length. For the chief
explanation of the great number of murders in countries that are
intellectually backward, see “L’homicide en Italie”, by Colajanni
(“Revue socialiste”, 1901).

[97] P. 131.

[98] Pp. 133, 134.

[99] P. 137.

[100] American edition, “Criminology” (The Modern Criminal Science
Series; Little, Brown, & Co., 1913), from which quotations are made.
See by the same author, “La superstition socialiste”, and “Le Crime
comme phénomène social” (“Annales de l’Inst. intern. de Sociologie”,
II).

[Note to the American Edition: See also his report to the Congress of
Cologne, “L’influence des prédispositions et du milieu dans la
criminalité.”]

[101] Pp. 144, 145.

[102] P. 164.

[103] See also “Studi sulla Criminalità in Francia (1826–1876).”

[104] Although I do not wish to attack the proposition that socialism
in Italy at that period (preceding 1880) was unscientific, I cannot
conceal my astonishment that Professor Ferri should fulminate against
socialism in general “because of its lack of the scientific spirit”,
apparently quite ignorant of the scientific socialism of Marx and
Engels, which had existed since the middle of the century!

[105] “Sociologie criminelle”, p. 161.

[106] P. 43.

[107] Pp. 150, 151.

[108] “Soc. crim.”, p. 157.

[109] “Les aptitudes et les actes”, pp. 328, 329.

[110] Upon crime and sex see Pt. II, Ch. II, § I, C., d.

[111] “Genèse normale du crime”, p. 451.

[112] Among the anthropological factors Professor Ferri includes also
education, profession, civil status, etc., called all together the
bio-social conditions. I am of the opinion that these factors ought not
to be classed as anthropological, but as social.

[113] [Note to the American Edition: Among the recent works against the
Italian school must be named that of Dr. S. Ettinger, “Das
Verbrecherproblem”.]

[114] It is not correct, in my opinion, to class agricultural
production among the physical factors as Professor Ferri does. It is
rather one of the social factors.

[115] Pp. 199–201.

[116] See Niceforo; “Criminalità e condizioni economiche in Sicilia”
(“Rivista scientifica del diretto”, 1897), and Colajanni, “L’homicide
en Italie” (“Revue Socialiste”, July, 1901).

[117] “Criminalité comparée”, p. 153.

[118] It is Colajanni in particular who, in his “Sociologia criminale”,
II, has cited a great number of examples of this kind. See Chs. VII,
VIII, IX. See also his “Oscillations thermométriques et délits contre
les personnes” (“Archives d’anthr. crim.”, 1886). See also Földes,
“Einige Ergebnisse der neueren Kriminalstatistik” (“Zeitschr. f. d.
ges. Strafrw.”, XI, p. 544).

[119] “Das Verbrechen in seiner Abhängigkeit von dem jährlichen
Temperaturwechsel” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.”, II, p. 13).

[120] See Colajanni, “Soc. crim.”, II, pp. 427 ff.

[121] See: Tarde, “Penal Philosophy”, p. 303; Quetelet, “Physique
sociale”, II, p. 288; Colajanni, “Soc. Crim.”, II, pp. 431 ff.

[122] See “Introduction to the Criminal Statistics of England and
Wales, 1905”, p. 53.

[123] Besides the authors cited, see also, as regards the influence of
physical factors, Mischler, “Hauptergebnisse in moralischer Hinsicht”
(“Handbuch des Gefängniswesens”, II, p. 485); Fr. von Liszt, “Die
sozialpolitische Auffassung des Verbrechens” (“Sozialpolitisches
Centralblatt”, 1892).

[124] [Note to the American Edition: Upon the relation between
criminality and the physical environment see also the recent works:
Aschaffenburg, “Das Verbrechen und seine Bekämpfung”, pp. 13 ff.; de
Roos, “Quelques recherches sur les causes de l’augmentation des vols
pendant l’hiver et des coups et blessures pendant l’été” (“Compte rendu
du VIe Congrès internat. d’anthrop. crim.”); Wulffen, “Psychologie des
Verbrechers”, I, pp. 381 ff.; P. Gaedeken, “Contribution statistique à
la réaction de l’organisme sous l’influence physico-chimique des agents
météorologiques” (“Archives d’anthr. crim.”, XXIV); Verrijn-Stuart, op.
cit., pp. 176 ff.; v. Mayr, “Statistik u. Gesellschaftslehre”, pp. 605
ff.

[125] “Zur Kritik der politischen Oekonomie”, Preface, p. xi.

[126] “La conception matérialiste de l’histoire”, pp. 229, 230
(“Devenir Social”, 1897).

[127] See the examples given by Professor Ferri, pp. 197–201.

[128] I will not speak of Ch. VI, which is only a repetition of a theme
treated of several times, “how much more scientific the sociologists
are than the socialists.”

[129] [See the author’s explanation of his use of this word, in the
preface.—Transl.]

[130] See “Le crime comme phénomène social” (“Annales de l’institut
international de Sociologie”, 1896, p. 414), and “Kriminelle
Anthropologie und Sozialismus” (“Neue Zeit”, 1895–96, II).

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. the recent work of C. Manes (a
disciple of Ferri), “Capitalismo e criminalità.”]

[131] P. 217. The author insinuates, without bringing the slightest
proof, that persons with criminal dispositions have often contributed
to the formation of the socialistic theories.

[132] See my criticisms upon these authors. It is not clear why Ferri
is cited as an adherent of the opinion expressed by Dr. Kurella; for he
gives an important place in the etiology of crime to economic factors.

[133] P. 179.

[134] “La criminalità e le vicende economiche d’Italia dal 1873 al 1890
e osservazioni sommarie per il Regno Unito della Gran Bretagna e
Irlanda (1840–1890) e per la Nova Galles del Sud (1882–1891).”

[135] Excepting rural thefts, included under a.

[136] Excepting fraudulent bankruptcy.

[137] Excepting rebellion and violence to public authorities.

[138] Pp. 166, 167.

[139] “Actes”, p. 240.

[140] “Compte rendu”, p. 232.

[Note to the American Edition: See also Professor Lacassagne’s preface
to Laurent’s “Le criminel.”]

[141] “Penal Philosophy”, p. 322.

[142] Op. cit., p. 332.

[143] Op. cit., p. 334.

[144] Op. cit., p. 359.

[145] Op. cit., pp. 362, 363.

[146] Op. cit., pp. 383, 384.

[147] Op. cit., pp. 389–391.

[148] Pp. 392, 393.

[149] On this subject see Kautsky, “Die materialistische
Geschichtsauffassung und der psychologische Antrieb”, p. 655 (“Neue
Zeit”, 1895–1896, II). See the criticism of the imitation theory by
Professor Ferri, in the “Devenir Social”, 1895, entitled “La théorie
sociologique de M. Tarde.”

[150] “Crime”, p. 212.

[151] “Compte Rendu”, p. 199.

[152] Ibid., p. 200.

[153] P. 204.

[154] Pp. 203, 204.

[155] P. 142.

[156] P. 430.

[157] P. 431.

[158] Pp. 434, 435.

[159] P. 436.

[160] P. 561.

[161] P. 568.

[162] See also by the same author: “Les crânes des suppliciés”, “Les
aptitudes et les actes”, “L’atavisme et le crime”, and his reports to
the Congress of Criminal Anthropology at Paris and at Brussels.

[163] Pp. 408, 409.

[164] Pp. 409, 410.

[165] Pp. 414, 415.

[166] Pp. 416, 417.

[167] Pp. 418, 419.

[168] P. 419.

[169] P. 429.

[170] Pp. 431, 432.

[171] Pp. 434–436.

[172] Pp. 445, 446.

[173] Pp. 449, 450.

[174] Pp. 452, 453.

[175] P. 455.

[176] P. 456.

[177] [“Somatisch.” Though capable of being translated thus, this word
is plainly not “physical” in the sense in which that is used for one of
Ferri’s three causes.—Transl.]

[178] Pp. 410, 411.

See also: Dr. A. Bournet, “De la criminalité en France et en Italie”;
G. Richard, “Les crises sociales et la criminalité” (“L’année
sociologique”, 1898–99); L. Gumplowicz, “Das Verbrechen als soziale
Erscheinung” (“Soziologische Essays”).

[Note to the American Edition: Compare further the recent works of the
French school: E. Laurent, “Le criminel”; J. L. de Lanessan, “La lutte
contre le crime”; J. Maxwell, “Le crime et la société.”]

[179] P. 13.

[180] Pp. 13–18.

[181] Pp. 19–22.

[182] P. 6.

[183] P. 37.

[184] Cf. Colajanni, “Sociologia criminale”, II, p. 558.

[185] Pp. 82, 83.

[186] Pp. 106, 107.

[187] [14% of 7% is about 1%, of course. The mistake is
Morrison’s.—Transl.]

[188] In his article, “The Interpretation of Criminal Statistics”
(“Journal of the Royal Statistical Society”), 1897, Morrison says: “I
am inclined to agree ... that the attempt to institute ... comparisons
(of international character) is at present impracticable” (p. 15). It
would have been well if he had not forgotten this opinion when he wrote
“Crime and its Causes.”

[189] See, by the same author: “Juvenile Offenders” (chaps. VII and
VIII).

[190] See, by the same author, “Das Verbrechen als sozial-pathologische
Erscheinung.”

[191] P. 59.

[192] Pp. 59, 60.

[193] [Note to the American Edition: I am glad to be able to call the
reader’s attention to the fact that Professor von Liszt has changed his
opinion with regard to the bio-sociological hypothesis of crime, and
must now be ranked with the partisans of the environmental school. (See
“Die gesellschaftlichen Faktoren der Kriminalität”, pp. 438–439,
“Strafrechtliche Aufsätze und Vorträge”, II.)

Chiefly on account of Professor von Liszt’s initiative, there has
appeared in Germany a series of monographs upon the criminality of a
province, of a district, etc. (criminal topography). Here are the
titles in chronological order: K. Böhmert, “Die sächsische
Kriminalstatistik mit besonderer Rücksicht auf die Jahre 1882–1887”
(“Zeitschr. d. K. Sächsische Statistischen Bureaus”, XXXV; Damme, “Die
Kriminalität in ihre Zusammenhänge in der Provinz Schleswig-Holstein
vom Januar 1882 bis dahin 1890” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrechtsw.”,
XII.); W. Weidemann, “Die Ursachen der Kriminalität im Herzogtum
Sachsen-Meiningen”; B. Blau, “Kriminalstatistische Untersuchung der
Kreise Marienwerder und Thorn”; P. Frauenstädt, “Kriminalistische
Heimatkunde” (“Zeitschr. f. Socialwissenschaft”, VI.); E. Peterselie,
“Untersuchungen über die Kriminalität in der Provinz Sachsen”; F.
Dochow, “Die Kriminalität im Amtsbezirk Heidelberg”; F. Galle,
“Untersuchung über die Kriminalität in der Provinz Schlesien”
(“Gerichtssaal” LXXI, LXXII); W. Stöwesand, “Die Kriminalität in der
Provinz Posen und ihre Ursachen”; A. Sauer, “Frauenkriminalität in
Amtsbezirk Mannheim”.]

[194] To my great satisfaction Dr. Näcke says, in a criticism of my
book, that through reading it, from a bio-sociologist he has almost
become an out-and-out follower of the environmental theory (of the
French school) (“Archiv f. Krim.-anthr. u. Kriminalstatistik,” XXI, p.
188).

[195] Pp. 96, 97.

[196] P. 98.

[197] Pp. 98, 99.

[198] P. 177.

[199] P. 208.

See also, by the same author: “Die neueren Erscheinungen auf
kriminal-anthropologischen Gebiete und ihre Bedeutung” (“Zeitschrift f.
d. ges. Strafrw.”, XIV.).

[Note to the American Edition: See also Näcke’s “Die Ueberbleibsel der
Lombrosischen kriminalanthropologischen Theorien” (“Archiv f.
Krim.-anthr. u. Kriminalität”, L. (1912), pp. 326 ff.)]

[200] In his introduction this author distinguishes three groups of
factors: the cosmic, the biological, and the social. Consequently he
can be ranked in the same category with Professor Ferri. However, I
have thought that he ought rather to be classed among the
bio-sociologists, because he gives a preponderating importance to the
social factors. As he himself says (p. vii of the introduction), his
work is one of the proofs that the divergences of opinions of the
schools of criminologists is not great.

[201] Pp. 371, 372.

[202] P. 97.

[203] P. 90.

[204] Pp. 100, 101.

[205] Pp. 103, 104.

[206] P. 113.

[207] Pp. 115, 116.

[208] [See the author’s explanation of his use of this term in the
preface.—Transl.]

[209] See also Chaps. II and IV.

[210] P. 346.

[211] Pp. 348, 349.

[212] P. 355.

[213] Pp. 358, 359.

[214] P. 365.

[215] [“Misère.” The word may mean misery, of course, as the author has
interpreted it in proving a contradiction of terms, but Joly seems to
use it, as it is generally used, to describe an external condition
rather than a mental state. In any case, all that Joly seems to mean is
that there are those who deliberately prefer effortless indigence to a
competence acquired by toil, being willing to put up with the indigence
for the sake of the wished for escape from effort.—Transl.]

[216] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. “La Belgique criminelle”, by
the same author.]

[217] “Le crime et la peine.”

[218] Pp. 204, 205.

[219] P. 207.

[220] “Les influences de la misère sur la criminalité.” See also
“L’école d’anthropologie criminelle”, by the same author.

[221] See the following chapter.

[222] Pp. 18–20.

[223] Pp. 22, 23.

[224] Pp. 31, 32.

[225] P. 43.

[226] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. also the following authors:
Dr. G. von Rohden, “Von den sozialen Motiven des Verbrechens” and
“Verbrechensbekämpfung und Verbrechensvorbeugung” (“Zeitschr. f.
Socialwissenschaft”, VII and IX), and F. A. K. Krauss, “Der Kampf gegen
die Verbrechensursachen.”]

[227] [Throughout this section the author uses “religion” as meaning a
professed connection with a cult and “irreligion” as the repudiation of
any such connection. This is not the use we commonly make of these
terms in English, but I know of no others that more accurately express
Dr. Bonger’s meaning.—Transl.]

[228] See Bonger, “Geloof en misdaad” (Religion and crime), p. 6.

[229] See also, as members of the “Terza Scuola”: Vaccaro, “Genesi e
funzione delle leggi penali”; Carnevale, “Una terza scuola di diritto
penale”; Alimena, “Naturalismo critico e diritto penale.” In the
“Mitteilungen der internationalen kriminalistischen Vereinigung”, Vol.
IV, is found an article by Dr. E. Rosenfeld, entitled “Die dritte
Schule”, in which the doctrine of this school is fully treated.

In a discourse more distinguished by hatred of Marxism than by a
knowledge of that doctrine, Professor Benedikt said at the Congress of
Criminal Anthropology held in Brussels: “The partisans of the ‘Terza
Scuola’ are in reality only Marxists.” Among those considered as
belonging to the Third School, there is only one Marxist as far as I
know. Professor Benedikt may have been led into his error by the fact
that Dr. Colajanni, one of the principal partisans of the Third School,
and also one of the few criminologists of this school who has written
upon the affinity between criminality and economic conditions, is in
agreement with the Marxists in this, that he finds the causes of crime,
in the last analysis, in economic conditions. This is why I speak of
Dr. Colajanni, as representing the Third School, and of the socialists
in the same chapter. Although Colajanni calls himself a republican in
political matters, he is nevertheless a partisan of an eclectic
socialism. (See “Il Socialismo.”) It is for this reason also that it is
well to name him in this chapter. Other partisans of the Third School
are also, as it appears, more or less of this opinion (see p. 18 of
“Die dritte Schule”, where Dr. Rosenfeld treats of Professor
Carnevale). However, it is evident from the manner in which Dr.
Colajanni treats the question, that he is not a Marxist.

[230] P. 42.

[231] P. 201.

[232] P. 202.

[233] Pp. 235–238.

[234] P. 404.

[235] See also his, “La delinquenza della Sicilia e le sue cause”, and
“Socialismo e criminalità.”

[236] Dr. Colajanni is in error here. Marx never formulated so strange
a theory.

[237] Pp. 456, 457.

[238] For further details see Dr. Colajanni’s report to the Fifth
Congress of Criminal Anthropology.

[239] See pp. 494–500, where the author proves this with the aid of
numerous quotations.

[240] See pp. 504–510.

[241] P. 513.

[242] With regard to Starke, from whom Dr. Colajanni takes these
figures, see Chap. II of this work.

[243] Pp. 562, 563. See also Chap. XIII, in which Dr. Colajanni treats
of the influence of militarism upon criminality.

[244] [To this point Dr. H. B. Adams, Walther’s translation, “Woman in
the Past, Present, and Future”, (Lovell, 1886) has been followed. The
remainder of the quotation is matter added by Bebel since the
publication of the edition from which the above translation was
made.—Transl.]

[245] [A decimal point is plainly lacking after the first figure in
each of these two numbers.—Transl.]

[246] Pp. 295–297.

[247] P. 107.

[248] Pp. 108, 109.

[249] In examining the statistical tables it must be remembered that
they give no real picture of criminality during the years 1870–71, on
account of the effect of the war.

[250] Lafargue’s idea of combining the curves of failure and of the
price of flour is ingenious, but in my opinion does not give a correct
notion of the truth, since it is upon the mistaken notion that the
effect of these two factors is equal.

[251] P. 116.

[252] Pp. 370, 371. “Actes du troisième Congrès international
d’anthropologie criminelle.” See, by the same author, “L’influence de
la crise économique sur la criminalité et le penchant au crime de
Quetelet”, “Le socialisme et les causes économiques et sociales du
crime”, and “Les index numbers (nombres indices) des phénomènes
moraux.”

[253] “Sozialpolitisches Handbuch.”

[254] Pp. 143, 144.

[255] In the last two columns “crimes” was later corrected by the
author himself to “criminals”. See “Neue Zeit”, 1892–1893, II, p. 179,
and 1893–1894, I, pp. 184 and 535.

[256] P. 150.

[257] Pp. 156, 157.

[258] P. 152.

[259] P. 159.

[260] In 1907 a second edition appeared, revised and corrected.

[261] P. 40.

[262] P. 54.

[263] P. 54.

[264] See also: P. Kropotkin, “Paroles d’un révolté”, pp. 241 ff., and
“The Coming Anarchy”, p. 161 (“Nineteenth Century”, 1887); J. Stern,
“Einfluss der sozialen Zustände auf alle Zweige des Kulturlebens”, pp.
24 ff.; E. Belfort Bax, “Ethics of Socialism”; T. W. Teifen, “Das
soziale Elend und die besitzenden Klassen in Oesterreich”, pp. 132–137,
170–171; J. S(chmidt), “Einfluss der Krisen und der Steigerung der
Lebensmittelpreise auf das Gesellschaftsleben”, pp. 16–19, 23; H.
Wetzker, “Die Zunahme der Verbrechen” (“Sozialistische Monatshefte”,
1902, II); E. Reich, “Criminalität und Altruismus”; E. Gystrow,
“Social-pathologische Probleme der Gegenwart” (“Soz. Monatshefte”, V,
1901).

See also Chapter I, in which I have treated of several socialists, who
had to be placed there because they wrote before the rise of modern
criminology.

[Note to the American Edition: See also E. Fischer, “Laienbemerkungen
zur Reform des Strafrechts” (“Soz. Monatshefte”, X,1 (1906); Dr. S.
Ettinger, “Das Verbrecherproblem in anthropologischer und
soziologischer Beleuchtung”, which, resting upon the socialist theory,
criticises especially the anthropological school; and Robert
Blatchford, “Not Guilty”, an original and popular exposition of the
theory of the environment.]

[265] P. xi.

[266] I do not mean to deny the importance of historical researches
into crime, such as the famous book of Pike, “History of Crime in
England”, or the “Documents de criminologie rétrospective” of Corre and
Aubry. They can give us valuable information with regard to the
etiology of crime, but in my opinion it is indubitable that the
historic method never permits us to give the complete etiology of a
social phenomenon, like criminality, for example.

[267] This sketch is based upon Karl Marx’s “Kapital” and K. Kautsky’s
works primarily, with some indebtedness to Marx’s “Oekonomischen
Lehren”, and “Das Erfurter Programm.”

[268] Marx, “Kapital”, I, p. 4.

[269] “Kapital”, I, p. 6. It is plain that in this exposition it is
needless to add why this law is discarded under a developed system of
capitalism. The exception in no way diminishes the fundamental truth of
the proposition.

[270] In his work “The Condition of the Working-class in England”, F.
Engels, after speaking of the condition of the English proletariat,
says, “The working-class has gradually become a race wholly apart from
the English bourgeoisie. The bourgeoisie has more in common with every
other nation of the earth than with the workers in whose midst it
lives. The workers speak other dialects, have other thoughts and
ideals, other customs and moral principles, a different religion, and
other politics than the bourgeoisie. They are two radically dissimilar
nations.” (P. 124. [In original, p. 127].)

[271] Upon the petty bourgeoisie see the excellent article of Dr. B.
Schönlank, “Zur Psychologie des Kleinbürgerthums” (“Neue Zeit”, 1890).

[272] Alcoholism being of great importance for criminality I shall
treat the etiology of this social phenomenon separately (see Chap. IV).

[273] It is plain that I cannot cite proofs in support of this
exposition; I should go beyond the proper limits of this discussion of
the present economic system and its consequences. Furthermore it would
be useless; for those of my readers who do not know from having seen it
that the situation is as I have stated, can be convinced by reading the
rich literature upon the subject. I will refer here only to the more
noteworthy books; For England: F. Engels, “The Condition of the
Working-Class in England” (1845); K. Marx, “Das Kapital” (1867); M.
Schippel, “Das moderne Elend und die moderne Ueberbevölkerung” (1888);
Chas. Booth, “Life and Labor of the People in London” (1892–1897); R.
Blatchford, “Merrie England” (1894), and “Dismal England” (1901); B. S.
Rowntree, “Poverty, A Study of Town Life” (1901). For Germany: Dr. H.
Lux, “Sozialpolitisches Handbuch” (1889); P. Göhre, “Drei Monate
Fabrikarbeiter” (1891); Dr. R. Hirschberg, “Soziale Lage der
arbeitenden Klasse in Berlin” (1897); H. Herkner, “Die Arbeitsfrage”
(1894), treating also of Austria and Switzerland. For Austria: T. W.
Teifen, “Das soziale Elend und die besitzenden Klassen” (1894). For
Holland: “Rapport der Commissie belast met het onderzoek naar den
toestand der kinderen in fabrieken arbeidende” (1872); “Enquête
betreffende werking en uitbreiding der wet van 19 September 1874 en
naar den toestand van fabrieken en werkplaatsen” (1887); “Enquête
gehouden door de staatscommissie benoemd volgens de wet van 19 Jan.
1890” (1800–1894); “Een vergeten hoofdstuk” (1898); H. Roland-Holst,
“Kapitaal en arbeid in Nederland” (1902).

Upon the conditions of women’s work see: L. Braun, “Die Frauenfrage.”
Upon the housing of working-men in the great cities see: A. Braun,
“Berliner Wohnungsverhältnisse”; E. von Philippovich, “Wiener
Wohnungsverhältnisse” (“Archiv f. soz. Gesetzgeb.” u. Stat. VII).

[Note to the American Edition: The literature upon the social condition
of the proletariat has increased considerably in recent years. It would
be impossible and also superfluous to cite the whole of this
literature; I note only certain works that seem remarkable for one
reason or another.

For England: L. G. Chiozza-Money, “Riches and Poverty” (1905). For
Germany: K. Fischer, “Denkwürdigkeiten und Erinnerungen eines
Arbeiters” (1903–04); M. W. Th. Bromme, “Lebensgeschichte eines
modernen Fabrikarbeiters” (1905); and Fr. Rehbein, “Das Leben eines
Landarbeiters.” For the United States: R. Hunter, “Das Elend der neuen
Welt” (1908). For Russia: K. A. Pashitnow, “Die Lage der arbeitenden
Klasse in Russland” (1907). For the Netherlands: J. J. Moquette,
“Onderzoekingen over volksvoeding in de gemeente Utrecht”, 1907;
“Arbeidersleven in Nederland” (1908); “Onderzoekingen naar de
toestanden in de Nederlandsche huisindustrie”, 1911–1912. Upon the
condition of working-people in general see especially the very
interesting and original work of Niceforo, “Anthropologie der
nichtbesitzenden Klassen” (1910). Upon the condition of working-women,
see “Die Jugendgeschichte einer Arbeiterin” (1909); R. Kempf, “Das
Leben der jungen Fabrikmädchen in München” (1911); the official
investigation into the work of married women in the factories in the
Netherlands (1911). Upon child-labor: “Das proletarische Kind.”]

[274] See the proof cited by K. Kautsky in his “Sozialreform und
soziale Revolution” (pp. 22–25), in support of the assertion that the
distance between the bourgeoisie and the proletariat has increased.

[275] What the Germans call “Lumpenproletariat.” [The French is “le bas
Prolétariat.” “Submerged class” is perhaps our most common English
equivalent.—Transl.] With the lower proletariat we must include
prostitutes and a part of the criminals. These two groups we shall
naturally treat in detail later.

[276] Pp. 213–215. (“Neue Zeit”, 1884).

[277] Op. cit. p. 215. See also, as regards the condition of the lower
proletariat in Germany, Dr. H. Lux, “Sozialpolitisches Handbuch”, pp.
32 ff.; for Austria: T. W. Teifen, “Das soziale Elend, etc.” IV, pp.
122 ff.; for Russia: O. Zetkin, “Die barfüssige Bande” (“Neue Zeit”,
1885); for England: Ch. Booth, “Pauperism” and “Life and Labour of the
People in London”, VIII; for all Europe: L. M. Moreau-Christophe, “Du
problème de la misère,” III; for North America see R. Hunter, “Das
Elend der neuen Welt”, pp. 51 ff.

[278] There may be found in Dr. L. Woltmann’s “Die Darwinsche Theorie
und der Sozialismus” (pp. 81–135) a detailed résumé of the works of the
authors who hold this opinion. Cf. also Herkner, “Die Arbeiterfrage”,
pp. 178 ff., where also the literature upon this point is to be found.

[279] P. 527, op. cit. I.

[280] P. 529, op. cit. I.

[281] As is well known, Galton is one of the authors who denies this
thesis. One of the rare examples which he produces as proof is
d’Alembert, who, notwithstanding an unfavorable educational
environment, became a celebrity. (See “Hereditary Genius,” pp. 34–39).
Unfortunately for Galton Professor Odin proves that d’Alembert received
an excellent education and was brought up in relatively favorable
economic conditions. (See “Genèse des grands hommes,” p. 538, I.) See
also Professor Odin’s criticism of Galton (pp. 192 ff., op. cit., I).

[282] Op. cit., I, p. 562.

[283] P. 80.

[284] Cf. especially the excellent refutation of the pseudo-Darwinian
theory by Professor Bücher in the chapter “Arbeitsgliederung und
Soziale Klassenbilderung” from his “Entstehen der Volkswirtschaft.”

[285] See Woltmann, op. cit., pp. 32–81 and pp. 334 ff., where he cites
a number of authors who are of this opinion. Upon the whole subject see
Dr. A. Ploetz, “Die Tüchtigkeit unsrer Rasse und der Schutz der
Schwachen”, and Dr. D. van Embden, “Darwinisme en Demokratie.”

[286] “Menschliche Auslese”, p. 10 (Zukunft, 1894).

[287] Under this heading are included all the children below 14, and
the women who live with the person assisted. It is enough to point out
that the indigence of these co-assisted persons does not proceed from
any cause in the persons themselves, but in their circumstances.

[288] “Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich”, X, 1889, pp.
206–208.

[289] Read the following taken from “Illustrations of the Manners,
Customs, and Conditions of the North American Indians”, by G. Catlin:
“This cruel custom of exposing their aged people, belongs, I think, to
all the tribes who roam about the prairies, making severe marches, when
such decrepit persons are totally unable to go, unable to ride or to
walk,—when they have no means of carrying them. It often becomes
absolutely necessary in such cases that they should be left; and they
uniformly insist upon it, saying as one old man did, that they are old
and of no further use—that they left their fathers in the same
manner—that they wish to die, and their children must not mourn for
them.” (I, p. 217.)

[290] The figures given by J. S. in “Aus den Ergebnissen der
sächsischen Armenstatistik” (“Neue Zeit” 1894–95, II), confirm those in
the table I have given, if we do not lose sight of the fact that J. S.
does not give the “co-assisted” persons separately. The figures of
Charles Booth in his “Pauperism” show that alcoholism forms a more
important factor in the two districts that he has studied (12.6% and
21.9%); for laziness the figures are 1.9% and 10.6%. Statistics of the
Netherlands confirm in general those of the German Empire:

=========================+========+========++===========================+========+========
  Assisted Temporarily.  |  1898  | 1899   ||  Assisted Continuously.   |  1898  |  1899
-------------------------+--------+--------++---------------------------+--------+--------
  Causes of Indigence.   |   %    |  %     ||   Causes of Indigence.    |   %    |   %
-------------------------+--------+--------++---------------------------+--------+--------
Illness, etc.            |  42.3  |  45.1  || Illness or bodily defects |  18.6  |  18.9
Lack or shortage of work |  30.7  |  28.9  || Old age                   |  45.4  |  47
Alcoholism               |   2.6  |   2.6  || Death of breadwinner      |  20.0  |  19.2
Other causes             |  24.4  |  23.4  || Alcoholism                |   1.8  |   1.5
                         |--------+--------|| Other causes              |  14.2  |  13.4
                         | 100.0  | 100.0  ||                           |--------+--------
                         |        |        ||                           | 100.0  | 100.0
=========================+========+========++===========================+========+========

(Verslagen over de verrichtingen aangaande het armbestuur over 1898 en
1899. Bijlage E. Handelingen 2e Kamer der Staten-Generaal 1899–1900,
1900–1901.)

[291] P. 490. “Biologie und Kriminalstatistik.” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
Strafrechtswissenschaft”, VII.)

[292] See K. Kautsky’s “Das Erfurter Programm”, p. 64.

[293] Upon the period without class see, among others, L. H. Morgan,
“Ancient Society”, and upon the origin of classes H. Cunow,
“Arbeitstheilung und Frauenrecht” (“Neue Zeit”, 1900–01, I, p. 178
ff.).

[294] It is well known that sociological studies upon the subject of
marriage date from 1861, when Bachofen’s “Das Mutterrecht” came out.
Since then a very extensive literature on the subject has appeared,
without by any means exhausting the subject. (See Dr. Steinmetz, “Die
neueren Forschungen zur Geschichte der menschlichen Familie”,
“Zeitschr. für Sozialwissenschaft,” 1899.)

[Note to the American Edition: The literature upon the origin and
evolution of marriage and the family has recently been considerably
increased. The following books seem to us to be the most important: H.
Schurtz, “Altersklassen und Männerbünde”; M. Weber, “Ehefrau und Mutter
in der Rechtsentwicklung”; A. Vierkandt, “Das Problem der Familien- und
Stammesorganisation der Naturvölker”; E. Westermarck, “Ursprung und
Entwicklung der Moralbegriffe”, II; F. Müller-Lyer, “Formen der Ehe”,
“Die Familie”, and “Phasen der Liebe”; H. Cunow, “Zur Urgeschichte der
Ehe und Familie.”]

[295] Westermarck (in his “History of Human Marriage”, pp. 51–133) has
led the opposition to the promiscuity theory. It is also combated by
Starcke in his “Die primitive Familie” and by Grosse in his “Die Formen
der Familie und die Formen der Wirthschaft” (pp. 41–45). For a résumé
of the arguments for and against see Dr. C. J. Wynaendts Francken, “De
Evolutie van het huwelijk” (pp. 57–65).

[296] See Ch. Letourneau, “L’évolution du mariage” (pp. 46–48).

[297] See Fr. Engels, “Der Ursprung der Familie, des Privateigenthums,
und des Staats” (pp. 17–18) [Translated as “The Origin of the family,
etc.” Page references are to the original.]; and C. de Kelles-Krauz,
“Formes primitives de la famille” (pp. 303–304 of the “Revue
Internationale de Sociologie”, VIII).

[298] The following discussion is based upon material drawn from Grosse
(op. cit.), and from H. Cunow (“Die ökonomischen Grundlagen der
Mutterherrschaft” (“Neue Zeit”, 1897–98).

[299] Op. cit., pp. 60–61.

[300] L. H. Morgan, “Ancient Society”, p. 424; Fr. Engels, op. cit., p.
21; and others.

[301] Westermarck believes that there is an innate aversion to sexual
relationships between persons who have lived together from childhood;
and that the sexual aversion that exists between near blood-relations
is in consequence of the fact that these persons have always lived
together. This instinct would thus have been acquired by natural
selection, since those who did not have it would run more danger than
the others of disappearing in consequence of the injurious effects of
such unions. (Op. cit., chaps. xiv and xv.) Cunow on the other hand
makes the point that there cannot be an innate aversion between persons
who have been raised together, for marriages between such persons do
take place, and are not thought at all immoral or contrary to nature.
(“Die Verwandtschaftsorganisationen der Australneger,” pp. 184 ff.)

[302] See Steinmetz, op. cit., p. 817.

[303] Upon the origin of agriculture see H. Cunow, “Arbeitstheilung und
Frauenrecht” (“Neue Zeit”, 1900–1901; I, pp. 102 ff.).

[304] See C. N. Starcke, “Die primitive Familie”, pp. 106–107.

[305] The “metronymic” system by which the mother has the right to
transmit her name to the child (Mutterrecht) is quite distinct from the
matriarchate. As to the origin of the matriarchate see Dr. L. v.
Dargun, “Mutterrecht und Vaterrecht”, pp. 67 ff.

[306] L. H. Morgan, “Ancient Society”, p. 345; Dargun, op. cit., pp.
131, 132.

[307] See Morgan, op. cit., Pt. II, chap. X and XIII, and F. Engels,
“Origin of the Family, etc.”, chap. V, VI, VIII; Gumplowicz, “Grundriss
der Soziologie,” pp. 190 ff.; and F. Oppenheimer, “Der Staat.”

[308] Engels, op. cit., p. 51. [Paging of original.]

[309] See Engels, op. cit., pp. 47 ff. [Paging of original.]

[310] See A. Bebel, “Die Frau und der Sozialismus”, pp. 265 ff.

[311] See “Neue Zeit”, 188, p. 239; G. v. Mayr, “Statistik und
Gesellschaftslehre”, II, p. 384; F. v. d. Goes, “Socialisme en
Feminisme” (“Tweemaandelijksch Tijdschrift”, VI, 1900) pp. 430–445;
Braun, “Die Frauenfrage”, pp. 166 ff.; C. Zetkin, “Geistiges
Proletariat, Frauenfrage und Sozialismus”, pp. 4, 5.

[312] See Bebel, op. cit., chapter entitled “Ehehemmnisse und
Ehehindernisse”; v. d. Goes, op. cit., pp. 445–458; Braun, op. cit.,
pp. 166–170; Zetkin, op. cit., pp. 5–6.

[313] See Bebel, op. cit., p. 159; v. d. Goes, op. cit., pp. 458 ff.;
and Braun, op. cit., pp. 165, 166.

[314] See Bebel, op cit., pp. 223 ff.; v. d. Goes, op. cit. (Année VII,
1901), pp. 120 ff.; Zetkin, op. cit., pp. 3, 4, and “Die Arbeiterinnen-
und Frauenfrage der Gegenwart”, pp. 3 ff.

[315] See Braun, op. cit., p. 181.

[316] See Braun, op. cit. Pt. II, chaps. IV and V.

[317] [Note to the American Edition: There has appeared, especially
recently, an extensive literature criticising the conditions of modern
marriage. Cf. among others: Forel, “Die Sexuelle Frage”; M. Weber, op.
cit., chap. vi; T. Bloch, “Das Sexualleben unserer Zeit”, chap. x;
Havelock Ellis, “Geschlecht und Gesellschaft”, II, chap. x; A. Moll,
“Handbuch der Sexualwissenschaften”; F. Müller-Lyer, “Die Familie” and
“Phasen der Liebe.”]

[318] “Das Weib und der Stier.” (“Neue Zeit”, 1900–1901, II, p. 6–7.)

[319] Upon marriage in the bourgeoisie see Fourier, “Théorie des quatre
mouvements” (Complete Works, I, pp. 162 ff.); A. E. F. Schäffle, “Bau
und Leben”, etc., III, pp. 36, 50; Nordau, “Die conventionnellen Lügen
der Kulturmenschheit”, pp. 263 ff.; Bebel, op. cit., pp. 103 ff.; and
Dr. E. Gystrow, “Liebe und Liebesleben im XIX Jahrhundert”, pp. 26 ff.

[320] It is unnecessary to go into the question of marriage in the
petty bourgeoisie, which does not differ fundamentally from that which
we have been treating. See Dr. B. Schönlank, “Zur Psychologie des
Kleinbürgerthums”, pp. 123–124 (“Neue Zeit”, 1890).

[321] Engels, op. cit., pp. 59, 60, and Dr. A. Blaschko, “Die
Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”, p. 12.

[322] See “Englands industrielle Reservearmee”, pp. 215–216 (“Neue
Zeit”, 1884).

[323] Engels, op. cit., pp. 63–74 [paging of original].

[324] E. Grosse, “Die Formen der Familie und die Formen der
Wirthschaft”, pp. 49–53.

[325] See Grosse, op. cit., pp. 78–82, 120–123.

[326] Grosse, op. cit., pp. 183–186.

[327] See Grosse, op. cit., pp. 220–223, 226–228, 230–234.

[328] See v. Dargun, op. cit., p. 12.

[329] See M. Kovalewsky, “Tableau des origines et de l’évolution de la
famille et de la propriété”, pp. 150–161.

[330] The law does not produce much change in the situation which would
exist without it, since most parents would perform this duty without
being compelled.

[331] L. Ferriani, “Entartete Mütter”, pp. 24–50.

[332] “Der Selbstmord im kindlichen Lebensalter”, p. 48.

[333] Op. cit. This quotation follows directly upon the one given
above.

[334] Dr. A. Baer, op. cit., p. 49. See also pp. 58, 59.

[335] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. M. Kauffmann, “Die Psychologie
des Verbrechens”, pp. 235 ff.]

[336] C. Zetkin, “Die Arbeiterinnen- und Frauenfrage der Gegenwart”,
pp. 23–39.

[337] See J. Stern, “Thesen über den Sozialismus”, p. 24; and C.
Zetkin, op. cit., pp. 30 ff.

[338] C. Zetkin, op. cit., p. 24.

[339] L. Ferriani, “Schlaue und glückliche Verbrecher”, pp. 34, 35.

[340] To name one among many: M. Kovalewsky. See his “Tableau des
origines et de l’évolution de la famille et de la propriété”, pp. 160,
161.

[341] The number of births is constantly decreasing, and the consequent
decrease in the size of families accentuates the tendency to develop
egoism in the child.

[342] Compare, among others, E. Key, “Das Jahrhundert des Kindes”, p.
316.

[343] “The Book of the New Moral World”, Pt. III., pp. 9–11.

[344] K. Kautsky, “Die Entstehung des Christenthums” (“Neue Zeit”,
1885).

[345] L. Ferriani, “Schlaue und glückliche Verbrecher”, p. 48.

[346] P. 144 [In original, p. 147]. See also L. Braun, “Die
Frauenfrage”, pp. 318 ff.; C. Zetkin, op. cit., p. 26; Herkner, op.
cit., pp. 36 ff.; and especially Rühle, “Das proletarische Kind”, pp.
42 ff. Upon the education of children of the working class in general,
see also: G. Schönfeldt, “Die heutige Arbeiterfamilie und die
öffentliche Erziehung vorschulpflichtiger Kinder” (“Neue Zeit”, I,
1898–1899).

[347] [Note to the American Edition: Upon the situation of illegitimate
children see Rühle, op. cit. pp. 63 ff., and especially the interesting
works of Dr. Spann, “Untersuchungen über die uneheliche Bevölkerung in
Frankfurt a/M.” and “Die unehelichen Mündel des Vormundschaftsgerichtes
in Frankfurt a/M.”]

[348] Dr. C. Hugo, “Kind und Gesellschaft”, p. 562 (“Neue Zeit”,
1894–1895, I). See also L. Ferriani, “Entartete Mütter.”

[Note to the American Edition: At this moment I have before me the
“Annual Report, 1912–1913”, where it is shown that the total number of
children for whom the society in question has cared has increased to
2,101,130 in 29 years, an annual average, therefore, of about 75,000.
For the year of the report the number was 159,000.

Cf. Rühle, op. cit., and especially the report upon Austria of Dr. J.
M. Baernreither, “Die Ursachen, Erscheinungsformen und die Ausbreitung
der Verwahrlosung von Kindern und Jugendlichen in Oesterreich.”]

[349] For a criticism of the present educational system see A. C. F.
Schäffle, “Bau und Leben des sozialen Körpers”, I, p. 262; Ch.
Letourneau, “L’évolution du mariage et de la famille”, p. 444; E. Key,
“Das Jahrhundert des Kindes”, pp. 109 ff.; Th. Schlesinger Eckstein,
“Die Frau im XIX Jahrhundert”, pp. 54–56.

[350] [Note to the American Edition: There has also appeared in recent
times a considerable literature upon the etiology of prostitution. We
note the following: A. Forel, “Die sexuelle Frage”, chap. x; P.
Kampffmeyer, “Die Prostitution als soziale Klassenerscheinung und ihre
sozialpolitische Bekämpfung”; T. Hermann, “Die Prostitution und ihr
Anhang”; T. Bloch, “Das Sexualleben unserer Zeit”, chap. xiii, and “Die
Prostitution”, I (chiefly historical); A. Pappritz, “Die Welt von der
man nicht spricht”; H. Arendt, “Menschen die den Pfad verloren”; M.
Minovici, “Remarques sur la criminalité en Roumanie”; C. K. Schneider,
“Die Prostituirte und die Gesellschaft”; G. Schnapper-Arndt,
“Sozial-Statistik”, chap. viii; Quiros and Aguinaliedo, “Verbrechertum
und Prostitution in Madrid”; R. Hessen, “Die Prostitution in
Deutschland”; A. Blaschko, “Prostitution” (“Handwörterbuch der
Staatswissenschaften”, VI); H. Ellis, “Geschlecht und Gesellschaft”,
II, chap. viii; “The Social Evil in Chicago” (“Report of the Vice
Commission of Chicago”); A. Moll, “Handbuch der Sexualwissenschaften”,
chap. iv; E. von Grabe, “Prostitution, Kriminalität, und Psychopathie”;
A. Neher, “Die geheime und öffentliche Prostitution in Stuttgart,
Karlsruhe, und München.”]

[351] C. Zetkin, “Geistiges Proletariat, Frauenfrage, und Sozialismus”,
pp. 5, 6; Dr. J. Jeannel, “De la prostitution dans les grandes villes
au XIXe siècle”, pp. 187, 188.

[352] Each consequence becomes in its turn a cause; as in this case,
for, while prostitution is largely a consequence of the impossibility
of marrying, prostitution in its turn becomes, through the demoralizing
influence of the prostitutes, a reason why some men do not marry
although their means would permit it.

[353] See also by the same author: “Die moderne Prostitution”, pp. 14,
15 (“Neue Zeit”, 1891–92, II), and “Hygiene der Prostitution und
venerischen Krankheiten”, p. 39; Dr. V. Augagneur: “La prostitution des
filles mineures” (“Archives d’anthropologie criminelle”, III, p. 224).

[354] [Note to the American Edition: Upon the demoralization of poor
children see the works of Baernreither and Rühle already cited, and H.
Arendt, “Kleine Weisse Sklaven.”]

[355] This study may be found in the second volume of
Parent-Duchatelet’s work: “De la Prostitution dans la ville de Paris.”

[356] P. 39 (Session 1882).

[357] Vol. I, pp. 91, 92.

[358] “La Prostitution à Paris et à Londres”, p. 125.

[359] Op. cit., p. 211.

[360] “Le Crime à Deux”, pp. 205, 206. For figures for Berlin see Dr.
B. Schoenlank, “Zur Statistik der Prostitution in Berlin”, pp. 335, 336
(“Archiv für soziale Gesetzgeb. u. Stat.”, VII.).

[361] “La prostitution en Russie”, p. 195 (“Progrès médical”, 1893).

[362] “Die Beziehungen der Prostitution zum Verbrechen”, p. 8 (“Archiv
f. Kriminal Anthropologie u. Kriminalstatistik”, XI.).

[363] “Zur Kenntnis des grossstädtischen Bettel- und Vagabondentums,”
p. 188 (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.”, XXXIII).

[364] Op. cit. I, pp. 92, 93.

[365] Op. cit., p. 210.

[366] Op. cit., pp. 215, 216.

[367] “Reports of the Select Committee”, Appendix B, p. 52.

[368] Pp. 42–44 and 46–66.

[369] Appendix B, p. 52.

[370] P. 133.

[371] Op. cit., p. 108.

[372] Op. cit., p. 196.

[373] Op. cit., I, pp. 67–70.

[374] Op. cit., I, p. 68.

[375] Op. cit., I, p. 71. The data of the same author show that out of
3,095 fathers of prostitutes, 1,078 (35%) could not sign their names.

[376] Op. cit., I, p. 108.

[377] “Moralstatistik”, p. 216. Upon this cause of prostitution see
also: Dr. G. Richelot, op. cit., pp. 582, 583; Dr. C. Röhrmann, “Der
sittliche Zustand von Berlin”, pp. 45, 46; “Die Prostitution in
Berlin”, pp. 86, 87; L. Faucher, “Études sur l’Angleterre”, I, p. 74;
Lecour, op. cit., pp. 202–204; Carlier, op. cit., pp. 35, 36; G. Tomel
and H. Rollet, “Les enfants en prison”, pp. 156 ff.; L. Ferriani,
“Entartete Mütter”, p. 161; Dr. O. Commenge, “La prostitution
clandestine à Paris”, pp. 33–35.

[378] Op. cit., p. 216.

[379] Appendix B, p. 52.

[380] P. 42.

[381] Op. cit., p. 108.

[382] Op. cit., p. 197.

[383] Op. cit., I, p. 102.

[384] Op. cit., I, p. 102. Upon this cause of prostitution see further:
Dr. Richelot, op. cit., pp. 574, 575; Dr. Fr. S. Hügel, “Zur
Geschichte, Statistik, und Regelung der Prostitution”, pp. 206, 207;
Dr. Jeannel, op. cit., pp. 145, 146; A. C. Fr. Schäffle, “Bau und Leben
des sozialen Körpers”, I, p. 261; H. Stursberg, “Die Prostitution in
Deutschland und ihre Bekämpfung”, pp. 44, 45; Dr. E. Laurent, “Les
habitués des prisons de Paris”, pp. 585–589 (description of types); G.
Schönfeldt, “Beiträge zur Geschichte des Pauperismus und der
Prostitution in Hamburg”, p. 269.

[385] A. Pappritz, “Die wirthschaftlichen Ursachen der Prostitution”,
p. 14.

[386] “Wiener Wohnungsverhältnisse”, pp. 221–223 (“Archiv f. soz.
Gesetzg. u. Statist.” VII).

[387] “Bijdragen tot de Statistiek van Nederland XXIV, Uitkomsten der
woning-statistiek”, p. 52.

[388] Op. cit., p. 98.

[389] Pappritz, op. cit., p. 15.

[390] v. Philippovich, op. cit., p. 222.

[391] P. 42. See also: Richelot, op. cit., pp. 573, 574; W. Acton,
“Prostitution Considered in its Moral, Social, and Sanitary Aspects”,
pp. 131 ff.; Jeannel, op. cit., p. 143; Lecour, op. cit., p. 246;
“Reports of the Select Committee, etc.”, p. 39 (Session of 1882);
Stursberg, op. cit., pp. 46, 47; Commenge, op. cit., p. 32.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. Th. M. Raest van Limburg, “In den
strijd tegen de ontucht.” P. Kampffmeyer, “Das Wohnungselend der
Grossstädte und seine Beziehungen zur Verbreitung der
Geschlechtskrankheiten und zur Prostitution”, and “Die
Wohnungsmissstände im Prostitutions- und im Schlafgängerwesen und ihre
gesetzliche Reform”; Pfeiffer, “Das Wohnungselend der grossen Städte
und seine Beziehungen zur Prostitution und den
Geschlechtskrankheiten.”]

[392] Op. cit., p. 54.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. especially the “Report of the
Departmental Committee on the Employment of Children, Oct., 1903.”]

[393] Op. cit., p. 247. See also Parent-Duchatelet, op. cit., I. p.
103; Röhrmann, op. cit., p. 44; Jeannel, op. cit., pp. 146–148;
“Reports”, etc. (Session of 1882), pp. 15–17; K. Struntz, “Die
erwerbsmässige Kinderarbeit und die Schule”, pp. 183 ff. (“Neue Zeit”,
1898–1899, I).

[394] Dr. A. Blaschko, “Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”, p. 22;
“Hygiene der Prostitution”, pp. 40, 41.

[395] Appendix B, p. 52.

[396] Dr. Bonhoeffer, op. cit., p. 109.

[397] See the detailed statistics, op. cit., I, pp. 79–84.

[398] Op. cit., p. 148.

[399] Op. cit., p. 336.

[400] Op. cit., p. 197.

[401] Pp. 148, 149 [in original, pp. 151, 152]. See also: L. Faucher,
“Études sur l’Angleterre”, I, pp. 276, 277; M. de Baets, “Les
influences de la misère sur la criminalité”, pp. 35, 36; Stursberg, op.
cit., pp. 49, 50; Commenge, op. cit., pp 13–15; L. Ferriani, “Schlaue
und glückliche Verbrecher”, p 467.

[402] Op. cit., p. 149 [in original, p. 152]. For analogous cases see
A. Bebel, “Die Frau und der Sozialismus”, pp. 195–197; “Les Scandales
de Londres”, pp. 235–238; “Enquête betreffende werking en uitbreiding
der wet van 19 September 1874 en naar den toestand van fabrieken en
werkplaatsen”, 1887, deel V, p. 77; Dr. H Lux, “Sozialpolitisches
Handbuch”, pp. 135, 136; Hirsch, op. cit., pp. 46–48; Commenge, op.
cit., pp. 15–17; G. S., “Die weibliche Lohnarbeit und ihr Einfluss auf
die Sittlichkeit und Kriminalität”, p. 748 (“Neue Zeit”, 1899–1900,
II); L. Braun, “Die Frauenfrage”, p. 308.

[403] See “Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”, pp. 23, 24.

[404] L. Braun, “Die Frauenfrage”, pp. 409–411; G. S., op. cit., pp.
754–756.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon servants cf. further: O. Spann,
“Die geschlechtlich-sittlichen Verhältnisse im Dienstboten und
Arbeiterinnenstande”; and R. de Ryckère, “La servante criminelle”, ch.
IX.]

[405] Hirsch, op. cit., pp. 48–50.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: C. Jellinek,
“Kellnerinnenelend” and Dr. H. Peters, “Zur Lage der Kellnerinnen im
Grossherzogtum Baden.” Upon prostitution in the theater see V. v.
Lepel, “Prostitution beim Theater.”]

[406] Stursberg, op. cit., pp. 55, 57; Hirsch, op. cit., pp. 42, 43;
Pappritz, op. cit., pp. 13, 14.

[407] Op. cit., I, p. 107.

[408] Appendix B, p. 52.

[409] P. 169.

[410] H. Frégier, “Les classes dangereuses de la population dans les
grandes villes”, I, p. 97; Lecour, op. cit., p. 244; L. Taxil, “La
corruption fin-de-siècle”, p. 42; Commenge, op. cit., pp. 17–20; A.
Aletrino, “Over eenige oorzaken der prostitutie”, pp. 21, 22; E.
Gystrow, “Liebe und Liebesleben im XIX Jahrhundert”, p. 22.

[411] Op. cit., I, p. 107.

[412] Op. cit., I, p. 99.

[413] Op. cit., I, pp. 104, 105.

[414] Session 1882, Appendix B, p. 52.

[415] Op. cit., p. 169.

[416] “Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”, pp. 17, 18. See also B.
Schönlank, “Zur Lage der in der Wäschefabrikation und
Konfektionsbranche Deutschlands beschäftigen Arbeiterinnen”, pp. 126,
127 (“Neue Zeit”, 1888); Hirsch, op. cit., p. 46; Pappritz, op. cit.,
p. 10.

[417] Hirsch, op. cit., p. 57.

[418] P. 161. See also Faucher, op. cit., I, p. 277; Bebel, op. cit.,
p. 194; and Schäffle, op. cit., I, p. 261. Cf. Neher, op. cit., pp. 13
ff.

[419] Pp. 8, 9.

[420] P. 188 (“Jahrbuch für Gesetzgebung, Verwaltung, und
Volkswirthschaft”, XII, 2). See also L. Braun, “Die Frauenfrage”, pp.
227 ff., and 287 ff.

[421] I, p. 65.

[422] III, p. 168. See also “Reports of the Select Committee,” etc.
(Session 1882), pp. 15, 16.

[423] Op. cit., I, pp. 103–104. See also: Richelot, op. cit., pp.
577–579; Frégier, op. cit., I, pp. 97, 98; Ducpetiaux, “De la condition
physique et morale des jeunes ouvriers”, I, p. 315; “Die Prostitution
in Berlin” (Anon.), pp. 84, 85; Loewe, “Die Prostitution”, pp. 135,
136; Röhrmann, op. cit., pp. 24, 25; Moreau-Christophe, op. cit., III,
pp. 167, 168; Acton, op. cit., pp. 180 ff.; Hügel, op. cit., p. 208;
Jeannel, op. cit., pp. 140–142; Lecour, op. cit., p. 248; Müller, “De
Prostitutie”, pp. 10–11; du Camp, “Prostitution à Paris”, pp. 257, 258
(“Journal des économistes”, 1872); Kühn, “Die Prostitution im XIX
Jahrhundert”, pp. 37, 38; Schäffle, op. cit., p. 261; von Oettingen,
op. cit., pp. 212, 213; Domela Nieuwenhuis, “Zur Frage der
Prostitution”, pp. 254 ff. (“Neue Zeit”, 1884); Stursberg, op. cit.,
pp. 51–53; Lux, “Die Prostitution”, pp. 10–12; Schönfeld, op. cit., pp.
269 ff.; Teifen, “Das Soziale Elende und die besitzenden Klassen in
Oesterreich”, pp. 150 ff.; Taxil, op. cit., pp. 33–38; De Baets, op.
cit., pp. 36, 37; Commenge, op. cit., pp. 28, 29, 36, 37; Blaschko,
“Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”, pp. 16–21.

[424] L. Braun, op. cit., p. 555; Röhrmann, op. cit., pp. 46, 47;
Pappritz, op. cit., p. 12.

[425] Kühn, op. cit., p. 38.

[426] Hatzig, “Der Mädchenhandel”, p. 514 (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
Strafrw.” XX); Bebel, op. cit., pp. 190–192; “Reports of the Select
Committee”, etc. (Session 1881); “Les scandales de Londres”, passim;
Collard, “De handel in blanke slavinnen”, pp. 4–56.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: A. Mackirdy and W. N.
Willis, “The White Slave Market”; Willis, “The White Slaves of London”;
and H. Wagener, “Der Mädchenhandel.”]

[427] Pp. 514, 515.

[428] Collard, op. cit., pp. 13–15. Upon the procurer’s trade in
general see: Parent-Duchatelet, op. cit., I, pp. 430–436; Richelot, op.
cit., pp. 583–588; Acton, op. cit., p. 165; Lecour, op. cit., pp.
195–202; Carlier, op. cit., chap. II; Stursberg, op. cit., p. 53;
Commenge, op. cit., pp. 60–90; Blaschko, “Hygiene der Prostitution und
venerischen Krankheiten”, pp. 37, 38.

[429] Op. cit., pp. 600 and 637.

[430] P. 52 (Session 1882), Appendix B.

[431] Op. cit., I, p. 86.

[432] Op. cit., p. 334.

[433] Richelot, op. cit., pp. 664, 665; Acton, op. cit., p. 165;
Pappritz, op. cit., pp. 17, 18.

[434] Tarnowsky, “Prostitution und Abolitionismus”, pp. 108 ff.

[435] Lombroso and Ferrero, “La femme criminelle et la prostituée”, p.
212.

[436] Op. cit., p. 581.

[437] P. 132.

[438] Op. cit., p. 574.

[439] Op. cit., pp. 118, 119.

[440] See some typical examples cited by Dr. Magnan in his report to
the second Congress of Criminal Anthropology: “De l’enfance des
criminels dans les rapports avec la prédisposition naturelle au crime.”
(“Actes,” pp. 60–63.)

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. H. F. Stelzner, “Die
psychopathischen Konstitutionen und ihre sociologische Bedeutung.”]

[441] Commenge, op. cit., p. 107.

[442] Op. cit., I, p. 106.

[443] See further against Lombroso’s theory: R. Calwer, “Die erbliche
Belastung der Prostituirten” (“Neue Zeit”, XII, 2); Hirsch, op. cit.,
pp. 15 ff.; Pappritz, op. cit., pp. 3–6.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. Näcke, “Die Ueberbleibsel der
Lombrosischen kriminalanthropologischen Theorien.”]

[444] See for example Blaschko, “Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”,
p. 9.

[445] “The History of Human Marriage”, pp. 70, 71.

[446] [Note to the American Edition: Notable recent works are: E.
Vandervelde, “Le socialisme et l’alcool” (“Essais socialistes”); E.
Wurm, “Die Alkoholfrage”; A. Pistolese, “Alcoolismo e delinquenza”; and
A. Dix, “Alkoholismus und Arbeiterschaft.”]

[447] The abuse of alcohol is much more extensive than is generally
believed. Dr. Grotjahn gives as the amount that a normal man can take
without being injured by it, 30–45 grams of absolute alcohol, the
amount contained in a liter of beer, or a half-liter of light wine.
(“Der Alkoholismus”, p. 143.)

[448] Pp. 126, 127.

[449] Op. cit., pp. 287, 288.

[450] Op. cit., p. 288.

[451] Holst, “Arbeiders en Alkohol” (“Nieuwe Tijd”, VII), p. 527, and
Grotjahn, op. cit., p. 225.

[452] Verhaeghe, “De l’alcoolisation”, pp. 215, 216.

[453] Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 35–41.

[454] See J. Rae, “Der Achtstunden-Arbeitstag”, pp. 249, 250, where
mention is made of the opposition of public-house keepers in Australia
to the movement for an eight-hour day. Upon the shortening of the day
and the decrease in the use of alcohol, see pp. 96, 107, 108 in the
same work; Lux, “Socialpolitisches Handbuch”, pp. 328–329; Dr. G. M.
den Tex, “Verkorting van den arbeidsdag”, pp. 28, 29, 34, 80, 117–120,
140; “Onmatig lange arbeidstijd en misbruik van sterken drank” (Anon.),
pp. 17–20; Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 288–289; Roland-Holst, op. cit., pp.
530–532; Augagneur, “Les vraies causes et les vrais remèdes de
l’alcoolisme”, pp. 76–77 (“Mouvement Socialiste”, 1900); Verhaeghe, “Le
parti socialiste et la lutte contre l’alcool”, pp. 25–26 (“Mouvement
Socialiste”, 1900).

[455] Given in detail in Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 277–283.

[456] See also Colajanni, “L’alcoolismo”, pp. 153 ff.; Zerboglio,
“L’alcoolisme: causes et remèdes”, pp. 123, 124 (“Devenir Social”,
1895); Vandervelde, op. cit., p. 260, and “Die ökonomischen Faktoren
des Alkoholismus”, pp. 747, 748 (“Neue Zeit”, 1901–1902, I); Verhaeghe,
op. cit., pp. 203–205.

Upon the fact that the abuse of alcohol has consequences much more
injurious for the badly nourished man than for others, see: A. Baer,
“Der Alkoholismus”, p. 286; Colajanni, op. cit., p. 183; Grotjahn, op.
cit., p. 273; Verhaeghe, “De l’alcoolisation”, p. 203.

[457] Colajanni, op. cit., pp. 177, 178; Braun, “Berliner
Wohnungsverhältnisse”, p. 22; Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 290–292;
Verhaeghe, “De l’alcoolisation”, pp. 205–208 and 217; Vandervelde, “Die
ökonomischen Faktoren des Alkoholismus”, p. 747.

[458] P. 533.

[459] Zerboglio, op. cit., p. 125. See also Verhaeghe, “De
l’alcoolisation”, p. 212; Colajanni, op. cit., pp. 181, 182.

[460] See upon this subject Colajanni, op. cit., pp. 168, 169;
Verhaeghe, op. cit., pp. 222, 223; Holst, op. cit., p. 528.

[461] Pp. 75, 76. See also Colajanni, op. cit., pp. 169–173; Grotjahn,
op. cit., pp. 289–298; Verhaeghe, “De l’alcoolisation”, pp. 225–227.

[462] Holst, op. cit., pp. 534, 535.

[463] Kautsky, “Der Alkoholismus und seine Bekämpfung” (“Neue Zeit”,
1890–91, II); Vandervelde, “Het alkoholisme en de arbeidsvoorwaarden in
België,” pp. 268, 271, 272; Holst, op. cit., pp. 528–536.

[464] See, among others, Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 296–298.

[465] “Condition of the Working Class”, pp. 102, 103 [in original pp.
105, 106]. See also: Ducpetiaux, “De la condition physique et morale
des jeunes ouvriers”, I, pp. 352 ff.; Battaglia, “La dinamica del
delitto”, pp. 415–417.

[466] “De la prostitution dans la ville de Paris”, I, p. 139.

[467] “Zur Kenntnis des grossstädtischen Bettel- und Vagabondentums.
Zweiter Beitrag: Prostituirte”, p. 119 (“Zeitsch. f. d. ges. Strw.”,
XXIII). See also: Logan, “The Great Social Evil”, pp. 55–56, 59;
Ladame, “De la prostitution dans ses rapports avec l’alcoolisme, le
crime et la folie”, pp. 7–14; Colajanni, op. cit., p. 179; Lombroso and
Ferrero, “La femme criminelle et la prostituée”, p. 538.

[468] Verhaeghe, “De l’alcoolisation”, p. 211; see also Colajanni, op.
cit., p. 183; and Kautsky, op. cit., p. 50.

[469] Pp. 50, 51. See also Battaglia, op. cit., pp. 418–420, and
Zerboglio, op. cit., p. 125.

[470] “Ergebnisse einer Umfrage über den Alkoholgenuss der Schulkinder
in Nieder-Oesterreich”, p. 82. See also Ducpetiaux, op. cit., pp.
367–370.

[471] See Baer, op. cit., pp. 144, 145; Colajanni, op. cit., pp.
139–142; Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 178, 179; Verhaeghe, “De
l’alcoolisation”, pp. 209–211; Vandervelde, “Die ökonomischen Faktoren
des Alkoholismus”, pp. 741, 742.

[472] Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 300, 301.

[473] Holst, op. cit., p. 530.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further upon alcoholism among the
Jews, Dr. L. Cheinisse, “Die Rassenpathologie und der Alkoholismus bei
den Juden.”]

[474] Vandervelde, “Die ökonomischen Faktoren des Alkoholismus”, pp.
742, 743.

[475] See Zerboglio, op. cit., pp. 125–127; Grotjahn, op. cit., pp.
149–155; Verhaeghe, op. cit., pp. 187–189.

[476] This has actually happened, certain distilleries in the whisky
trust being closed to increase the profits.

[477] See Vandervelde, “Het alcoholisme en de arbeidsvoorwaarden in
België”, p. 268.

[478] See Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 219–221.

[479] See Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 5–12.

[480] Grotjahn, op. cit., p. 9. See also: Hirschfeld, “Die historische
Entwicklung des Alkoholmissbrauchs” (VIII Intern. Cong. gegen den
Alkoholismus).

[481] The assertion that the Germans were addicted to alcohol before
the invasion is erroneous. Agriculture was not sufficiently developed
among these peoples for a regular consumption of alcohol. See Kautsky,
op. cit., pp. 46, 47, and Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 13–15.

[482] See Kautsky, op. cit., p. 47, and Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 20 ff.

[483] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. upon the whole subject of this
chapter: J. Makarewicz, “Einführung in die Philosophie des
Strafrechts.”]

[484] [The author disregards the legal distinction between the words
crime and délit as being “without interest in a sociological work.” The
latter word will appear in this translation as “misdemeanor” or
“offense” according to the context.—Transl.]

[485] See upon this subject: Post, “Die Geschlechtsgenossenschaft der
Urzeit und die Entstehen der Ehe”, p. 156; Steinmetz, “Ethnologische
Studien zur ersten Entwicklung der Strafe”, I, pp. 365 ff.; Makarewicz,
“L’évolution de la peine”, p. 137 (“Archives d’Anthropologie
Criminelle”, XIII). Upon the vengeance of blood see especially Kohler,
“Shakespeare vor dem Forum der Jurisprudenz.”

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. also H. Berkusky, “Die Blutrache”
(“Zeitschr. f. Socialwissenschaft”, XII).]

[486] The so-called offenses of omission are so few and unimportant
that they may be left out of account.

[487] Albrecht, “Actes du Ier congrès d’anthr. crim.”, pp. 110 ff.;
Battaglia, “La dinamica del delitto”, pp. 201, 202; “Genesi e funzione
delle leggi penali”, pp. 211, 212; Manouvrier, “Genèse normale du
crime”, pp. 451, 452 (see also Part One of the present work, on
Manouvrier); Näcke, “Verbrechen und Wahnsinn beim Weibe”, p. 96.

[488] A. H. Post, “Bausteine für eine allgemeine Rechtswissenschaft”,
I, p. 224.

[489] Steinmetz, “L’ethnologie et l’anthropologie criminelle” (“Compte
rendu du Ve Cong. d’anthr. crim.”, p. 105).

[490] It is unnecessary to treat of the origin of punishment. For this
subject the works of Steinmetz and Makarewicz already cited may be
consulted, together with Westermarck’s “Der Ursprung der Strafe”
(“Zeitschrift für Socialwissenschaft”, 1900).

[491] [Note to the American Edition: Recent works of importance are: P.
Kropotkin, “Mutual Aid”; L. T. Hobhouse, “Morals in Evolution”; K.
Kautsky, “Ethik und Materialistische Geschichtsauffassung”; E.
Westermarck, “Ursprung und Entwicklung der Moralbegriffe.”]

[492] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. Ch. Vallon and G.
Genil-Perrin, “Crime et altruisme” (“Archives d’anthr. crim.” XXVIII).]

[493] See, among others, Spencer, “Principles of Sociology”, I, p. 79,
where he says “Sociality, strong in the civilized man, is less strong
in the savage man.”

[494] Chap. iv, pp. 97–99. See also Kautsky, “Die sozialen Triebe in
der Tierwelt” (“Neue Zeit”, 1883); Letourneau, “L’évolution de la
morale”, pp. 59–64; and Kropotkin, “Mutual Aid among Animals”
(“Nineteenth Century”, 1890).

[495] “Eskimo Life”, p. 101.

[496] Op. cit., p. 106.

[497] Op. cit., p. 158.

[498] Op. cit., p. 187.

[499] Op. cit., II, pp. 342, 343.

[500] “Illustrations of the Manners, Customs, and Conditions of the
North American Indians”, pp. 9, 10.

[501] “Ancient Society”, pp. 85, 86.

[502] “Houses and House-life of the American Aborigines.” For the facts
with regard to the North American Indians east of the Rocky Mountains,
see Waitz, op. cit., III, pp. 160 ff.

[503] “The Malay Archipelago”, II, p. 283; see also Waitz, op. cit.,
III; Spencer, “Descriptive Sociology”, No. 6 (“American Races”), pp.
31, 32.

[504] Pp. 225, 226.

[505] “L’ethnologie et l’anthropologie criminelle”, pp. 100, 101.

[506] “Tableau des origines et de l’évolution de la famille et de la
propriété”, p. 56. See also Kautsky, “Die sozialen Triebe in der
Menschenwelt” (“Neue Zeit”, 1884); and Kropotkin, “Mutual Aid among
Savages” (“Nineteenth Century”, 1891), and “Mutual Aid among the
Barbarians” (ibid., 1892).

[507] See Morgan, “Ancient Society”, p. 505.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon the origin of slavery cf. H. J.
Nieboer: “Slavery as an Industrial System.”]

[508] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. Kautsky, op. cit., pp. 99,
100.]

[509] See Maine, op. cit., pp. 227, 228.

[510] P. 50.

[511] See Kautsky, “Die sozialen Triebe in der Menschenwelt”, and also
“Die Indianerfrage” (“Neue Zeit”, 1885) by the same author.

[512] See Steinmetz, “Classification des types sociaux et catalogue des
peuples” (“Année sociologique”, III).

[513] Upon the dualism of ethics see: Kulischer, “Der Dualismus der
Ethik bei den primitiven Völkern” (“Zeitschr. f. Ethnologie”, 1885);
Kropotkin, “Mutual Aid among Savages”, pp. 558, 559; Kovalewsky, “Les
origines du devoir”, pp. 85 ff. (“Revue internationale de sociologie”,
II).

[514] See Sutherland, op. cit., I, x, for example, and compare
Letourneau, “L’évolution de la morale”, p. 55.

[515] In the discussion which follows I have made large use of
Kautsky’s “Die sozialen Triebe in der Tierwelt.”

[516] See Galton, “Inquiries into Human Faculty and its Development”,
pp. 68–82.

[517] See Darwin, “Descent of Man”, p. 102; Sutherland, op. cit., I, x;
Ammon, “Der Ursprung der sozialen Triebe” (“Zeitschr. f.
Socialwissenschaft” IV); H. Schultz, “Altersklassen und Männerbünde”,
I, 2.

[518] See the quotation from Darwin earlier in this section, in which
he speaks of cases of self-sacrifice among animals.

[519] I make great use here of Kautsky’s “Die sozialen Triebe in der
Menschenwelt.”

[520] See Darwin, “Descent of Man”, p. 105.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon the social origin of man see
Müller-Lyer, “Die Familie”, pp. 12 ff.]

[521] “Die sozialen Triebe in der Tierwelt”, p. 27.

[522] See Darwin, “Descent of Man”, pp. 95, 96, 106.

[523] See Maine, “Village Communities”, p. 68.

[524] Dargun, “Egoismus und Altruismus in der Nationalökonomie”, pp.
100, 101.

[525] See Dargun, op. cit., p. 34.

[526] See Letourneau, “L’évolution de la propriété”, pp. 72–75.

[527] See Kropotkin, “Mutual Aid among Savages”, pp. 552, 553; and
Sutherland, op. cit., I, vi.

[528] See Kropotkin, op. cit., pp. 553, 554.

[529] Pp. 335, 336.

[530] Compare Morgan, “Ancient Society”, p. 527.

[531] See Dargun, “Egoismus und Altruismus in der Nationalökonomie”,
pp. 36, 37; Jhering, “Der Zweck im Recht”, I, p. 117.

[532] Lassalle, “Die Feste, die Presse und der Frankfurter
Abgeordnetentag”, II, p. 646; Schäffle, “Bau und Leben des sozialen
Körpers”, I, pp. 461–466, and IV, pp. 68–70; Mandl, “Die Wiener
Presskorruption” (“Neue Zeit”, 1884); Stern, “Einfluss der sozialen
Zustände auf alle Zweige des Kulturlebens”, pp. 33–37.

[533] P. Moreau (of Tours), “L’homicide commis par les enfants”, p. 80;
Cuénoud, “La criminalité à Genève au XIXe siècle”, pp. 93–96; Aubry,
“La contagion du meurtre”, pp. 84–106; “De l’influence contagieuse de
la publicité des faits criminels” (“Archives d’anthropologie
criminelle”, VIII); Ferriani, “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 106, 107
and 282, 283; Lombroso, “Crime, its Causes and Remedies”, pp. 54, 55.

[Note to the American Edition: Besides the influence of the sensational
press, and harmful literature, we must now mention the cinematograph.

From the literature upon the whole subject we select the following: S.
Türkel, “Einfluss der Lektüre auf die Delikte phantastischer
jugendlicher Psychopathen” (“Archiv f. Krim. anthr. u. Krim.” XLII); S.
Sighele, “Littérature et criminalité”, chap. v; M. Homburger, “Der
Einfluss der Schundlitteratur auf jugendliche Verbrecher und
Selbstmörder” (“Monatschr. f. Krim. Psych. und Straf.”, VI); F. Fenton,
“The Influence of Newspaper Presentations upon the Growth of Crime and
Other Anti-social Activity”; A. Hellwig, “Die Beziehungen zwischen
Schundlitteratur, Schundfilms, und Verbrechen” (“Archiv f. Krim. anthr.
u. Krim.”, LI); Meyer, “Schundlitteratur und Schundfilm” (“Arch. f.
Krim. anthr. u. Krim.”, LIII).]

[534] P. 242.

[535] “Fürsorgeerziehung” (Woche V, No. 51).

[536] From “Crimineele Statistiek” for the years given, and “Uitkomsten
der achtste tienjaarlijksche volkstelling” and “Uitkomsten der
beroepstelling van 1899.”

[537] This number is below the reality; they have classed among persons
without trade those whose trade was unknown.

[538] [Note to the American Edition: For North America cf. Fehlinger,
“Erwerbsarbeit und Kriminalität von Kindern u. Frauen in den
Vereinigten Staaten.”]

[539] See “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1898”, I, pp. 52 ff., and
“Notizie complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali degli anni
1890–1895”, pp. xlix, l.

[540] [Note to the American Edition: For Germany the
“Kriminalstatistik” of 1891, 1901, and 1902 contain data upon this
point; see II, p. 32. For Austria, cf. Herz, “Verbrechen und
Verbrechertum in Oesterreich”, pp. 121 ff.]

[541] “Die berufliche und soziale Gliederung des Deutschen Volkes nach
der Berufszählung vom 14 Juni, 1895” (“Stat. des Deutschen Reichs. Neue
Folge”, Band 111).

[542] Op. cit., pp. 143 and 144.

[543] “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1896. Erläuterungen”, I, pp. 22,
23.

[544] [Note to the American Edition: Juvenile criminality in Germany
increased up to 1906, when a fairly regular decrease began. The law
upon the “Fürsorgeerziehung” dates from the beginning of the century.]

[545] Calculated from the work cited, I, pp. 18–21.

[546] “Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich”, 1896, p. 5.

[547] Morrison, “Juvenile Offenders”, p. 5.

[548] [Note to the American Edition: According to recent statistics
juvenile delinquency in England has decreased rather than increased.]

[549] “Judicial Statistics, England and Wales, Part I, Criminal
Statistics, 1899”, p. 64.

[550] The “Summary Jurisdiction Act” gives the English judges the right
not to convict, even though the proof may be sufficient, when they deem
the offense not grave enough. 20% of those so discharged are added to
the figures to allow for this.

[551] Op. cit., p. 65.

[552] P. L., “Die Ergebnisse der Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate
vertretenen Königreichen und Ländern im Jahre 1899.”

[553] [Note to the American Edition: After the period cited juvenile
crime in Austria has increased further. Cf. Herz, op. cit., pp. 107 ff.
See also Hoegel, “Die Grenzen der Kriminalstatistik”, pp. 414 ff.]

[554] Op. cit., pp. l–li.

[555] Calculated from “Administration de la Justice criminelle et
civile de la Belgique, période de 1881–1885. Résumé statistique”, p.
81.

[Note to the American Edition: In Belgium no criminal statistics
appeared from 1886 to 1897. For the period after 1898 see Jacquart, “La
criminalité belge.” Here there appears rather a decrease than an
increase of juvenile delinquency for this period.]

[556] Figured from p. cix, Table No. 3 of the “Rapport sur
l’administration de la justice criminelle de 1881 à 1900.” (Compte
général de l’administration de la justice criminelle pendant l’année
1900.)

[557] Figured from op. cit., p. cxvi, Table No. 8.

[558] See Grosmolard, “Criminalité juvénile” (“Archives d’anthr.
crim.”, XVIII), and Albanel, “Le crime dans la famille”, p. 194.

[559] [Note to the American Edition: Upon France cf. especially Dr. G.
Jacquetty, “Étude statistique de la criminalité juvénile en France.”
According to this study the crimes of minors under 16 years of age have
remained stationary as regards crimes against persons, and have
decreased as regards crimes against property; misdemeanors, however,
have increased. The crimes committed by minors between 16 and 20 have
remained the same in comparison with the criminality of adults; on the
other hand there has been a constant increase of misdemeanors. The
increase of crimes and misdemeanors of violence committed at this age
has been considerable. See also: G. L. Duprat, “La criminalité dans
l’adolescence.”]

[560] According to the “Compte Général de l’administration de la
justice criminelle pendant l’année 1900”, p. 32, Table XVI.

[561] According to op. cit., p. 54, Table XXIX.

[562] “Statistica giudiziaria penale per l’anno 1899”, p. cxvii.

[563] “Notizie complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali degli
anni 1890–1895”, p. xli. In the period from 1896–1900 juvenile
criminality increased further in a striking manner.

[564] Op. cit., p. xlvii.

[565] I have not been able to get data for the United States. The
American criminologist, A. Drähms, says that the criminality of the
young is increasing in the United States (“The Criminal”, p. 279), and
W. D. Morrison makes a similar statement (“Juvenile Offenders”, p. 17).

[566] From “De Gerechtelijke Statistiek van het Koninkrijk der
Nederlanden” for the years 1896 to 1899, and from “Bijdragen tot de
Statistiek van Nederland, Nieuwe volgreeks XVII, XXVII. Crimineele
statistiek over de jaren 1900 en 1901.”

[567] Taken from “Crimineele Statistiek over het jaar 1901.” In the
criminal statistics of the Netherlands the system was changed in 1901.
Before this year convictions were counted, and from that year on,
individuals convicted.

[568] See also Ducpetiaux, “De la condition physique et morale des
jeunes ouvriers”, Bk. I, ch. 2; Starke, “Verbrechen und Verbrecher in
Preussen”, pp. 210, 211; Ferriani, “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 144
ff., 177–185; “Entartete Mütter” and “Schlaue und glückliche
Verbrecher”, pp. 443, 444, 458–475; Agahd, “Die Erwerbsthätigkeit
schulpflichtiger Kinder im Deutschen Reiche” (“Archiv für soziale
Gesetzgebung und Statistik”, XII); Struntz, “Die erwerbsmässige
Kinderarbeit und die Schule” (“Neue Zeit”, 1898–1899, I); Dix, “Die
Jugendlichen in der Sozial- und Kriminalpolitik”; Albanel, “Le crime
dans la famille”, pp. 41–43; Aschaffenburg, “Das Verbrechen und seine
Bekämpfung”, pp. 119–123; Joly, “L’enfance coupable”, pp. 24, 25, 126.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. the following recent works:
Baernreither, op. cit., passim; P. Pollitz, “Die Psychologie des
Verbrechers”, pp. 112 ff.; Duprat, op. cit., pp. 125 ff.; M. Homburger,
“Ueber den Zusammenhang zwischen den Zahlen der in den Fabriken
beschäftigten Personen unter 18 Jahren und der Zahl der Verbrechen
solcher Personen”; H. W. Gruhle, “Die Ursachen der jugendlichen
Verwahrlosung und Kriminalität”, pp. 104 ff.]

[569] See also Engels, “The Condition of the Working Class in England,”
pp. 118, 119.

[570] See: Brace, “The Dangerous Classes of New York”, pp. 51 ff.; O.
S., “Die Verbrecherwelt von Berlin”, pp. 120 ff. (“Zeitschr. f. d.
gesammte Strafrechtswissenschaft”, V); Földes, “Einige Ergebnisse der
neueren Kriminalstatistik”, p. 548 (ibid., XI); Lux, “Sozialpolitisches
Handbuch”, pp. 58 ff.; Philippovich, “Wiener Wohnungsverhältnisse”, p.
264 (“Archiv für soziale Gesetzgebung und Statistik”, VI); Dix,
“Sozial-Moral”, pp. 15–18; Ferriani, “Schlaue und glückliche
Verbrecher”, pp. 444 ff.; Liszt, “Das Verbrechen als
sozial-pathologische Erscheinung”, p. 22; Th. Holmes, “Pictures and
Problems from London Police Courts”, pp. 70 ff.; Albanel, op. cit., pp.
11 ff.; Aschaffenburg, op. cit., p. 115.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. Baernreither, op. cit., passim.]

[571] P. 10.

[572] P. 12.

[573] P. 12.

[574] See Laspeyres, pp. 86–91.

[575] Laspeyres, op. cit., pp. 19 and 21.

[576] See Engels, “Condition of the Working Class in England”, pp. 76
ff.

[577] “Condition of the Working Class in England”, p. 116.

[578] For the different opinions see Dr. L. DelBaere, “De invloed van
opvoeding en onderwijs op de criminaliteit”, pp. 23 ff., and Földes,
“Einige Ergebnisse der neueren Kriminalstatistik”, pp. 552–559
(“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.” XI).

[579] The figures for prisoners are from Drähms, “The Criminal”, p. 74;
those in the last column from “The Statesman’s Year-Book”, 1902, p.
1203.

[580] From “Die Ergebnisse der Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate
vertretenen Königreichen und Ländern im Jahre 1899”, p. xlviii.

[581] Taken from the “Judicial Statistics of England and Wales”, Part
I, Criminal Statistics, 1894–1900. The last two columns are taken from
“The Statesman’s Year-Book”, 1892, p. 39.

[582] Figured from the table F. A II of the “Ergebnisse der
Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate vertretenen Königreichen und
Ländern”, 1899. The number of illiterates in the total population 16
and over, was about 24%.

[583] Taken from Jacquart, op. cit., p. 104.

[584] “Statesman’s Year Book”, 1910, p. 31.

[585] The last two columns are taken from “l’Annuaire Statistique de la
France,” xvi ff.; the others from the “Statistique pénitentiaire,”
1882–1898.

[586] From 1886 to 1891 women and men are reported together under this
heading.

[587] After Table XXIV of the “Report of the Judicial Statistics of
Scotland for the Year 1910.”

[588] “Rapport sur l’administration de la justice criminelle de 1881 à
1900.”

[589] “Judicial Statistics, Ireland”, 1905, I, “Criminal Statistics,”
p. 24.

[590] The last two columns are taken from the “Annuario Statistico
Italiano”, 1900, p. 214; the others from the “Statistica giudiziaria
penale”, 1881 to 1889.

[591] Men playing a larger part in crime than women, I have thought it
well to give the figures for illiterate men also.

[592] Figured from Table XXVIII of the “Statistica giudiziaria penale”,
1889.]

[593] From the “Year-Book of the New York State Reformatory”, for the
years in question. In “The Dangerous Classes of New York” (p. 32),
Brace mentions that in 1870 about 31% of the adult criminals in the
State of New York were illiterate, while of the adult non-criminals of
the population only 6.08% were illiterate.

[594] Taken from the “Jaarcijfers voor het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden.
Rijk in Europa”, 1901, p. 47.

[595] de Roos, op. cit., p. 108.

[596] Figured from Table II of the “Crimineele Statistiek”, 1900.

[597] Evert, “Zur Statistik rückfälliger Verbrecher in Preussen”
(“Zeitschr. des Kön. Preuss. Stat. Bureaus”, XXXIX), p. 197; the last
figure from “Stat. Jahrb. f. d. Deutsche Reich”, 1896, 1897, and 1898.

[598] “Die Ergebnisse der Schweizerischen Kriminalstatistik während der
Jahre 1892–1896”, p. 38 (“Schweizerische Statistik”, Pt. 125).

[599] Ibid.

[600] [Note to the American Edition: Upon the Balkan states see Wadler,
op. cit., pp. 176 ff.]

[601] Taken from “Statistica giudiziaria penale”, 1887, 1888, 1889.

[602] Figured from Table XXVIII of the “Statistica giudiziaria penale”,
1889.

[603] From “Die Ergebnisse der Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate
vertretenen Königreichen und Ländern im Jahre 1899”, p. xlviii.

[604] Figured from Table F. a. II in “Die Ergebnisse der
Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate vertretenen Königreichen und
Ländern im Jahre 1899.”

[605] [“Fortune” here has not exactly the connotation of our English
word, but as “money” and “property” would be equally inexact it seems
better to keep the author’s term. Transl.]

[606] [Note to the American Edition: Upon Austria cf. Herz, op. cit.,
pp. 8 ff.]

[607] Figured from the table on p. 199 of Evert’s “Zur Statistik
rückfälliger Verbrecher in Preussen.”

[608] From “Die Ergebnisse der Schweizerischen Kriminalstatistik
während der Jahre 1892–1896”, p. 37.

[609] Concerning Hungary Prof. Földes says (without giving the year)
that 92% of the crimes are committed by persons without fortune, while
these represent only 85% of the population in general (“Einige
Ergebnisse der neueren Kriminalstatistik”, Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.,
XI, p. 545).

[Note to the American Edition: Upon the Balkan States cf. Wadler, op.
cit., pp. 164 ff.]

[610] Taken from Prinzing, “Soziale Faktoren der Kriminalität”
(Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw. XXII). The figures for criminality are
the average figures for the years 1894–1896. The figures for the
occupations are those of the census of occupations of June 14, 1895.

[611] Servants only.

[612] Taken from “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1896” (Erläuterungen)
II, pp. 38, 39.

[613] This category includes the unskilled workmen, as the author of
this table says himself, this heading is not very exact, since it
includes those who without following a fixed occupation call themselves
working-men.

[Note to the American Edition: The “Kriminalstatistik 1908” gives the
statistics of the criminality of the different occupations, figured
from the census of occupations of 1907.]

[614] Pp. 585, 586.

[615] Figured from the “Judicial Statistics, England and Wales, Pt. I
Criminal Statistics”, 1894–1900.

[Note to the American Edition: The English Criminal Statistics for 1905
contain a table upon the occupations of prisoners convicted during the
years 1896–1905.]

[616] From the “Rapport au Président de la république française sur
l’administration de la justice criminelle de 1881 à 1900”, p. xxvi.

[617] From the “Statistique pénitentiaire”, 1890–1895.

[618] Furnishing trade only.

[619] Vagrants and prostitutes.

[620] “Notizie complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali degli
anni 1890–1895”, p. lxi. As the calculations are based upon the census
of 1881 the accuracy of the table is not absolute.

[621] Op. cit., p. lxxxii.

[622] Op. cit., pp. lxxxiii–lxxxiv.

[623] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. the recent works upon the
relation between occupation and criminality: for Germany:
Aschaffenburg, op. cit., pp. 56 ff.; H. Lindenau, “Beruf und
Verbrechen”; Peterselie, op. cit., pp. 106 ff.; Wassermann, “Beruf,
Konfession, und Verbrechen”; Galle, op. cit., pp. 93 ff.; Stöwesand,
op. cit., pp. 99 ff.; for Austria: Hoegel, op. cit., pp. 449 ff.; and
pp. 134 ff.; for the Balkan States: Wadler, op. cit., pp. 137 ff.; for
the Netherlands: de Roos, op. cit., pp. 132 ff.; Verrijn Stuart, op.
cit. II, pp. 244 ff.; for France: G. Bertrin, “De la criminalité en
France dans les congrégations, le clergé et les principales
professions.”]

[624] “Die Ergebnisse der Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate
vertretenen Königreichen und Ländern im Jahre 1899”, p. lxviii.

[625] Prinzing, “Der Einfluss der Ehe auf die Kriminalität des Mannes”,
p. 41; and “Die Erhöhung der Kriminalität des Weibes durch die Ehe”
(“Zeitschrift f. Sozialwissenschaft”, II), p. 437.

[626] “Notizie complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali degli
anni 1890–1895”, p. lii.

[627] “Rapport au Président de la République française sur
l’administration de la justice criminelle de 1881–1900”, p. xxiii.

[628] Figured from “Uitkomsten der achtste tienjaarlijksche
volkstelling”, and the “Gerechtelijke Statistiek over 1899.”

[629] “Die Ergebnisse der Schweizerischen Kriminalstatistik während der
Jahre 1892–1896”, p. 21.

[630] Prinzing, “Soziale Faktoren der Kriminalität”, pp. 556–557.

[631] “Der Einfluss der Ehe auf die Kriminalität des Mannes”, p. 42.

[632] Op. cit., p. 117. The figures for criminality are the average
figures for the years 1882–1893. They all give the number to 100,000
persons of each category.

[633] Op. cit., p. 117.

[634] Op. cit., p. 119.

[635] Op. cit., p. 111.

[636] Op. cit., p. 112.

[637] Op. cit., p. 109.

[638] Op. cit., p. 113.

[639] Op. cit., p. 114.

[640] Op. cit., p. 114.

[641] Prinzing, “Soziale Faktoren der Kriminalität”, p. 559.

[642] “Die Erhöhung der Kriminalität des Weibes durch die Ehe”, p. 437.

[643] This table and those which follow all belong to the period from
1882 to 1893, and are figured for 100,000 of each category. They are
taken from the work cited, pp. 438–444.

[644] [“Rebellion” has a wider significance in French than in English,
any violence to public officials being so designated. The word is
retained, however, for brevity.—Transl.]

[645] Cf. F. Prinzing, “Ueber frühzeitige Heiraten, deren Vorzüge und
Nachteile.” See also Durkheim, “Le suicide”, pp. 186 ff.

[646] P. 40.

[647] Note to the American Edition: Cf. the following recent works upon
the relation between marriage and criminality: for Germany:
Aschaffenburg, op. cit., pp. 139 ff.; Pollitz, op. cit., pp. 34 ff.;
for Austria: Hoegel, op. cit., pp. 16 ff.; Herz, op. cit., pp. 127 ff.;
for the Balkan States: Wadler, op. cit., pp. 128 ff.; for Belgium:
Jacquart, op. cit., pp. 80 ff.; for the Netherlands: de Roos, op. cit.,
pp. 122 ff. See further N. Muller, “Biografisch-aetiologisch onderzoek
over occidivie, etc.”

[648] “Kriminalstatistik f. d. Jahr 1896”, Erläuterungen, II, p. 33.

[649] [Note to the American Edition: The “Kriminalstatistik für das
Jahr 1903” contains very important data bearing upon the period
1882–1902, with regard to feminine criminality in Germany.]

[650] “Judicial Statistics, England and Wales, Pt. I, Criminal
Statistics, 1899”, p. 55, with separate calculations made for 1900.

[651] “The Statesman’s Yearbook, 1902”, p. 14.

[652] “Judicial Statistics, England and Wales, Criminal Statistics,
1894”, p. 19.

[653] “Die Ergebnisse der Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate
vertretenen Königreichen und Ländern im Jahre 1899”, p. xlix.

[654] “Rapport au président de la république française sur
l’administration de la justice criminelle de 1881–1900”, pp. xix, cxvi.

[655] Figured from “Compte général de l’administration de la justice
criminelle pendant l’année 1900”, pp. 30–31.

[656] Op. cit., pp. 54–62, Tab. XXIX.

[657] For the years 1884–1889 taken from the “Statistica giudiziaria
penale per l’anno 1889”, and for the years following from the “Notizie
complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali degli anni 1890–95.”

[658] The fact that a new penal code went into effect in 1890 makes a
noticeable change in the total figures.

[659] Op. cit., p. xxxvii.

[660] “Statesman’s Year Book”, 1910, p. 948.

[661] Taken from “de Gerechtelijke Statistiek van het Koninkrijk der
Nederlanden”, 1896–1899, and “de Crimineele Statistiek”, 1900. For more
detailed information upon the Netherlands see Loosjes, “Bijdrage tot de
studie van de criminaliteit der vrouw”, pp. 8–30.

[662] Figured from “Crimineele statistiek over het jaar 1901.”

[663] “Criminal Statistics, 1899”, p. 27. See in the same place the
reason for thinking that the figures quoted for the number of women
acquitted are too small. Morrison says that in England one woman in
four is acquitted, and one man in six. (“Juvenile Offenders”, p. 46.)

[664] “Rapport”, etc., p. xxxiv.

[665] Op. cit., p. lvi.

[666] See Colajanni, “Sociologia criminale”, II, p. 83; Földes, op.
cit., pp. 630, 631; and Morrison, op. cit., p. 46.

[667] “Criminal Statistics of England and Wales, 1899”, p. 54.

[668] Loosjes, op. cit., p. 50.

[669] Figured from Tables 23 and 24 of the “Rapport au président de la
république française”, etc.

[Note to the American Edition: Wadler tells us that in Servia the
percentage of feminine criminality is between 3.71 (1893) and 6.25
(1903); in Greece, about 2 (1899–1902); in Bulgaria, about 3.2
(1899–1906); in Bosnia and Herzegovina, between 5.07 (1899) and 6.69
(1902) (op. cit., pp. 94, 102–104). In Rumania, Minovici tells us, the
percentage is 2.42 (1874–1890).]

[670] “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1898”, II, p. 73.

[671] “Juvenile Offenders”, p. 47.

[672] “Die Straffälligkeit des Weibes”, p. 253 (Archiv f. Krim. Anthr.
u. Kriminalstatistik, V).

[673] Galicia, Western and Eastern separately.

[674] Tyrol and Vorarlberg separately.

[675] From “Kriminalstatistik”, 1888, 1894, 1896, 1898, and 1900.

[676] “Die Ergebnisse, etc.”, p. xlviii.

[677] [Note to the American Edition: Wadler points out that in the
Balkan States the percentage of feminine criminality is rapidly
increasing.]

[678] See Loosjes, op. cit., pp. 11, 12.

[679] See Loosjes, op. cit., p. 12, where he demonstrates that the
decrease in the percentage of female criminality is in great measure
due to the diminution of mendicity.

[Note to the American Edition: French and German statistics bearing
upon a long period show that the economic criminality of woman tends to
decrease, and that against persons to increase. The last fact
corresponds, therefore, with the thesis that the social situation of
woman explains her criminality. The first fact is explained perhaps by
the decrease of poverty resulting from the greater participation of
woman in the economic life.]

[680] For opinions of other authors see Loosjes, op. cit., pp. 75–108.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon feminine criminality in general see
further the following recent works: for Germany: Aschaffenburg, op.
cit., pp. 135 ff.; Wulffen, op. cit., I, pp. 402 ff., and II, pp. 258
ff.; O. Mönkemöller, “Korrektionsanstalt und Landarmenhaus”; Galle, op.
cit., pp. 68 ff.; Stöwesand, op. cit., pp. 23 ff.; Sauer, op. cit., pp.
57 ff. For Austria: Herr, “Die Kriminalität des Weibes nach den
Ergebnissen der neueren österreichischen Statistik” (“Archiv f. Krim.
anthr. u. Krim.”, XVIII), and op. cit., pp. 78 ff.; Hoegel, op. cit.,
pp. 410 ff. For the Balkan States: Wadler, op. cit., pp. 93 ff. For
Belgium: Jacquart, op. cit., pp. 67 ff. For France: C. Granier, “La
femme criminelle”; de Lanessan, op. cit., pp. 145 ff.; H. Lacaze, “De
la criminalité féminine en France”; H. Leale, “De la criminalité des
sexes” (“Archives d’anthr. crim.”, XXV). For the Netherlands: de Roos,
op. cit., pp. 76 ff.; Verrijn Stuart, op. cit., pp. 190 ff. For
Rumania: Minovici, op. cit. Upon female criminality in relation to
special occupations, see: R. de Rijcken, “La servante criminelle”.]

[681] Liszt, “Die gesellschaftlichen Ursachen des Verbrechens”. (See
discussion of this work in Pt. I of the present work.)

[682] P. 96, chap. IV.

[683] “Nos jeunes détenus”, pp. 24, 25.

[684] See what is said in criticism of Professor Ferri in Pt. I of this
work.

[685] “Schlaue und glückliche Verbrecher”, p. 34. See the whole section
“L’hypocrisie dans l’éducation” (pp. 29–49), where the author
criticises contemporary education severely.

[686] See Corre, “Crime et Suicide”, pp. 327, 328, and Ferriani,
“Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 284–295, 372, 373.

[687] There are other reasons for this, of course, besides better
education: the absence of poverty, pleasures within easy reach, etc.

[688] Taken from Morrison, “Juvenile Offenders”, p. 160.

[689] Morrison, op. cit., p. 159.

[690] Figured from “L’annuaire statistique de la France”, V–IX.

[691] Figured from the “Statistique pénitentiaire,” 1890–1895.

[692] Raux (“Nos jeunes détenus”) and Grosmolard (“Criminalité
juvénile”, p. 199) come to the same conclusion.

[693] “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 76 and 440.

[694] Plasz, “Fürsorgeerziehung” (Woche V, No. 51). According to the
statistics upon the “Fürsorgeerziehung” there were between 1901 and
1906 among the parents of the children on an average: 7.1% without
income, 71.5% with an income under 900 marks, 14.1% with an income
between 900 and 3000 marks, 0.1% between 3000 and 6000 marks, and 7.2%
with income unknown. See F. Frank, “Das Fürsorgeerziehungsgesetz in
Preussen” (“Neue Zeit”, XXVII, p. 460).

[695] L. Braun, “Die Frauenfrage”, pp. 279–280.

[696] Op. cit., p. 320.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. W. Feld, “Die Kinder der in Fabriken
arbeitenden Frauen und ihre Verpflegung.”

[697] Braun, op. cit., p. 278.

[698] See Ducpetiaux, “De la condition physique et morale des jeunes
ouvriers”, pp. 199 ff., and Corre, “Crime et Suicide”, pp. 330–332.

[699] Op. cit., p. 9.

[700] In the following list I do not give the statistics for Germany as
a whole, as I have been able to procure them for certain states, only.
For Germany see: Näcke, “Verbrechen und Wahnsinn beim Weibe”, pp. 161,
162; von Liszt, “Das Verbrechen als sozial-pathologische Erscheinung”,
pp. 22, 23; W. Rein, “Jugendliches Verbrecherthum” (“Zeitschr. f.
Socialwissenschaft”, III); H. Wetzker, “Die Zunahme der Verbrechen”;
Aschaffenburg, op. cit., pp. 107–116; see also the section on Hirsch in
Pt. I of this work.

[Note to the American Edition: Besides the works of Neumann, Spann,
Pollitz, and Rühle, already cited, the following recent publications
must be named: Mönkemöller, “Zur Kriminalität des Kindesalters”
(“Archiv f. Krim. Anthrop. u. Kriminalstatistik”, XL); H. W. Gruhle,
“Die Ursachen der jugendlichen Verwahrlosung und Kriminalität”; A.
Hamburger, “Lebensschicksale geisteskranker Strafgefangener”.]

[701] “Statistisches Uebersicht der Verhältnisse der Oesterreichischen
strafanstalten und der Gerichtsgefängnisse”, 1883 and 1884, Table IV
and IVa.

[702] “Die Ergebnisse der Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate
vertretenen Königreichen und Ländern”, 1896 and 1899.

[703] Mayr, “Statistik und Gesellschaftslehre”, II, p. 197.

[704] Mayr, op. cit., p. 282. [Note to the American Edition: Upon
Austria, cf. Baernreither, op. cit.]

[705] J. S., “Zur Verwahrlosung der Kinder in der kapitalistischen
Gesellschaft” (“Neue Zeit”, 1893–94, II).

[706] Mayr, “Statistik und Gesellschaftslehre”, II, p. 197.

[707] Morrison, “Juvenile Offenders”, pp. 122–147.

[708] Tönnies, “Jugendliche Kriminalität und Verwahrlosung in
Gross-Britannien”, p. 904 (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.”, XIII).

[709] Morrison, op. cit., pp. 148–151.

[710] W. H. Douglas, “The Criminal; Some Social and Economic Aspects”,
p. 106 (“Proceedings of the Royal Philosophical Society of Glasgow”,
vol. XXXIII, 1901–1902).

[711] Lenz, “Die Zwangserziehung in England”, p. 38.

[712] With regard to England see also: L. Gordon Rylands, “Crime, its
Causes and Remedy”, pp. 18–19, 37–42.

[713] Figured from the “Statistique pénitentiaire”, 1890–1895.

[714] Mayr, op. cit., p. 197.

[715] Mayr, op. cit., p. 282.

[716] A. von Oettingen says that in 1864 there were in France, out of
8,006 young prisoners, 60% who were illegitimate children or orphans,
and 38.5% who were descended from criminals, vagrants, and prostitutes
(“Moralstatistik”, p. 335).

[717] P. 17.

[718] Op. cit., p. 48.

[719] Op. cit., p. 201.

[720] Joly, “L’enfance coupable”, p. 37. See the whole of chap. III.

[721] “Le crime dans la famille”, pp. 27, 38.

[722] Motet, “De l’éducation correctionnelle”, p. 186 (“Actes du IIe
Congrès d’anthropologie criminelle”).

[723] Raux, op. cit., p. 181.

[724] Raux, op. cit., p. 211. See also the following authors with
regard to France: Joly, “La France criminelle”, Ch. VI; Corre, “Crime
et Suicide”, pp. 485–490; Tomel and Rollet, “Les enfants en prison”;
and Aubry, “La Contagion du meurtre”, pp. 17–51.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: Duprat and de Lanessan, op.
cit.; E. Laurent, “La criminalité infantile”; L. Manouvrier, “Quelques
cas de criminalité juvénile et commençante” (“Archives d’anthr. crim.”
XXVII); E. Martin, “Études sur l’enfance coupable” (“Archives d’anthr.
crim.” XXVIII).]

[725] Lenz, op. cit., p. 70.

[726] From Colajanni, “Sociologia criminale”, II, p. 107, and the
“Statistica giudiziaria penale per l’anno 1889”, p. CXV.

[727] “Annuario statistico italiano 1900”, p. 95.

[728] Mayr, op. cit., p. 282.

[729] P. 164.

[730] P. 76.

[731] “I caratteri dei delinquenti”, pp. 237 and 250. For Italy see
also: Carrara, “Les petits criminels de Cagliari” (“Compte rendu du Ve
Congrès d’anthropologie criminelle”).

[732] Figured from “Gerechtelijke Statistiek van het Koningrijk der
Nederlanden”, 1896, 1897, 1898, and 1899, and “Crimineele Statistiek”,
1900 and 1901.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further the work of de Roos already
cited, pp. 117 ff. Dr. J. P. F. A. Noorduijn, “De Observatie, na de
invoering der Kinderwetten, etc.” (“Tijdschrift v. Strafrecht”, XXIII),
and J. Feith, “Misdadige Kinderen”.]

[733] Mayr, op. cit., p. 197.

[734] Mayr, op. cit., p. 282.

[735] P. 85.

[736] See Drähms, “The Criminal”, Ch. XI.

[737] “Beretning om Rigets Strafarbeidsanstalter for 1897–1898,
1898–1899”, and for 1899–1900 from Weinberg, “Der werdende Verbrecher”,
p. 16. (“Neue Zeit”, 1902–1903, II).

[738] Mayr, op. cit., p. 197.

[739] Mayr, op. cit., p. 282.

[740] Aschaffenburg, op. cit., p. 105.

[741] Mayr, op. cit., pp. 197 and 282.

[742] Based on Evert, “Zur Statistik rückfälliger Verbrecher in
Preussen.”

[743] “Die Ergebnisse der Schweizerischen Kriminalstatistik während der
Jahre 1892–1896”, p. 34.

[744] Mayr, op. cit., p. 282.

[745] “Die Ergebnisse etc.”, pp. 35, 37, 38.

[746] Weinberg, op. cit., p. 19.

[747] Mayr, op. cit., p. 283. The other data are taken from Sichart,
“Ueber individuelle Faktoren des Verbrechens.” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
Strafrw.” X.)

[748] P. 298.

[749] P. 10.

[750] Richelot, “La Prostitution en Angleterre”, p. 571.

[751] Mayr, “Statistik der gerichtlichen Polizei im Königreiche Bayern
und in einigen anderen Ländern”, Table CXVIII.

[752] Parent-Duchatelet, “De la prostitution dans la ville de Paris”,
II, p. 612.

[Note to the American Edition: The “Criminal Statistics, Ireland”
(1905) even gives a percentage as high as 38.5, of prostitutes among
female prisoners (p. 25).]

[753] G. S., “Die weibliche Lohnarbeit und ihr Einfluss auf die
Sittlichkeit und Kriminalität”, p. 751 (“Neue Zeit”, 1899–1900, II).

[754] After “Notizie complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali
degli anni 1890–95.”

[755] P. 173.

[756] See further: Parent-Duchatelet, op. cit., pp. 139–142; Faucher,
“Études sur l’Angleterre”, I, pp. 77, 78; C. L. Brace, “The Dangerous
Classes in New York”, pp. 116, 117; “Einiges über die Prostitution in
Gegenwart und Zukunft”, p. 519 (“Neue Zeit”, 1891–92, I); Commenge, “La
prostitution clandestine à Paris”, pp. 29–131; Blaschko, “Die
Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”, pp. 27, 28.

[757] Upon “souteneurs” and the part they play in crime see:
Parent-Duchatelet, op. cit., I, Chap. II, § 12; Frégier, “Les classes
dangereuses”, I, pp. 168–170; Ladame, “De la prostitution dans ses
rapports avec l’alcoolisme, le crime, et la folie”, p. 16; Sichart,
“Ueber individuelle Faktoren des Verbrechens”, p. 44; Baumgarten, op.
cit., pp. 17–19; Stursberg, “Die Prostitution in Deutschland und ihre
Bekämpfung”, pp. 76–82.

[Note to the American Edition: See further Hermann, op. cit., pp. 68
ff.; Brusse, op. cit.; and H. Ostwald, “Das Zuhältertum in Berlin”.]

[758] P. 138. See also: Engels, “Der Ursprung der Familie, des
Privateigenthums und des Staats”, p. 63; Stursberg, op. cit., pp. 28,
29; Faure, “Souvenirs de la Roquette”, p. 360; Baumgarten, op. cit., p.
20; Blaschko, op. cit., pp. 28, 29.

Upon the relation between prostitution and criminality in general see:
Moreau-Christophe, “Du problème de la misère”, III, pp. 167–170;
Richelot, op. cit., pp. 610–615; Avé-Lallemant, “Das Deutsche
Gaunerthum”, II, pp. 28, 29, and 336, III, pp. 157 and 165; Oettingen,
“Moralstatistik”, pp. 224–232; Ladame, op. cit., pp. 15 ff.; Lombroso
and Ferrero, “La femme criminelle et la prostituée”, pp. 535–538.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further the recent studies: A. H.
Hübner, “Ueber Prostituirte und ihre strafrechtliche Behandlung”
(“Monatschr. f. krim. Psych. und Strafrechtsreform”, III); O.
Mönkemöller, “Die Kriminalität der Korrigendin” (“Monatschr.” etc. V)
and “Korrektionsanstalt und Landarmenhaus”, ch. III.]

[759] See among others: Krauss, “Die Psychologie des Verbrechens”, pp.
68, 69; Grotjahn, “Der Alkoholismus”, p. 87.

[760] “L’alcoolisme dans ses rapports avec la criminalité”, pp. 411,
413, 415 (“Bulletin de l’académie royale de médecine de Belgique”,
1896).

[761] “La prophylaxie et le traitement du criminel récidiviste”, p.64
(“Compte rendu Ve congrès d’anthropologie criminelle”).

[762] Löffler, “Alkohol und Verbrechen”, p. 511 (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
Strafrw.” XXIII).

[763] Dalhoff, “Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la
criminalité”, pp. 40, 41. (“Actes du Congrès pénitentiaire internat. de
Bruxelles”, IV.)

[764] For the years 1858–1862 taken from Mayr, “Statistik der
gerichtlichen Polizei im Königreiche Bayern und in einigen anderen
Ländern”, Tab. CXVIII; and for the other years from “Criminal
Statistics”, 1894–1897.

[765] In these tables the term “drinker” is used for one who drinks to
excess.

[766] Upon England see further: L. Gordon Rylands, “Crime, its Causes
and Remedy”, pp. 17, 20–22; J. Baker, “Rapport sur l’influence de
l’alcoolisme sur la criminalité”, and W. C. Sullivan, id. (“Actes du
Cong. pén. internat. de Brux.” 1900, IV).

[Note to the American Edition: The “Report on the Judicial Statistics
of Scotland for the year 1908” contains data upon criminality and
alcoholism.]

[767] “Actes,” p. 112.

[768] “Actes”, p. 106. See also upon France: Laurent, “Les habitués des
prisons de Paris”, pp. 297 ff.; Corre, “Crime et suicide”, pp. 182 ff.,
and Verhaeghe, “De l’alcoolisation”, p. 144.

[Note to the American Edition: See also the “Compte général de
l’administration de la justice criminelle pendant l’année 1907”, pp. xx
ff.]

[769] “Der Alcoholismus”, p. 348.

[770] Op. cit., p. 351.

[771] “Ein Beitrag zur Kenntnis des grossstädtischen Bettel- und
Vagabondentums” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.” XXI).

[772] “I caratteri dei delinquenti”, p. 296.

[773] [Note to the American Edition: “The criminal statistics of the
Netherlands for 1904” contain data upon the subject in question. Cf.
further de Roos, op. cit., pp. 175 ff., and “Parallelismen tusschen
alcoholisme en criminaliteit” (“Tijdschrift v. Strafrecht”, XXIII);
Verrijn Stuart, op. cit., pp. 204 ff.; A. Ariëns, “Criminaliteit en
drankmisbruik.”]

[774] P. 66.

[775] “The Jukes”, p. 85.

[776] Evert, “Zur Statistik rückfälliger Verbrecher in Preussen”, p.
198.

[777] Wieselgren, “L’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la criminalité”, p.
164 (“Actes du Congr. pénit. de Bruxelles”), cf. Kinberg, “Alcool et
criminalité” (“Arch. d’anthr. crim.” XXVIII).

[778] Schaffroth, “L’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la criminalité”, p.
128 (“Actes du Cong. pén. intern. de Bruxelles”).

[779] “Die Ergebnisse der Schweizerischen Kriminalstatistik während der
Jahre 1892–1896”, p. 36.

[780] “Ueber individuelle Faktoren des Verbrechens”, p. 42.

[781] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. besides the works of de Roos,
Verrijn Stuart, Ariëns, and Kinberg, already cited, the following of
recent date: H. Hoppe, “Alkohol und Kriminalität”; A. Pistolese,
“Alcoolismo e delinquenza”; Hoegel, op. cit., pp. 397 ff.; K. W. F.
Boas, “Alkohol und Verbrechen nach neueren Statistiken”; Aull, “Alkohol
und Verbrechen”; A. Ley et R. Charpentier, “Alcoolisme et criminalité”;
G. B. Gruber, “Der Alkoholismus.” All these authors recognize, though
not all in the same degree, that the influence of alcoholism upon crime
is great; Pistolese alone denies it almost wholly.]

[782] The question must be looked at from the other side also, and it
must be admitted that military service can have a favorable effect upon
totally lawless individuals, who thus learn order and discipline; this,
however, does not prevent the disadvantages from remaining.

[783] Quoted by Oettingen in his “Moralstatistik”, p. 481.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: upon Germany: H. Dietz,
“Die Militärstrafrechtspflege im Lichte der Kriminalstatistik”; for
France: A. Corre, “Aperçu général de la criminalité militaire en
France”; for Italy: L. Ferrero di Cavallerleone and C. Placido, “Essais
de criminologie militaire.”]

[784] See also Oettingen, op. cit., p. 687; Colajanni, “Sociologia
criminale”, II, pp. 572–589; Corre, “Crime et suicide”, p. 337; Lux,
“Sozialpolitisches Handbuch”, p. 250; Wagner, “Die Sittlichkeit auf dem
Lande”, pp. 77–81; Lombroso, “Crime, its Causes and Remedies”, pp.
201–203; Steinmetz, “Der Krieg als sociologisches Problem”, p. 37;
Bleibtreu, op. cit., p. 16; Hamon, “Psychologie du Militaire
professionnel”, Chs. V–VIII.

[785] See also: Corre, “Essai sur la criminalité”, p. 78 (“Journal des
Economistes”, 1868); Colajanni, op. cit. II, pp. 572–589; Aubry, “La
contagion du meurtre”, pp. 247–249; Prof. Fr. v. Liszt, “Das Verbrechen
als sozial-pathologische Erscheinung”, p. 17.

[Note to the American Edition: See further upon the demoralizing
consequences of war: Steinmetz, “Die Philosophie des Krieges”, ch. III,
5, and my criticism of this book under the title “An apology for war”
(“Nieuwe Tijd”, XIII, pp. 488 ff.). Think of the horrible cruelties
committed in the recent wars in the Balkans (see the report of the
Commission of the Carnegie Foundation); no one can any longer deny the
demoralizing consequences of war!] [It may be of interest to the reader
to know that the author wrote the foregoing in the spring of
1914.—Transl.]

[786] Aubry, “La contagion du meurtre”, p. 70; see also Ch. III, and
Aschaffenburg, op. cit., p. 229.

[787] “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1895”, I, p. 31.

[788] “Kriminalstat. f. d. Jahr 1900”, I, pp. 18–19.

[789] “Kriminalstat. f. d. Jahr 1895”, I, p. 25.

[790] Drähms, “The Criminal”, p. 228, and “Criminal Statistics”,
1894–1900, Table XXXV.

[791] After “Criminal Statistics”, 1894–1900, Table IX.

[792] “Ergebnisse der Strafrechtspflege in den im Reichsrate
vertretenen Königreichen und Ländern im Jahre 1899”, p. li.

[793] The figures for 1850–1880 are taken from Bournet, “De la
criminalité en France et en Italie”, p. 31, for the Assizes, and from
Joly, “La France criminelle”, p. 166, for the others; the figures for
1881–1900 are from the “Rapport sur l’administration de la justice
criminelle de 1881 à 1900”, p. lxii.

[794] “Rapport etc.”, pp. lxiv and lxv.

[795] After Bournet “De la criminalité en France et en Italie”, p. 32,
and “Statistica giudiziaria penale”, 1881–1889. The criminal statistics
for 1890–95 contain all those convicted including those brought before
the justices of the peace, which makes them not comparable with those
given above. The average figure for 1891–95 was 25.27%, and for
1896–1900, 30.19% (“Notizie complementari etc.”, 1896–1900).

[796] After the “Jaarcijfers voor het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden”,
1901, p. 121.

[Note to the American Edition: The general percentage of recidivism in
the Netherlands had risen to 44.5% in 1908.]

[797] On short imprisonments for minor offenses see von Liszt,
“Kriminalpolitische Aufgaben”, V, “Die kurzzeitige Freiheitsstrafe”
(“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.” IX).

[798] See Gautier, “Le monde des prisons” (“Archives d’anthropologie
criminelle”, III) p. 563; Colajanni, “Sociologia criminale”, II, pp.
671–679; Laurent, “Les habitués des prisons de Paris”, pp. 592–596;
Havelock Ellis, “Verbrecher und Verbrechen”, pp. 266–276; Moreau, “Le
monde des prisons”, pp. 280–282; Aubry, “La contagion du meurtre”, Ch.
II; Lombroso, “Les palimpsestes des prisons”, pp. 379–381.

[799] Pp. 142, 143.

[800] Op. cit., p. 22.

[801] I will mention the following: Prins, “Criminalité et répression”,
Ch. V; Ferri, “La sociologie criminelle”, pp. 546–554, and “Eine
Verirrung des neunzehnten Jahrhunderts” (“Neue Zeit”, 1898–1899, II);
Sacker, op. cit., pp. 70–74; Roos, “De strafmiddelen in de nieuwere
strafrechtswetenschap”, Ch. VIII; Leuss, op. cit., pp. 176–193.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: G. Gradnauer, “Das Elend
des Strafvollzugs”, and A. Aletrino, “Is celstraf nog langer geoorloofd
en gewenscht?”]

[802] See the Reports already cited, and Winter, “The New York State
Reformatory in Elmira.”

[803] As was pointed out in Part I, Tarde is the author who has drawn
attention to the rôle of imitation in the etiology of crime; but see
also: Sighele, “Le crime à deux”, “La foule criminelle”, and “La
psychologie des sectes”; Aubry, “La contagion du meurtre”; Ferriani,
“Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 203–211.

[804] P. 37.

[805] See Engels, “The Condition of the Working Class in England”, pp.
120 ff.

[806] “Criminal statistics”, 1894 and 1898, pp. 24 and 31.

[Note to the American Edition: In the “Crim. Stat. England and Wales,
1905” there is a special study of crime in some of the great cities
(pp. 62 ff.).]

[807] Prinzing, “Soziale Faktoren der Kriminalität”, pp. 565, 566.

[808] “Rapport sur l’administration de la justice criminelle de 1881 à
1900”, p. xxix.

[809] “Rapport etc.”, p. xxx.

[810] “Crimineele statistiek over het jaar 1901”, pp. xvii and xviii.

[811] See also A. Mayer, “Die Verbrechen in ihrem Zusammenhang mit den
wirtschaftlichen und sozialen Verhältnissen im Kanton Zürich.”

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: for Germany: J. Galle, “Die
Kriminalität in Stadt und Land in ihrer Beziehung zur
Berufsverteilung”; for the Balkan States: Wadler, op. cit., pp. 155
ff.; for Belgium: Jacquart, op. cit., pp. 86 ff.; for the Netherlands:
de Roos, op. cit., pp. 222 ff., and Verrijn Stuart, op. cit., p. 239.]

[812] See, among others, de Vries, “Eenheid in Veranderlijkheid”, pp.
3–6.

[813] [Note to the American Edition: In present day sociology it is
almost universally accepted that there is only a quantitative
difference between criminals and other men, and that the “homo
criminalis” does not exist. An interesting contribution to this
question is given by Dr. Finkelnburg in his “Die Bestraften in
Deutschland”. His statistical calculations bring him to the conclusion
that in Germany there is one person out of every 12 (over 20 years of
age) convicted!]

[814] I speak neither of all the crimes nor of all the motives of those
of which I do treat. For a complete enumeration of the motives of
crimes, see Starke, “Des éléments essentiels qui doivent figurer dans
la statistique criminelle et des moyens de les rendre comparables”, pp.
77, 78 (“Bulletin de l’institut international de statistique”, 1889),
and von Liszt, “Die psychologischen Grundlagen der Kriminalpolitik”,
pp. 490–494 (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.” XVI).

[815] After the “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1900”, II, pp. 7–13.

[816]

[817] After the “Rapport sur l’administration etc.”, Tables 1, 2, and
7.

[818] After “Notizie complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali
degli anni 1890–1895”, pp. x and xi.

[819] After the “Gerechtelijke Statistiek”, 1897–1899, and the
“Crimineele Statistiek”, 1900–1901.

[820] “Rapport sur l’administration etc.”, p. xxxvii.

[821] Ferri, “Atlante antropologico-statistico dell’omicidio”, p. 328,
for 1880, and for 1881, from “Statistica giudiziaria penale per l’anno
1881”, pp. xc and xci.

[822] [There seems no better way to designate a classification that
does not exist in English than by taking over this French
term.—Transl.]

[823] Pp. 6, 14–18.

[824] “Ueber individuelle Faktoren des Verbrechens”, pp. 40, 41. On the
relation between vagrancy and mendicity, and criminality see also:
Colajanni, “Sociologia criminale”, I, pp. 478, 479 (quoted in Part I of
this work); Kurella, “Naturgeschichte des Verbrechers”, pp. 206, 207;
Sacker, “Der Rückfall”, pp. 56, 57; Fornasari de Verce, “La criminalità
e le vicende economiche d’Italia”, p. 19; A. Meyer, “Die Verbrechen in
ihrem Zusammenhang mit den wirtschaftlichen und sozialen Verhältnissen
im Kanton Zürich”, p. 59; Ferriani, “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 144
ff.; Bérard, “Le vagabondage en France”, pp. 609, 610 (“Arch. d’anthr.
crim.” XIII); Florian and Cavaglieri, “I Vagabondi”, II, pp. 181–197;
Löwenstimm, “Das Bettelgewerbe”, pp. 124–128 (“Kriminalistische
Studien”); Rivière, “Mendiants et vagabonds”, pp. 227, 228.

[825] “Neue Zeit”, 1893–1894, II, p. 443.

[826] Ostwald, “Das Leben der Wanderarmen”, p. 313 (“Archiv f.
Kriminalanthr. u. Kriminalstat.” XIII).

[827] “Neue Zeit”, 1893–1894, II, p. 58.

[828] Ostwald, op. cit., p. 313.

[829] Florian and Cavaglieri, op. cit., II, pp. xl and xli.

[830] See the works of Fornasari di Verce, Tugan-Baranowsky, and G.
Mayr, cited in Part I.

[Note to the American Edition: In his “Statistik und
Gesellschaftslehre”, III, p. 653, G. V. Mayr gives statistics of
vagrancy and mendicity for Germany (1877–1888), in which there appears
a formidable increase during the years 1877–1880 (the end of the
economic crisis), and a decrease after 1880. For Austria cf. Herz, op.
cit., pp. 49 ff.]

[831] [Note to the American Edition: Upon Bavaria, cf. F. Knoblauch,
“Bettel und Landstreicherei im Königreiche Bayern”, 1893–99.]

[832] For France see also Bérard, op. cit., pp. 607, 608.

[833] Ostwald, op. cit., p. 313. Cf. upon the periods 1866–1870 and
1877–1884, H. Bennecke, “Bemerkungen zur Kriminalstatistik des
Grossherzogtums Hessen”, pp. 369 ff.

[834] Cf. K. Böhmert, “Die Sächsische Kriminalstatistik mit besonderer
Rücksicht auf die Jahre 1882–1887.”

[835] See Bérard, op. cit., pp. 605, 606.

[836] Flynt, op. cit., p. 170.

[837] “Ein Beitrag zur Kenntnis des grossstädtischen Bettel- und
Vagabondentums” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.” XXI).

[838] See Ostwald, op. cit., pp. 306, 307.

[839] After “Criminal Statistics”, 1894–1900, Table XIII. In studying
these figures it must not be lost sight of that in general a workman is
soon worn out and after that is no longer hired.

[840] After “de Gerechtelijke Statistiek”, 1896–1899 and “de Crimineele
Statistiek”, 1901.

[841] After pp. 30, 31.

[842] Pp. 40, 41.

[843] “Naturgeschichte des Verbrechers”, p. 208.

[844] Florian and Cavaglieri, op. cit., II, p. 22. See also the whole
of Sec. 5, IV, Chap. 2, of the same authors.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon this subject cf. K. Wilmanns, “Zur
Psychopathologie des Landstreichers”, and Stelzner, op. cit., pp. 92
ff.]

[845] See Dugdale, “The Jukes”, pp. 47 and 49; and Flynt, op. cit., p.
6.

[846] See Florian and Cavaglieri, op. cit., II, pp. 34, 35, 177, 178.

[847] See Tomel and Rollet, “Les enfants en prison”, pp. 55–76;
Puibaraud, “Les malfaiteurs de profession”, pp. 217–230; Albanel, “Le
crime dans la famille”, p. 88; Löwenstimm, op. cit., pp. 89–99; Joly,
“L’enfance coupable”, pp. 60 ff.

[848] Op. cit., pp. 31, 32.

[849] Florian and Cavaglieri, op. cit., II, p. 52. See also: Frégier,
“Les classes dangereuses de la population dans les grandes villes”, I,
pp. 199, 200; Tomel and Rollet, op. cit., pp. 28–45; and Albanel, op.
cit., p. 78.

[850] Op. cit., p. 2.

[851] Flynt, op. cit., p. 49; Th. Holmes, “Pictures and Problems of
London Police Courts”, p. 64; and others.

[852] Upon vagrancy and mendicity of children see further: J. Délie,
“Le vagabondage des mineurs”; Ferriani, “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp.
144–155; and Flynt, op. cit., pp. 28–60.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon pathological children see P.
Schroeder, “Das Fortlaufen der Kinder” (“Monatschr. f. Krim.
Psychologie u. Strafr. reform”, VIII); and E. Stier, “Wandertrieb und
pathologisches Fortlaufen bei Kindern.”]

[853] See Florian and Cavaglieri, op. cit., II, pp. 11–14.

[854] See, for example, Löwenstimm, op. cit., pp. 17 and 92.

[855] See Bérard, op. cit., p. 605.

[856] See Ferriani, “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 177 ff., and
“Schlaue und glückliche Verbrecher”, pp. 460 ff.

[857] Op. cit., pp. 97, 103, 110, 182, and 244.

[858] Op. cit., p. 38.

[859] Op. cit., I, pp. 111, 112.

[860] Ferriani, “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 151–154. Tomel and
Rollet, op. cit., pp. 24–27.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. Haury, “La paresse pathologique”
(“Archives d’anthrop. crim.” XXVIII).]

[861] “Die Vagabondage und ihre Behandlung”, p. 715 (“Zeitschr. f. d.
ges. Strafrw.” XI).

[862] [Note to the American Edition: Of the recent literature upon
vagrancy and mendicity we would call attention to the following: K.
Wilmanns, “Das Landstreichertum, seine Bekämpfung und Abhilfe”; A.
Aletrino, “Handleiding bij de studie der crimineele anthropologie”, II,
ch. VI; Rotering, “Das Landstreichertum der Gegenwart”; Riebeth, “Ueber
den geistigen und körperlichen Zustand der Korrigenden”; de Roos, op.
cit., pp. 151 ff.; A. Marie and R. Meunier, “Les vagabonds”; Pollitz,
op. cit., pp. 95 ff.; A. Pagnier, “Le vagabond”; Kauffmann, op. cit.,
pp. 97 ff.; H. T. de Graaf, “Karakter en behandeling van veroordeelden
wegens landlooperij en bedelarij.”]

[863] Marx, “Kapital”, I, ch. XXLV, pp. 699 ff.

[864] Upon the impossibility of innate moral concepts see Näcke, “Die
neueren Erscheinungen auf kriminal-anthropologischen Gebiete und ihre
Bedeutung”, p. 342 (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.” XIV).

[865] “Der Ursprung der Idee des Gerechten und Ungerechten”, pp. 470,
471. (“Neue Zeit”, 1898–1899, II.)

[866] “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1894”, II, p. 53.

[867] The figures in the line a are the absolute figures (annual
averages), those in the line b the relative numbers, i.e. what the
daily average for that month would be if the daily average for the year
were 100.

[868] “Marche de la criminalité en France, 1825–1880” (“Revue
scientifique”, 1881), to be found also in Levasseur’s “La population
française”, II, p. 458.

[869] Taken from the “Kriminalstatistik”, 1895, 1907, 1908 and 1911,
and from the “Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich.”

[870] The figures from 1906 on are comparable with those preceding,
only with reserve.

[871] The figures from 1907 on are not comparable with those preceding.

[872] For details see my study already cited, “Verbrechen und
Sozialismus.”

[873] [Note to the American Edition: The English criminal statistics
for 1905 show an interesting diagram upon the connection between the
trend of economic crime and that of business from 1885 to 1905 (Int. p.
24).]

[874] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. Jacquart, op. cit. pp. 109
ff.]

[875] [Note to the American Edition: For the period 1896–1908 I have
shown in my study “Crime et Socialisme” the striking parallel between
economic crime and the business situation.]

[876] There are still to be mentioned as authors who have treated the
dynamics of criminality: J. Sacker, “Der Rückfall” (pp. 39, 40);
Aschaffenburg, “Das Verbrechen und seine Bekämpfung” (pp. 89 ff.); and
H. Leuss, “Aus dem Zuchthause” (pp. 228 ff.).

[Note to the American Edition: See further: for Austria: Hoegel, op.
cit., pp. 369 ff., Herz, op. cit., pp. 40 ff.; for Saxony: Böhmert, op.
cit., and Wulffen, op. cit., I pp. 390 ff.; for Servia: Wadler, op.
cit., p. 73 ff. Cf. also in general: V. Mancini, “Le varie specie di
furto nella storia e nella sociologia”, III 3, Ch. IV.]

[877] Cf. further: Aschaffenburg, op. cit., pp. 98 ff.; Eggert, “Not
und Verbrechen”; Wulffen, op. cit., I, pp. 395 ff.; v. Rohden in
“Zeitschr. f. Sozialwissenschaft”, VII, pp. 522 ff., and IX, pp. 229
ff.

[878] Cf. the recent study of Prinzing, “Die soziale Lage der Witwe in
Deutschland” (“Zeitschr. f. Sozialwissenschaft”, III).

[879] In general, criminals are distinguished as occasional, habitual,
and professional. Habitual criminals, however, are also occasional
criminals, for they do not seek the occasion for their crimes like
criminals by profession, but profit by it whenever it presents itself.
They are the bond of union between the first and third kind of
criminals, and in my opinion, it is unnecessary to treat of them
separately.

[880] See the passage from Mably, Pt. I, p. 14; also Lassalle, “Offenes
Antwort-Schreiben” (“Reden und Schriften”, II, pp. 426–427).

[881] Cf. Földes, “Einige Ergebnisse der neueren Kriminalstatistik”, p.
548.

[882] Cf. Ryckère, “La servante criminelle”, ch. III.

[883] As to the literature upon theft in stores, etc., see especially
Lacassagne, “Les vols à l’étalage et dans les grands magasins” (“Compte
rendu du IVe Congrès d’anthr. crim.”) and Dubuisson, “Les voleuses des
grands magasins” (“Arch. d’anthr. crim.”, XVI.); also Lombroso and
Ferrero, “La femme criminelle et la prostituée”, pp. 481, 482; Albanel,
op. cit., pp. 91–95.

[884] An interesting proof of the truth of this assertion may be found
in an article by Dr. P. v. Gizycki, entitled “Wie urteilen Schulkinder
über Funddiebstahl?” (“Zeitschrift für Kinderforschung”, VIII). One day
this author gave young girls (between 11 and 15 years of age) in a
school of the poor in Berlin, the following composition: “You are going
to the Christmas fair without money, for your parents are poor. Your
father is out of work. You find a pocket book containing a five-mark
piece. What do you do with it?” The children had not been prepared for
the subject and had received no indication of how they ought to treat
it. Only five per cent. of the girls said that they would return the
money, because they would pity the person who lost it, and who might
also be poor. All the others among those who also wished to return the
money (53%) had other motives. Those who, on the contrary, wished to
retain the money, wanted, without exception, to use it to give their
parents things they needed. Who will still dare to say that the
children who wanted to keep the money (most of them believing in good
faith that they had a right to it) in order to give it to others, had
feelings less social than most of the rich who, without blushing, see
the misery of the poor?

[885] Upon the bad surroundings of the childhood of thieves see
further: Raux, “Nos jeunes détenus”, p. 42, and Ferriani,
“Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 264 ff.

[886] Op. cit., p. 28.

[887] “Das Verbrechen, etc.”, p. 123.

[888] Op. cit., p. 42.

[889] Cf. Ferriani, “Schlaue und glückliche Verbrecher”, p. 39, and
Sighele, “Psychologie des sectes”, pp. 141, 142.

[890] Ferriani, op. cit. See also Zerboglio, “Les inconvénients de
l’honnêteté” (“L’ère nouvelle”, 1894).

[891] “Aus dem Zuchthause”, p. 122.

[892] “Kriminalstatistik f. d. Jahr 1896”, I, p. 14.

[893] “Notizie complementari alle statistiche giudiziarie penali degli
anni 1890–1895”, p. viii.

[894] Tönnies, “Das Verbrechen als soziale Erscheinung”, p. 334 (“Arch.
f. Soz. Gesetzgeb. u. Stat.”, VIII).

[895] Tarde, “Les délits impoursuivis”, p. 207 (“Essais et mélanges
sociologiques”).

[896] “Statistica giudiziaria penale per l’anno 1894”, p. lxxxii. See
also the detailed statistics cited by Ferriani, op. cit., pp. 112–118.

[897] “Les malfaiteurs de profession”, 5. 139.

[898] “Les transformations de l’impunité”, p. 167 (published by
Professor Lacassagne in “Vacher l’éventreur et les crimes sadiques”).

[899] “Betrachtungen über ein Sammeln der verbrecherischen Motive”, p.
278 (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.”, XVII). See also Földes, op. cit.,
pp. 516–519.

[900] In a work upon the etiology of crime it is unnecessary to set
forth in detail the numerous ruses that professional criminals make use
of to dupe the public and the police. We merely note here a few
important works dealing with this subject: Frégier, “Les classes
dangereuses de la population dans les grandes villes”, I, Part II,
Chap. VII; Avé-Lallemant, “Das deutsche Gaunerthum”, III, pp. 118–340;
O. S., “Die Verbrecherwelt von Berlin”, III (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges.
Strafrw.”, V); Puibaraud, “Les malfaiteurs de profession.”

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. Herz, op. cit., Ch. IVa, and E.
Wulffen, “Gauner- und Verbrechertypen.”]

[901] Cf. the following passage from “Tramping with Tramps”, by Josiah
Flynt: “One more regret which nearly all criminals of the class I am
considering have experienced at one time or another in their lives, is
that circumstances have led them into a criminal career. Their remorse
may be only for a moment, and an exaggerated indifference often follows
it; but while it lasts it is genuine and sincere. I have never known a
criminal well who has not confessed to me something of this sort; and
he has often capped it with a further confidence—his sorrow that it was
now too late to try anything else” (pp. 25–26).

[902] Op. cit., pp. 131, 132. As regards the education of children in
thieving, see also: Faucher, “Études sur l’Angleterre”, I, pp. 89 ff.;
Tomel and Rollet, “Les enfants en prison”, pp. 195–197.

[903] Although there are some works upon this subject, criminal
sociology would derive great profit from the publication of a great
number of biographies of criminals, and especially of great criminals.

[Note to the American Edition: Dr. N. Muller in his work already
referred to, “Biografisch-aetiologisch onderzoek etc.”, has made a
noteworthy beginning in this field, by giving biographies of 24 great
criminals. The “Verbrechertypen” edited by Gruhle and Wetzel, promises
much.]

[904] See, among others, G. Moreau, “Souvenirs de la petite et de la
grande Roquette”, I. p. 27, and “Le monde des prisons”, pp. 11, 16; L.
Gordon Rylands, “Crime, its Causes and Remedy”, pp. 18 ff.

[905] Op. cit., pp. 21, 22.

[906] Op. cit., p. 22.

[907] Op. cit., pp. 23, 24. To the same effect see O. S., op. cit., pp.
136, 137.

[908] Op. cit., pp. 5, 6; see also pp. 11–12. To the same effect:
Starke, “Verbrechen und Verbrecher in Preussen”, p. 221; Havelock
Ellis, “Verbrecher und Verbrechen”, pp. 24, 25; and Leuss, “Aus dem
Zuchthause”, p. 125.

[909] [Note to the American Edition: Muller mentions further as a
result of his researches that criminals by profession show in general
an adventurous and unstable character. Cf. Kauffmann, op. cit., pp. 160
ff.]

[910] “Actes du IIe Congrès d’Anthr. Crim.”, p. 163.

[911] IV., pp. 386–388. See also Zerboglio, “Les inconvénients de
l’honnêteté”, pp. 385 ff.

[912] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. further (besides the works of
Muller and Kauffmann): Wulffen, II, pp. 284 ff.; Pollitz, op. cit., pp.
124 ff.; also Brusse’s brochure, already cited, “Het rosse”, etc.]

[913] Cf. A. H. Post, “Bausteine für eine allgemeine
Rechtswissenschaft”, I, p. 293, and “Grundriss der ethnologischen
Jurisprudenz”, II, pp. 421 ff.

[914] In his “Grundriss, etc.”, II, p. 213, Dr. Post names different
peoples who do not consider theft as blamable but as praiseworthy. It
is very probable that this relates to theft committed to the detriment
of another group, and not to the prejudice of the members of the
thief’s own group. It is plain that it is only the latter kind of theft
that we treat of in a work upon crime. Cf. Kovalewsky, “Les origines du
devoir”, pp. 88, 89 (“Revue internationale de sociologie”, II).

[915] To the same effect see Kovalewsky, op. cit., pp. 88, 89, note.

[916] “Bausteine etc.”, I, pp. 286, 287. See by the same author,
“Grundriss etc.”, II, p. 429, and “Der Ursprung des Rechts”, pp. 114,
115. Cf. Steinmetz, “Ethnologische Studien zur ersten Entwicklung der
Strafe”, II, p. 252.

[917] Cf. the quotation from Morgan on p. 386 of this work.

[918] See Dargun, “Ursprung und Entwicklungsgeschichte des Eigenthums”,
pp. 81–83.

[919] Cf. Post, “Bausteine etc.”, I, p. 288 ff.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: Westermarck, “Ursprung und
Entwicklung der Moralbegriffe”, II, ch. 24.]

[920] Cf. v. Liszt, “Das gewerbmässige Verbrechen”, pp. 126, 127
(“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.” XXI).

[921] “Statistica giudiziaria penale per l’anno 1889”, pp. cliv–clv.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. further upon Austria: Herz, op.
cit., pp. 39 ff.; upon the Balkan states: Wadler, op. cit., pp. 46 and
54.]

[922] “Della statistica dell’omicidio negli stati Uniti d’America”
(“Bulletin de l’Institut intern. de statistique”, X), pp. 40 ff.

[923] Cf. Niceforo, “Les transformations du crime et la civilisation
moderne”, pp. 642 ff. (“Scuola Positiva”, XI).

[924] “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1894”, II, p. 53.

[925] H. Berg, “Getreidepreise und Kriminalität in Deutschland seit
1882”, pp. 10, 18.

[Note to the American Edition: After 1898, also, the influence of the
economic situation made itself felt in these crimes.]

[926] P. 47. See plate, pp. 40, 41.

[927] [Note to the American Edition: Wadler has shown the connection of
these two phenomena for Servia (op. cit., p. 83).]

[928] Taken from Sighele, “Le crime à deux”, pp. 122–125.

[929] Taken from “Archiv für Kriminal-Anthropologie und
Kriminalstatistik”, XI, pp. 307 ff.

[930] Baer, “Ueber jugendliche Mörder und Todtschläger” (“Archiv f.
Krim.-Anthr. und Krim.”, XI).

[931] Op. cit., pp. 166, 167.

[932] “Les enfants en prison”, p. 215.

[933] Cf. Ferriani, “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 279 ff.

[934] Taken from Moreau, “Souvenirs de la petite et de la grande
Roquette”, II, ch. VIII. See also Joly, “Le crime”, pp. 97 ff.

[935] Cf. Manouvrier, “Les crânes des suppliciés” (“Arch. d’anthr.
crim.”, I), where he shows that the conformation of the skulls of
assassins is simply of a coarser type than others.

[936] Pp. 47–48.

[937] “Tramping with Tramps”, p. 24. Cf. Moreau, “Le monde des
prisons”, p. 621, and Kauffmann, op. cit., pp. 163, 164 and 203–206.

[938] Cf. Post, “Der Ursprung des Rechts”, p. 116, “Bausteine etc.”, I,
pp. 300–302, and “Grundriss der ethnologischen Jurisprudenz”, II, p.
444.

[939] P. 318.

[940] For Germany see also H. Berg, “Getreidepreise und Kriminalität in
Deutschland seit 1882”, p. 18.

[941] Pp. 375, 376.

[942] Where capitalism is beginning to develop, adulteration, etc., is
the order of the day (e.g. in Japan in our day. See “Zeitschr. f.
Socialwissenschaft”, N. F. IV, p. 503); later a certain honesty, based
upon interest, especially in the wholesale business, becomes the rule.
(Cf. Engels, “Die Lage der arbeitenden Klassen in England”, Preface pp.
vii–viii.)

[943] See Zerboglio, “Les inconvénients de l’honnêteté” (“L’ère
nouvelle”, 1894); also Ferriani, “Glückliche und schlaue Verbrecher”,
IV.

[944] Laschi, op. cit., pp. 72, 73.

[945] Laschi, op. cit., p. 106.

[946] Laschi, op. cit., pp. 97 ff.

[947] Pp. xx and xxi.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. B. Kritschewsky, “Die Korruption in
der französischen Demokratie” (“Neue Zeit”, XXVIII2), pp. 12 ff.]

[948] See Laschi, op. cit., p. 107.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon the way in which great fortunes
have been amassed, see F. Kummer, “Die Geschichte der grossen
amerikanischen Vermögen” (“Neue Zeit”, XXX2).]

[949] For descriptions of cases see Zola, “L’argent”, and Wulffen, op.
cit., II, p. 334.

[950] Laschi, op. cit., p. 180.

[951] Pp. 147, 148.

[952] P. 128 (in the original, p. 131).

[953] Cf. Post, “Grundriss der ethnologischen Jurisprudenz”, II, p.
359; Letourneau, “L’évolution du mariage et de la famille”, p. 257;
Lafargue, “Der Ehebruch in Gegenwart und Vergangenheit” (“Neue Zeit”,
VII); and Ferrero, “Le crime d’adultère—son passé, son avenir”
(“Archives d’anthrop. crim.”, IX).

[954] “Les criminels dans l’art et la littérature”, p. 141. Cf. also
Letourneau, “Évolution du mariage”, pp. 282, 283.

[955] Pp. 444, 445.

[956] Aschaffenburg, “Das Verbrechen und seine Bekämpfung”, p. 13. Cf.
A. v. Oettingen, “Moralstatistik”, pp. 221, 222; Prof. Tardieu, “Étude
médico-légale sur les attentats aux mœurs”, pp. 22, 23; Dr. P. Bernard,
“Des viols et attentats à la pudeur sur adultes”, p. 562 (“Arch.
d’anthr. crim.” II); also the German criminal statistics.

[957] “Das Verbrechen in seiner Abhängigkeit von dem jährlichen
Temperaturwechsel” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.”, II).

[958] See G. v. Mayr, “Gesetzmässigkeit im Gesellschaftsleben”, pp. 239
ff., and “Statistik und Gesellschaftslehre”, II, pp. 170, 171.

[959] “Contribution à l’étude statistique de la criminalité en France”,
p. 60. Dr. A. Bournet, in “De la criminalité en France et en Italie”,
p. 68, and Ferri, op. cit., p. 39, and Bernard, op. cit., p. 566, come
to the same conclusion.

[960] Socquet, op. cit., pp. 61 and 69. See also Ferri, op. cit., p.
43.

[961] Socquet, op. cit., p. 60.

[962] Cf. Bournet, op. cit., p. 68, and Bernard, op. cit., p. 567.

[963] The first two columns are taken from Bernard, op. cit., p. 569;
the last is figured from the “Annuaire statistique de la France”, VII,
p. 526.

[Note to the American Edition: The same thing is shown by the criminal
statistics of the Netherlands. Cf. de Roos, op. cit., p. 114, and my
own study already cited, “Misdaad en Socialisme”, pp. 34–35.]

[964] “Die Sittlichkeitsverbrechen in Deutschland in
kriminalstatistischer Beleuchtung”, p. 266. Cf. Wittenberg and Wagner,
“Die geschlechtlich sittlichen Verhältnisse der evangelischen
Landbewohner im Deutschen Reiche”, and Wagner, “Die Sittlichkeit auf
dem Lande.” See also Ferriani, “Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 96 ff.,
and L. Braun, “Die Frauenfrage”, pp. 385, 386.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. Herz, op. cit., p. 35; Bonger, op.
cit., pp. 33, 34; Baernreither, op. cit. passim; and Geill,
“Kriminal-anthropologische Untersuchungen dänischer
Sittlichkeitsverbrecher”, p. 358.]

[965] See among others Grotjahn, “Der Alkoholismus”, pp. 53 and 86.

[966] “Actes du congrès pénitentiaire international de Bruxelles.”

[967] Loeffler, “Alkohol und Verbrechen”, pp. 518–521 (“Zeitschrift f.
d. ges. Strafrw.” XXIII).

[968] P. 113. See also Bournet, op. cit., p. 69.

[969] “Crimineele Statistiek voor het jaar 1901”, p. xxvii.

[970] “Actes etc.”, p. 167.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon the influence of alcohol upon
sexual crimes see further Geill, op. cit., p. 362; Aschaffenburg, “Zur
Psychologie der Sittlichkeitsverbrechen”, p. 408; Bonhoeffer,
“Sittlichkeitsdelikt und Körperverletzung”, p. 469.]

[971] “Die Ergebnisse der schweizerischen Kriminalstatistik während der
Jahre 1892–1896.”

[972] See “Der Ursprung des Rechts”, p. 112; “Die Grundlagen des Rechts
etc.”, p. 377; and “Grundriss der ethnologischen Jurisprudenz”, II, p.
382.

[973] See among others Garraud and Bernard, “Des attentats à la pudeur
et des viols sur les enfants”, pp. 404–405 (“Arch. d’anthr. crim.”, I).

[974] See Lafargue, p. 293; Garraud and Bernard, op. cit., pp. 408–409.

[975] Cf. “Reports on the law relating to the protection of young
girls”, 1882, p. 37; Dr. Ladame, “De la prostitution dans ses rapports
avec l’alcoolisme, le crime, et la folie”, pp. 24–26; and Amschl,
“Aberglauben als Heilmittel”, pp. 397, 398 (“Archiv f. Krim.-Anthr. und
Kriminalstatistik”, XV).

[976] Cf. Tardieu, op. cit., pp. 21, 22; Levasseur, “La population
française”, II, p. 448; Starke, op. cit., pp. 172, 173.

[977] Socquet, op. cit., pp. 60 and 68.

[978] In his “Die Frau und der Sozialismus”, Bebel gives almost the
same proportion for Germany without indicating the source from which he
takes his figures. As he remarks the percentage of the rich and
well-to-do would be larger if those interested did not often succeed in
hushing the matter up. We need only recall the revelations made by the
“Pall Mall Gazette” (see “Les scandales de Londres”).

[979] Garraud and Bernard, op. cit., p. 432.

[980] Socquet, op. cit., pp. 60 and 69.

[981] Cf. Bournet, op. cit., pp. 66–68; Socquet, op. cit., p. 73;
Garraud and Bernard, op. cit., p. 435.

[982] The author makes the mistake of omitting here the words “of
children.” Statistics show that it is especially the country, where the
sexual life is characterized rather by grossness than by perversion,
that produces these crimes. Dr. Després has been led to this error
through studying the geography of rape upon children and upon adults at
the same time—by which method they are seen to be most numerous in the
cities where prostitution exists exclusively. An examination of the two
crimes separately gives different results.

[983] P. 43.

[984] Op. cit., p. 24. Cf. Tarde, “Penal Philosophy”, p. 355, and
Leuss, op. cit., p. 106.

[985] Op. cit., p. 36.

[986] Cf. Bérard des Glajeux, “Les passions criminelles”, pp. 121, 122.

[Note to the American Edition: Additional works that have appeared
recently are: R. Quanter, “Die Sittlichkeitsverbrechen”; F. Leppmann,
“Die Sittlichkeitsverbrecher” (very interesting!); de Roos, “De
sexueele criminaliteit”; L. Wachholz, “Zur Lehre von den sexuellen
Delikten”; E. Wulffen, “Der Sexualverbrecher”; L. Ferrante Capetti,
“Reati e psicopatie sessuali”; J. Werthauer, “Sittlichkeits-Delikte der
Gross-Stadt”; Kauffmann, op. cit., pp. 133 ff.; M. R. Senf,
“Geschlechtstrieb und Verbrechen.”]

[987] For a complete enumeration of the motives of crime see: Liszt,
“Die psychologischen Grundlagen der Kriminalpolitik”, pp. 490–494
(“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.”, XVI) and Starke, “Des éléments
essentiels qui doivent figurer dans la statistique criminelle et des
moyens de les rendre comparables”, pp. 77, 78 (“Bulletin de l’inst.
intern. de statistique”, 1889).

[Note to the American Edition: See further the recent studies upon
superstition and crime: Löwenstimm, “Aberglaube und Verbrechen”,
“Aberglaube und Gesetz”; Wulffen, “Psychologie des Verbrechens”, II,
pp. 219–229; Helling, “Verbrechen und Aberglaube”.]

[988] Upon the psychology of vengeance see Steinmetz, “Ethnologische
Studien zur ersten Entwicklung der Strafe”, I, pp. 99 ff.

[989] Upon the instinct of vengeance see: A. H. Post, “Bausteine für
eine allgemeine Rechtswissenschaft”, I, pp. 140 ff.; Colajanni,
“Sociologia criminale”, II, p. 64; Letourneau, “L’évolution juridique”,
pp. 7 ff.; Lafargue, “Der Ursprung der Idee des Gerechten und
Ungerechten”, p. 421 (“Neue Zeit”, 1898–1899, II).

[990] Cf. Prinzing, “Soziale Faktoren der Kriminalität”, p. 558, and
Aschaffenburg, “Das Verbrechen und seine Bekämpfung”, p. 135.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. especially: Müller-Lyer, “Phasen der
Liebe”, pp. 47 ff.]

[991] See Ferriani, “L’amore in tribunali”, and L. Holtz, “Les crimes
passionels”, upon crimes of this class.

[992] II, p. 131.

[993] “Eskimo Life.”

[994] See Letourneau, “L’évolution du mariage et de la famille”, p.
275.

[995] See Steinmetz, op. cit., II, p. 303, and Sutherland, op. cit., I,
chap. VIII.

[996] It is plain that this influences also those relationships that
are not sanctioned by law.

[997] There is almost no mention of sexual jealousy where men and women
both occupy an independent position. Cf. Morgan, “Ancient Society”, p.
431.

[998] Cf. Holtz, op. cit., pp. 52–54.

[999] Cf. Holtz, op. cit., pp. 147–149.

[1000] “Kriminalstatistik für das Jahr 1894”, II, p. 52.

[1001] In his “Getreidepreise und Kriminalität in Deutschland”, H. Berg
shows that crimes against persons in Germany were not influenced by
economic occurrences during the years 1882–1898 (pp. 31 ff.).

[Note to the American Edition: I have proved the same for 1898–1908.
(See my study, “Verbrechen und Socialismus”, p. 808.)]

[1002] [Note to the American Edition: The same is true in the
Netherlands. In Austria, Herz has shown a certain relation between the
phenomena in question after 1863, but not in recent years.]

[1003] The figures for homicide, etc., are taken from Ferri, “Atlante
antropologico-statistico dell’omicidio”, pp. 246–248. The figures for
illiteracy in Italy, Belgium, France, Germany, and Holland are taken
from the official statistics, the others from the “Statesman’s Year
Book, 1902.”

[1004] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: Wadler, op. cit.,
pp. 176 ff., upon the Balkan States, where the crimes in question are
very frequent, and the degree of civilization is very low. (In Servia,
for example, in 1900 there was a percentage of illiteracy of about
79!)]

[1005] From Colajanni, “L’homicide en Italie”, p. 49 (“Revue
Socialiste”, 1901).

[1006] The first column is taken from “Kriminalstatistik f. d. Jahr
1898”, II, pp. 27–30; the second from “Statistisches Jahrbuch f. d.
Deutsche Reich, 1894”, p. 151; the last is figured from “Statistik der
Reichstagswahlen von 1898”, p. 3.

[Note to the American Edition: In my study already quoted, “Verbrechen
und Socialismus”, I have given figures for 1903–1907, which show in
general the same results.]

[1007] I have chosen the crime of serious assault, because it is
committed especially out of revenge, and because the figures for
homicide are too small in Germany to answer for this table.

[1008] Later I will explain why these figures are added.

[1009] From Boies, “Science of Penology”, Appendix B.

[1010] From Ferri, “Atlante dell’omicidio”, pp. 250, 251; the figures
for illiteracy are from “Annuario statistico italiano, 1900”, pp. 177,
178.

[1011] To my regret I have been unable to procure the figures for
1880–1883; the differences between the provinces were, however,
probably the same as for 1896.

[1012] The first column is from “De crimineele statistiek van 1901”,
the second from “Jaarcijfers voor het Koninkrijk der Nederlanden,
1901”, p. 47.

[Note to the American Edition: In my study, “Misdaad en socialisme”, I
have given the figures for a longer period (1901–1905), which confirm
in general the results given above (p. 35).]

[1013] Cf. Moreau (of Tours), “L’homicide commis par les enfants”, pp.
53 and 77; Ferriani, “Entartete Mütter”, pp. 73 and 167, and
“Minderjährige Verbrecher”, pp. 134 ff.

[1014] Cf. E. Key, “Das Jahrhundert des Kindes”, p. 149.

[1015] Steinmetz, “Ethnologische Studien zur ersten Entwicklung der
Strafe”, I, pp. 299 ff.

[1016] Cf. Colajanni, op. cit., p. 39.

[1017] For Italy, in addition to the official statistics already cited,
see Colajanni, “L’homicide en Italie”, pp. 43, 44, 51–52. I have not
been able to procure figures for the movement of these crimes in other
countries.

[Note to the American Edition: Herz mentions, for Austria (1862–1899) a
decrease of crimes in their most serious form and an increase in the
less serious. For Scotland and Ireland the criminal statistics show a
remarkable decrease; in England this decrease has been very
considerable in recent years, and for all forms of these crimes. In
Belgium there is a decrease for the more serious forms, the others
remaining stationary. In the Netherlands there has been a decrease in
recent years. In the United States the crimes in question seem to be
increasing (cf. J. W. Garner, “Homicide in American Cities” (“Journal
of Criminal Law and Criminology”, III, p. 675).]

[1018] Cf. Starke, “Verbrechen und Verbrecher in Preussen”, p. 236, and
Berg, “Getreidepreise und Kriminalität in Deutschland seit 1882”, pp.
34 ff.

[1019] Cf. Lux, “Sozialpolitisches Handbuch”, p. 152.

[1020] [Note to the American Edition: Later it has been shown that the
last remark is perfectly correct. In recent years (about the beginning
of the century), the consumption of alcohol has decreased, and also the
crimes in question: cf. my study “Verbrechen und Sozialismus”, pp. 807
ff.]

[1021] “Der Alkoholismus”, p. 57. Cf. O. Lang, “Alkoholgenuss und
Verbrechen”, pp. 50, 51.

[1022] See A. Baer, “Der Alcoholismus”, pp. 30 ff.; Grotjahn, op. cit.,
pp. 52 ff.; Aschaffenburg, “Alkoholgenuss und Verbrechen”, pp. 73–77
(“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.”, XX. This is also to be found in “Das
Verbrechen und seine Bekämpfung”, pp. 69–72).

[1023] “Sociologie criminelle”, p. 222.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. for Germany Bonger, op. cit., pp.
807 ff.; for Austria: Herz, op. cit., pp. 57 ff.; for Belgium:
Jacquart, op. cit., pp. 98 ff.; and for the Netherlands: Bonger, op.
cit., p. 27.]

[1024] The first two columns have been taken from Löffler, “Alkohol und
Verbrechen”, pp. 533, 534; the third from Lang, op. cit., p. 43; and
the two others from Aschaffenburg, op. cit., pp. 86 and 88.

[Note to the American Edition: See also: E. Kürz, “Zur Prophylaxe der
Roheitsdelikte”, and C. Hotter, “Alkohol und Verbrechen in
Niederbayern.”]

[1025] P. 92. See also Merens, “Over het onderzoek naar den invloed der
dronkenschap op de criminaliteit”, pp. 170–200.

[1026] See the criticism of these methods in Merens, op. cit., pp. 128
ff.

[1027] Löffler, op. cit., pp. 518–521.

[1028] Aschaffenburg, op. cit., p. 85.

[1029] Masoin, “L’alcoolisme dans ses rapports avec la criminalité”,
pp. 410–414 (“Bulletin de l’académie royale de médecine de Belgique”,
1896).

[Note to the American Edition: For Austria see Herz, op. cit., pp. 31
ff., and for the Netherlands: Bonger, op. cit., p. 35.]

[1030] “Actes etc.”, p. 113.

[Note to the American Edition: For France see also M. Yvernès,
“L’alcoolisme et la criminalité” (“Archives d’anthr. crim.”, XXVII).]

[1031] “Actes etc.”, p. 58.

[1032] Merens, op. cit., p. 126.

[1033] Merens, op. cit., p. 107.

[1034] “Crimineele Statistiek, 1901”, pp. xxvi–xxvii.

[1035] Wieselgren, “Rapport sur l’influence de l’alcoolisme sur la
criminalité” (“Actes du Congrès pénitent. de Bruxelles”).

[1036] P. 36.

[1037] [Note to the American Edition: In his “Anthropologie der
nichtbesitzenden Klassen”, Niceforo defends the thesis that the crimes
in question are caused by the physiological poverty of the poor
classes, in its turn a consequence of environment (pp. 369 ff.).]

[1038] Cf. Steinmetz, op. cit., I, Pt. III.

[1039] T. W. Teifen, “Das soziale Elend und die besitzenden Klassen in
Oesterreich”, p. 171.

[1040] Socquet, “Contribution à l’étude statistique de la criminalité
en France, 1876–1880”, p. 41.

[1041] Op. cit., p. 36.

[1042] Cf. Dr. Audiffrent, “Quelques considérations sur l’infanticide”,
p. 5 (“Archives d’anthrop. crim.”, XVII).

[1043] Cf. Starke, “Verbrechen und Verbrecher in Preussen”, p. 156;
Loosjes, “Bijdrage tot de studie van de criminaliteit der vrouw”, pp.
164, 165; Lombroso, “La femme criminelle et la prostituée”, p. 494;
Joly, “Le crime”, pp. 263, 264.

[1044] In his “L’évolution de la morale”, Letourneau points out that in
countries where public opinion is very indulgent to female frailty,
infanticide is almost unknown (p. 73).

[1045] Cf. Brissot de Warville, “Théorie des lois criminelles”, I, p.
95. Of a literature that has long been copious may be named,
especially, the interesting work of Pestalozzi, “Ueber Gesetzgebung und
Kindermord.”

[1046] Cf. Sutherland, “Origin and Growth of the Moral Instinct”, I,
pp. 113 ff.

[1047] [Note to the American Edition: Of the recent literature upon
infanticide I would call attention to: W. Gleispach, “Ueber
Kindesmord”; A. Amschl, “Das Verbrechen des Kindesmordes nach
oesterreichischem Recht”; G. van Dijck, “Eenige beschouwingen over het
misdrijf van kindermoord”; W. Kürbitz-Sonnenschein, “Der Geisteszustand
der Kindermörderinnen.”]

[1048] It seems to me that Lombroso and Laschi extend the conception of
political crime too much in making it any revolt against the
authorities, as they do in their work, “Der politische Verbrecher und
die Revolutionen”. Very often these troubles are only more or less
serious fights with the police and have no political character at all.
Opinions may differ as to the value of Professor Lombroso’s works, but
I cannot imagine how any one can admire his work upon political crime.
It is full of mistakes and superficial observations.

[1049] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. Vallon and Genil-Perrin,
“Crime et altruisme” (“Archives d’anthr. crim.”, XXVIII).]

[1050] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. upon political crimes in
Russia: E. Tarnowsky, “Les crimes politiques en Russie” (“Archives
d’anthr. crim.” XII), and A. Wadler, “Die politische Verbrechen in
Russland” (“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strafrw.” XXIX).]

[1051] See Dubois, “Le péril anarchiste”, pp. 25 ff.; Aubry, “La
contagion du meurtre”, pp. 256 ff.; and Enthoven, “Het anarchisme van
de daad”, ch. II.

[1052] Cf. Lombroso, “Les anarchistes”, p. 116.

[1053] Cf. Hamon, “Psychologie de l’anarchiste-socialiste”, ch. IV.

[1054] Lombroso, “Les anarchistes”, pp. 143, 144.

[1055] Cf. Seuffert, “Anarchismus und Strafrecht”, pp. 12 ff.

[1056] Cf. Hamon, op. cit., ch. V, and Lombroso, “Les anarchistes”, pp.
131 ff.

[1057] Some authors claim that active anarchists are ordinary
criminals. But see Hamon, op. cit., p. 15.

[1058] With regard to Caserio see Lacassagne, “L’assassinat du
président Carnot”, pp. 535 and 539, and the unsigned article, “Caserio
en prison”, both in “Arch. d’anthr. crim.”, LX and XVI respectively.

[Note to the American Edition: Upon Lucheni see further Forel,
“Verbrechen und konstitutionelle Seelenabnormitäten” and Ladame and
Régis, “Le régicide Lucheni.” The books of H. Varennes, “De Ravachol à
Caserio”, and of Hesse, “Les criminels peints par eux-mêmes” III,
“L’apostolat”, contain interesting information upon the active
anarchists.]

[1059] An exposition of the anarchistic theories has been given by Dr.
Eltzbacher, “Der Anarchismus”, and a very just critique of this subject
is that of Plechanow, “Anarchismus und Sozialismus.”

[Note to the American Edition: Upon Anarchism in general see further:
H. Zoccoli, “Die anarchie.”]

[1060] Tarde, “Les crimes de haine” (“Arch. d’anthr. crim.”, IX,
reproduced also in “Essais et mélanges sociologiques”).

[1061] It is impossible to fix the percentage of these cases, the
judges in general not being enough in touch with modern ideas etc.

[1062] See Benedikt, “Biologie und Kriminalstatistik”, p. 489
(“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.”, VII); Näcke, “Verbrechen und Wahnsinn
beim Weibe”, p. 175; “Die neueren Erscheinungen auf
kriminal-anthropologischen Gebiete und ihre Bedeutung”, p. 340
(“Zeitschr. f. d. ges. Strw.”, XIV).

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. Th. Ziehen, “Die Erkennung der
psychopathischen Konstitutionen und die öffentliche Fürsorge für
psychopathisch veranlagte Kinder”, and Stier, op. cit., p. 99.]

[1063] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. R. Gaupp, “Ueber den heutigen
Stand der Lehre vom ‘geborenen’ Verbrecher”, and J. Longard, “Ueber
‘Moral insanity.’” De Lanessan truly says that although these
individual causes are found in equal proportions in the two sexes,
women are much less criminal than men (“La lutte contre le crime”, p.
146).]

[1064] See above, pp. 439 ff. Also Patijn, “Atavisme en Misdaad”
(“Tijdschrift v. Strafr.”, V).

[1065] P. 106, “Tijdschrift v. Strafrecht”, VI.

[1066] P. 339. In further refutation from the anthropological
standpoint see Ch. Féré, “Dégénérescence et criminalité”, ch. V;
Manouvrier, “L’atavisme et le crime” (“L’ère nouvelle”, 1894);
Dallemagne, “Les théories de la criminalité”, ch. I; and Aschaffenburg,
“Das Verbrechen und seine Bekämpfung”, pp. 170, 171.

[1067] Upon the criminal as morally insane see: Baer, op. cit., pp. 380
ff.; Näcke, op. cit., p. 341; and Dallemagne, op. cit., ch. III.

Upon the criminal as epileptic see: Baer, op. cit., pp. 384 ff.;
Dallemagne, op. cit., ch. III; and Aschaffenburg, op. cit., p. 172.

[1068] Cf. Lacassagne and E. Martin, “Des résultats positifs et
indiscutables que l’anthropologie criminelle peut fournir à
l’élaboration ou l’application des lois” (Compte rendu du Ve Congrès
d’anthrop. crim.).

[1069] Kurella is one of the rare authors who denies this (see
“Naturgeschichte des Verbrechers”, pp. 258 ff.).

[1070] Upon page 107 of the article cited Professor Jelgersma shows
that certain really atavistic stigmata found in some criminals are very
well explained by degeneracy.

[1071] [Note to the American Edition: Cf. further: K. Birnbaum, “Die
psychopathischen Verbrecher”, and Stelzner, op. cit.]

[1072] “La famille névropathique”, p. 10.

[1073] “Dégénérés et déséquilibrés”, p. 168.

[1074] Op. cit., p. 102. See also Kende, “Die Entartung des
Menschengeschlechts”, p. 34.

[1075] [Note to the American Edition: Upon the relation between disease
and society see the fundamental work “Krankheit und soziale Lage”
(edited by M. Mosse and Tugendreich with collaboration of several
authorities).

It should also be mentioned here that the eugenists (e.g. Schallmayer
in the book just cited, pp. 841 ff.) deny that the causes mentioned
under first and second have any significance in heredity.]

[1076] “Les causes de la folie”, p. 34.

[1077] Stinca, “Le milieu social comme facteur pathologique”, p. 148
(“L’ère nouvelle”, 1894).

[1078] See Féré, “La famille névropathique”, pp. 133 ff.

[1079] “Verbrechen und Wahnsinn beim Weibe”, p. 155.

[1080] Cf. Maudsley, “The Physiology and Pathology of Mind”, pp. 232,
233.

[1081] Quoted by Lux, “Sozialpolitisches Handbuch”, pp. 71, 72.

[1082] Cf. Zadek, “Die Achtstundentag eine gesundheitliche Forderung”,
pp. 12 ff.

[1083] Quoted by Lux, p. 173. See also Toulouse, op. cit., p. 68.

[1084] See Braun, “Die Frauenfrage”, pp. 312 ff.

[1085] Cf. Näcke, “Verbrechen und Wahnsinn beim Weibe”, p. 196.

[1086] Upon the relation of the condition of the poorer classes to
degeneracy, cf. Zerboglio, “La fin de la névrose” (“Devenir Social”, I)
and “Les bases économiques de la santé” (“Devenir Social”, III); “Die
Not des Vierten Standes” (anonymous); Fornasari di Verce, “La
criminalità e le vicende economiche in Italia”, pp. 5–10; Dallemagne,
“Dégénérés et déséquilibrés”, p. 142; and Aschaffenburg, “Das
Verbrechen und seine Bekämpfung”, p. 172.

[Note to the American Edition: Cf. Niceforo, op. cit., pp. 474 ff.]

[1087] Cf. Toulouse, op. cit., p. 86, and Zerboglio, “La fin de la
névrose”, p. 630.

[1088] Pp. 103, 104.

[1089] Op. cit., pp. 233–235.

[1090] Cf. Battaglia, “La dinamica del delitto”, p. 412; Näcke, op.
cit., p. 156; Zerboglio, “La fin de la névrose”, p. 629. Toulouse, op.
cit., p. 85; Kraepelin, “Psychiatrie”, I, pp. 88, 89; Hellpach,
“Soziale Ursachen und Wirkungen der Nervosität”
(“Politisch-anthropologische Revue”, i).

[1091] Cf. Toulouse, op. cit., pp. 224 ff.

[1092] “Die Prostitution im XIX Jahrhundert”, p. 33; see also by the
same author, “Hygiene der Prostitution und venerischen Krankheiten”,
pp. 7 ff. Cf. also Kende, op. cit., p. 90, and Dr. M. Alsberg,
“Erbliche Entartung bedingt durch soziale Einflüsse”, p. 20.

[1093] “Hygiene der Prostitution etc.” p. 35.

Above we have seen that prostitution increases and diminishes with the
fluctuations of economic conditions. Dr. Schoenlank proves in his “Die
Syphilis und die Sozialzustände” (“Neue Zeit”, 1887) that syphilis also
increases and diminishes in these periods, an added proof of the
intimate connection of syphilis and prostitution.

[1094] Cf. Hellpach, “Der Kampf gegen die Geschlechtskrankheiten”, p.
197 (“Sozialistische Monatshefte”, VII).

[1095] Blaschko, “Die Prostitution etc.”, p. 32.

[1096] “Dégénérés et déséquilibrés”, p. 167.

[1097] Some authorities are of the opinion that children conceived
during a state of intoxication run the danger of being degenerates;
others, however, doubt this. See Grotjahn, “Der Alkoholismus”, p. 165.

[1098] “Conséquences sociales de l’alcoolisme des ascendants au point
de vue de la dégénérescence, de la morale et de la criminalité”, pp.
160–165 (“Compte Rendu IVe Congr. d’anthr. crim.”). For other figures
see also: de Vaucleroy, “Influence de l’hérédité alcoolique sur la
folie et la criminalité” (“Actes du IIIme Congr. d’anthr. crim.”);
Grotjahn, op. cit., pp. 166 ff.; Verhaeghe, “De l’alcoolisation”, pp.
112 ff.

[1099] See Toulouse, op. cit., pp. 163–167; and Grotjahn, op. cit., p.
220.

[1100] See Toulouse, op. cit., p. 178.









        
            *** END OF THE PROJECT GUTENBERG EBOOK CRIMINALITY AND ECONOMIC CONDITIONS ***
        

    

Updated editions will replace the previous one—the old editions will
be renamed.


Creating the works from print editions not protected by U.S. copyright
law means that no one owns a United States copyright in these works,
so the Foundation (and you!) can copy and distribute it in the United
States without permission and without paying copyright
royalties. Special rules, set forth in the General Terms of Use part
of this license, apply to copying and distributing Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works to protect the PROJECT GUTENBERG™
concept and trademark. Project Gutenberg is a registered trademark,
and may not be used if you charge for an eBook, except by following
the terms of the trademark license, including paying royalties for use
of the Project Gutenberg trademark. If you do not charge anything for
copies of this eBook, complying with the trademark license is very
easy. You may use this eBook for nearly any purpose such as creation
of derivative works, reports, performances and research. Project
Gutenberg eBooks may be modified and printed and given away—you may
do practically ANYTHING in the United States with eBooks not protected
by U.S. copyright law. Redistribution is subject to the trademark
license, especially commercial redistribution.


START: FULL LICENSE
THE FULL PROJECT GUTENBERG LICENSE
PLEASE READ THIS BEFORE YOU DISTRIBUTE OR USE THIS WORK


To protect the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting the free
distribution of electronic works, by using or distributing this work
(or any other work associated in any way with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg”), you agree to comply with all the terms of the Full
Project Gutenberg™ License available with this file or online at
www.gutenberg.org/license.


Section 1. General Terms of Use and Redistributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works


1.A. By reading or using any part of this Project Gutenberg™
electronic work, you indicate that you have read, understand, agree to
and accept all the terms of this license and intellectual property
(trademark/copyright) agreement. If you do not agree to abide by all
the terms of this agreement, you must cease using and return or
destroy all copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in your
possession. If you paid a fee for obtaining a copy of or access to a
Project Gutenberg™ electronic work and you do not agree to be bound
by the terms of this agreement, you may obtain a refund from the person
or entity to whom you paid the fee as set forth in paragraph 1.E.8.


1.B. “Project Gutenberg” is a registered trademark. It may only be
used on or associated in any way with an electronic work by people who
agree to be bound by the terms of this agreement. There are a few
things that you can do with most Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
even without complying with the full terms of this agreement. See
paragraph 1.C below. There are a lot of things you can do with Project
Gutenberg™ electronic works if you follow the terms of this
agreement and help preserve free future access to Project Gutenberg™
electronic works. See paragraph 1.E below.


1.C. The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation (“the
Foundation” or PGLAF), owns a compilation copyright in the collection
of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works. Nearly all the individual
works in the collection are in the public domain in the United
States. If an individual work is unprotected by copyright law in the
United States and you are located in the United States, we do not
claim a right to prevent you from copying, distributing, performing,
displaying or creating derivative works based on the work as long as
all references to Project Gutenberg are removed. Of course, we hope
that you will support the Project Gutenberg™ mission of promoting
free access to electronic works by freely sharing Project Gutenberg™
works in compliance with the terms of this agreement for keeping the
Project Gutenberg™ name associated with the work. You can easily
comply with the terms of this agreement by keeping this work in the
same format with its attached full Project Gutenberg™ License when
you share it without charge with others.



1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also govern
what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most countries are
in a constant state of change. If you are outside the United States,
check the laws of your country in addition to the terms of this
agreement before downloading, copying, displaying, performing,
distributing or creating derivative works based on this work or any
other Project Gutenberg™ work. The Foundation makes no
representations concerning the copyright status of any work in any
country other than the United States.


1.E. Unless you have removed all references to Project Gutenberg:


1.E.1. The following sentence, with active links to, or other
immediate access to, the full Project Gutenberg™ License must appear
prominently whenever any copy of a Project Gutenberg™ work (any work
on which the phrase “Project Gutenberg” appears, or with which the
phrase “Project Gutenberg” is associated) is accessed, displayed,
performed, viewed, copied or distributed:


  
    This eBook is for the use of anyone anywhere in the United States and most
    other parts of the world at no cost and with almost no restrictions
    whatsoever. You may copy it, give it away or re-use it under the terms
    of the Project Gutenberg License included with this eBook or online
    at www.gutenberg.org. If you
    are not located in the United States, you will have to check the laws
    of the country where you are located before using this eBook.
  


1.E.2. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is
derived from texts not protected by U.S. copyright law (does not
contain a notice indicating that it is posted with permission of the
copyright holder), the work can be copied and distributed to anyone in
the United States without paying any fees or charges. If you are
redistributing or providing access to a work with the phrase “Project
Gutenberg” associated with or appearing on the work, you must comply
either with the requirements of paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 or
obtain permission for the use of the work and the Project Gutenberg™
trademark as set forth in paragraphs 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.


1.E.3. If an individual Project Gutenberg™ electronic work is posted
with the permission of the copyright holder, your use and distribution
must comply with both paragraphs 1.E.1 through 1.E.7 and any
additional terms imposed by the copyright holder. Additional terms
will be linked to the Project Gutenberg™ License for all works
posted with the permission of the copyright holder found at the
beginning of this work.


1.E.4. Do not unlink or detach or remove the full Project Gutenberg™
License terms from this work, or any files containing a part of this
work or any other work associated with Project Gutenberg™.


1.E.5. Do not copy, display, perform, distribute or redistribute this
electronic work, or any part of this electronic work, without
prominently displaying the sentence set forth in paragraph 1.E.1 with
active links or immediate access to the full terms of the Project
Gutenberg™ License.


1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form, including
any word processing or hypertext form. However, if you provide access
to or distribute copies of a Project Gutenberg™ work in a format
other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or other format used in the official
version posted on the official Project Gutenberg™ website
(www.gutenberg.org), you must, at no additional cost, fee or expense
to the user, provide a copy, a means of exporting a copy, or a means
of obtaining a copy upon request, of the work in its original “Plain
Vanilla ASCII” or other form. Any alternate format must include the
full Project Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.


1.E.7. Do not charge a fee for access to, viewing, displaying,
performing, copying or distributing any Project Gutenberg™ works
unless you comply with paragraph 1.E.8 or 1.E.9.


1.E.8. You may charge a reasonable fee for copies of or providing
access to or distributing Project Gutenberg™ electronic works
provided that:


    • You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive from
        the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the method
        you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The fee is owed
        to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark, but he has
        agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to the Project
        Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty payments must be paid
        within 60 days following each date on which you prepare (or are
        legally required to prepare) your periodic tax returns. Royalty
        payments should be clearly marked as such and sent to the Project
        Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation at the address specified in
        Section 4, “Information about donations to the Project Gutenberg
        Literary Archive Foundation.”
    
    • You provide a full refund of any money paid by a user who notifies
        you in writing (or by e-mail) within 30 days of receipt that s/he
        does not agree to the terms of the full Project Gutenberg™
        License. You must require such a user to return or destroy all
        copies of the works possessed in a physical medium and discontinue
        all use of and all access to other copies of Project Gutenberg™
        works.
    
    • You provide, in accordance with paragraph 1.F.3, a full refund of
        any money paid for a work or a replacement copy, if a defect in the
        electronic work is discovered and reported to you within 90 days of
        receipt of the work.
    
    • You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
        distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.
    


1.E.9. If you wish to charge a fee or distribute a Project
Gutenberg™ electronic work or group of works on different terms than
are set forth in this agreement, you must obtain permission in writing
from the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the manager of
the Project Gutenberg™ trademark. Contact the Foundation as set
forth in Section 3 below.


1.F.


1.F.1. Project Gutenberg volunteers and employees expend considerable
effort to identify, do copyright research on, transcribe and proofread
works not protected by U.S. copyright law in creating the Project
Gutenberg™ collection. Despite these efforts, Project Gutenberg™
electronic works, and the medium on which they may be stored, may
contain “Defects,” such as, but not limited to, incomplete, inaccurate
or corrupt data, transcription errors, a copyright or other
intellectual property infringement, a defective or damaged disk or
other medium, a computer virus, or computer codes that damage or
cannot be read by your equipment.


1.F.2. LIMITED WARRANTY, DISCLAIMER OF DAMAGES - Except for the “Right
of Replacement or Refund” described in paragraph 1.F.3, the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation, the owner of the Project
Gutenberg™ trademark, and any other party distributing a Project
Gutenberg™ electronic work under this agreement, disclaim all
liability to you for damages, costs and expenses, including legal
fees. YOU AGREE THAT YOU HAVE NO REMEDIES FOR NEGLIGENCE, STRICT
LIABILITY, BREACH OF WARRANTY OR BREACH OF CONTRACT EXCEPT THOSE
PROVIDED IN PARAGRAPH 1.F.3. YOU AGREE THAT THE FOUNDATION, THE
TRADEMARK OWNER, AND ANY DISTRIBUTOR UNDER THIS AGREEMENT WILL NOT BE
LIABLE TO YOU FOR ACTUAL, DIRECT, INDIRECT, CONSEQUENTIAL, PUNITIVE OR
INCIDENTAL DAMAGES EVEN IF YOU GIVE NOTICE OF THE POSSIBILITY OF SUCH
DAMAGE.


1.F.3. LIMITED RIGHT OF REPLACEMENT OR REFUND - If you discover a
defect in this electronic work within 90 days of receiving it, you can
receive a refund of the money (if any) you paid for it by sending a
written explanation to the person you received the work from. If you
received the work on a physical medium, you must return the medium
with your written explanation. The person or entity that provided you
with the defective work may elect to provide a replacement copy in
lieu of a refund. If you received the work electronically, the person
or entity providing it to you may choose to give you a second
opportunity to receive the work electronically in lieu of a refund. If
the second copy is also defective, you may demand a refund in writing
without further opportunities to fix the problem.


1.F.4. Except for the limited right of replacement or refund set forth
in paragraph 1.F.3, this work is provided to you ‘AS-IS’, WITH NO
OTHER WARRANTIES OF ANY KIND, EXPRESS OR IMPLIED, INCLUDING BUT NOT
LIMITED TO WARRANTIES OF MERCHANTABILITY OR FITNESS FOR ANY PURPOSE.


1.F.5. Some states do not allow disclaimers of certain implied
warranties or the exclusion or limitation of certain types of
damages. If any disclaimer or limitation set forth in this agreement
violates the law of the state applicable to this agreement, the
agreement shall be interpreted to make the maximum disclaimer or
limitation permitted by the applicable state law. The invalidity or
unenforceability of any provision of this agreement shall not void the
remaining provisions.


1.F.6. INDEMNITY - You agree to indemnify and hold the Foundation, the
trademark owner, any agent or employee of the Foundation, anyone
providing copies of Project Gutenberg™ electronic works in
accordance with this agreement, and any volunteers associated with the
production, promotion and distribution of Project Gutenberg™
electronic works, harmless from all liability, costs and expenses,
including legal fees, that arise directly or indirectly from any of
the following which you do or cause to occur: (a) distribution of this
or any Project Gutenberg™ work, (b) alteration, modification, or
additions or deletions to any Project Gutenberg™ work, and (c) any
Defect you cause.


Section 2. Information about the Mission of Project Gutenberg™


Project Gutenberg™ is synonymous with the free distribution of
electronic works in formats readable by the widest variety of
computers including obsolete, old, middle-aged and new computers. It
exists because of the efforts of hundreds of volunteers and donations
from people in all walks of life.


Volunteers and financial support to provide volunteers with the
assistance they need are critical to reaching Project Gutenberg™’s
goals and ensuring that the Project Gutenberg™ collection will
remain freely available for generations to come. In 2001, the Project
Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation was created to provide a secure
and permanent future for Project Gutenberg™ and future
generations. To learn more about the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation and how your efforts and donations can help, see
Sections 3 and 4 and the Foundation information page at www.gutenberg.org.


Section 3. Information about the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation


The Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation is a non-profit
501(c)(3) educational corporation organized under the laws of the
state of Mississippi and granted tax exempt status by the Internal
Revenue Service. The Foundation’s EIN or federal tax identification
number is 64-6221541. Contributions to the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation are tax deductible to the full extent permitted by
U.S. federal laws and your state’s laws.


The Foundation’s business office is located at 809 North 1500 West,
Salt Lake City, UT 84116, (801) 596-1887. Email contact links and up
to date contact information can be found at the Foundation’s website
and official page at www.gutenberg.org/contact


Section 4. Information about Donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation


Project Gutenberg™ depends upon and cannot survive without widespread
public support and donations to carry out its mission of
increasing the number of public domain and licensed works that can be
freely distributed in machine-readable form accessible by the widest
array of equipment including outdated equipment. Many small donations
($1 to $5,000) are particularly important to maintaining tax exempt
status with the IRS.


The Foundation is committed to complying with the laws regulating
charities and charitable donations in all 50 states of the United
States. Compliance requirements are not uniform and it takes a
considerable effort, much paperwork and many fees to meet and keep up
with these requirements. We do not solicit donations in locations
where we have not received written confirmation of compliance. To SEND
DONATIONS or determine the status of compliance for any particular state
visit www.gutenberg.org/donate.


While we cannot and do not solicit contributions from states where we
have not met the solicitation requirements, we know of no prohibition
against accepting unsolicited donations from donors in such states who
approach us with offers to donate.


International donations are gratefully accepted, but we cannot make
any statements concerning tax treatment of donations received from
outside the United States. U.S. laws alone swamp our small staff.


Please check the Project Gutenberg web pages for current donation
methods and addresses. Donations are accepted in a number of other
ways including checks, online payments and credit card donations. To
donate, please visit: www.gutenberg.org/donate.


Section 5. General Information About Project Gutenberg™ electronic works


Professor Michael S. Hart was the originator of the Project
Gutenberg™ concept of a library of electronic works that could be
freely shared with anyone. For forty years, he produced and
distributed Project Gutenberg™ eBooks with only a loose network of
volunteer support.


Project Gutenberg™ eBooks are often created from several printed
editions, all of which are confirmed as not protected by copyright in
the U.S. unless a copyright notice is included. Thus, we do not
necessarily keep eBooks in compliance with any particular paper
edition.


Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.


This website includes information about Project Gutenberg™,
including how to make donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary
Archive Foundation, how to help produce our new eBooks, and how to
subscribe to our email newsletter to hear about new eBooks.